99% Invisible - Food Deserts
Episode Date: July 8, 2025How did millions of Americans end up living in neighborhoods where finding fresh food is harder than ever, and why is the problem by design, not accident? The answer rests in a major policy shift that... fundamentally altered the American food landscape.Food DesertsIf you're new to the show (thanks Apple Podcasts!) here are some favorite episodes to get you started:Freedom House Ambulance ServiceOne-Nil to the ArsenalGuerrilla Public Service ReduxTowers of SilenceThe House that Came in the MailThe Real Book Subscribe to SiriusXM Podcasts+ to listen to new episodes of 99% Invisible ad-free and a whole week early. Start a free trial now on Apple Podcasts or by visiting siriusxm.com/podcastsplus.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
This is 99% Invisible. I'm Chris Birube, sitting in this week for Roman Mars.
In Woonsocket, Rhode Island, there's one surefire way to get yourself clocked as an out-of-towner.
Is it Woonsocket?
Woon. Woonsocket.
Woonsocket.
Yep.
No double O.
No woo. No woo.
No woo.
No woo! No woo! This past spring, producer Jason DeLeon drove to, uh, One Socket, which is just a few miles up the road from where he lives.
And in One Socket, I met up with Jean Michonne. Jean is Native American and French-Canadian.
So technically, her name is...
Jean. God's gift to man. That's what it means.
Really?
Yeah, my mother had a sense of humor.
Pronunciation aside, everyone calls her Jean.
And Jean is third generation one socket.
She grew up there in the 1970s.
And back then, she said, the city had some stuff going for it.
There were places to hang out, like the local movie theater,
or the skating rink or the arcade.
And because she loved to cook, Jean remembers always jumping at the chance to go with her mom to the grocery store.
And that was the biggest thing ever.
Woo, let's go. We're going shopping with mom.
Woohoo. No, you're not getting nothing.
At the time, Jean's family had a lot of options for grocers.
There were small, locally owned stores like Fernandez Produce and Big D's.
The city also had supermarkets, from regional chains like Star Market and Almax.
The way some of these local shops bag groceries always mesmerized young Jean.
After ringing them up, a cashier would place the groceries in a box on a giant conveyor
belt which would crank out the side of the building.
And everybody knew that you park there and then it'll come out to you.
You know, dad would wait in the car while my kids were shopping, throwing whatever in
the boxes.
As the years went on, Wendsocket's economy took a turn for the worse.
For decades, factory jobs had employed a lot of the city. But those jobs left, and pretty soon, the local movie theater closed.
So did the skating rink and the arcade.
Then the grocery stores started disappearing.
We used to have Star Market, which was always packed on Diamond Hill, and then that one left.
One by one, local grocers shut their doors
and never reopened.
The decline was so dramatic that today in Woonsocket,
a city of 45,000, there's only one grocery store,
a Price Right out on the edge of town.
It's sad that people don't have other choices to make.
And I'm not knocking Price Right,
but when you have no choice,
but to go to one place, it's like that's the oasis in the desert.
This is the only spot that they can go to get refreshed is at this price right.
Woonsocket is what's known as a food desert. These are low-income communities where it's hard to find groceries.
According to the USDA, in a city like Woonsocket, that means lots of residents live more than a
mile from the nearest grocery store. And while a mile in a city may not sound like much,
according to the latest census information, nearly 20% of Woonsocket's residents don't have access to a vehicle.
Pair that with unreliable public transportation, and suddenly a simple task like grabbing groceries
can become a real struggle.
On its face, the story of how Woonsocket turned into a food desert seems pretty straightforward.
The city fell on hard times, then businesses abandoned ship, and now it's harder to get basic things like groceries.
But the actual story of how when socket and places like it became food deserts is more
complicated than that.
The common assumption about why food deserts exist, both in the academic literature and
among policymakers, is that these are communities that can't
support a supermarket.
You know, they're either too poor or too small to generate enough spending on groceries
and therefore can't support a supermarket.
Stacy Mitchell is a food researcher and co-executive director at the Institute for Local Self-Reliance.
And she thinks this general understanding of food deserts misses the bigger
picture.
Food deserts didn't used to exist.
You know, poverty has been with us forever.
But food deserts only arose in the late 1980s.
And so this explanation that we have that food deserts are really kind of like there's
something wrong with the community, like the community itself is deficient in some way and therefore can't support a supermarket.
That's not actually why we have food deserts.
Everybody eats, you know, poor neighborhoods spend a lot of money on grocery stores.
It's not that there's not enough spending in these neighborhoods.
Like something else happened.
It's easy to think of food deserts as a natural consequence of poverty.
But in communities like Woonsocket, grocery stores stuck around well into the 1990s,
long after the factories closed and the city's fortunes faded.
Stacey Mitchell says the real reason these food deserts emerged all across the country
is because of a decades-long battle over
one policy. The story of this policy fight starts with the rise of one of
America's first national grocery chains, the Great Atlantic and Pacific Tea
Company, better known as AMP.
We watch our P's and Q's and A&P.
We know you'll be back. For these little green guys.
They're our specials of the week.
A&P started as a tea company in lower Manhattan,
but at the turn of the 20th century,
the retailer expanded into the grocery business.
At the time, the industry was mostly composed
of small independent neighborhood grocers.
These mom-and-pop shops would often take orders by phone and then deliver them to your house.
They also operated on a credit system, so instead of settling the bill with every purchase,
customers would just pay a tab at the end of the month.
However, deliveries can get expensive, and operating on a credit system exposed these
grocers to big losses.
Sometimes people just didn't pay up.
So to cover shortfalls, they'd often mark up their prices.
But with the arrival of AMP came a new business model.
AMP did away with deliveries and purchases on credit.
Instead, at your local A&P, customers would approach the counter and pay on the spot with
cash.
They also cut costs by vertically integrating their business.
The company owned manufacturing facilities, which produced A&P branded products, which
they sold in A&P stores, all of which helped them offer the lowest prices in town.
Prioritizing low prices is a pretty simple change, but it was existential for all of those mom and pop shops.
There's a lot of alarm across the country about AMP.
You know, they're opening all of these stores, they're putting lots of local grocers out of business
and really just taking over
the market very rapidly.
By the early 1930s, AMP had expanded from grocery stores in the New York metro area
to more than 15,000 stores nationwide.
While other chain stores existed, A&P perfected the model. Even in places like Winsocket, A&P had multiple stores throughout the city.
And with all that growth, A&P achieved something no retailer in America had ever done before.
It produced more than a billion dollars in sales.
And the company used all this money and power as a weapon.
In negotiations with suppliers, A&P knew that it had the upper hand.
And so the company leveraged its size not only to get the very best deals,
but to make life harder on their competition.
The reason that A&P is growing so rapidly is that it's squeezing suppliers.
It's going to suppliers and saying, we're your biggest customer and we want you to give us big discounts and other favors while raising the prices that you're charging our competitor down the street.
This is what's known as the waterbed effect.
When suppliers charged AMP less for its products, they made up for it by
charging more to the small neighborhood grocers.
So like a waterbed, if you sit on one side, the other side goes up.
So in effect, what drives AMP's growth is that it has this kind of leverage that
comes purely from its size.
In the 1930s, AMP was viewed by many as a monopoly, and its size was a huge issue in
the country.
The company was known to blacklist suppliers who didn't bend to their will.
It also extracted big fees from farmers and manufacturers to carry their products.
From the federal government all the way down to high school debate classes, people argued
about AMP and how big is too big.
AMP is like changing the fabric of neighborhoods and of towns. It's coming in and running out of
business, a lot of local businesses. So there's this big backlash all across the country.
This pushback against AMP was part of a wider movement against chain stores in general.
In small towns throughout the Midwest and the South, big chains threatened local businesses.
And because AMP was the biggest chain store, it became the target of communities nationwide.
Municipal governments tried to help small local grocers by taxing AMP.
Some even passed laws to limit the number of stores it could open in a county.
In Shreveport, Louisiana, a local radio station ran a whole program focused on fighting chain stores.
A musician named Andrew Jenkins had a message for communities facing a takeover
by the likes of AMP. when the hometown merges before it is too late.
In the 1930s, the anger with chain stores
was also part of a broader frustration with the economy.
Many people felt the system
just wasn't serving the working class.
After all, A&P crossed a billion dollars in sales
during the Great Depression.
While the low prices helped cash-strapped Americans, it was notable that A&P's rise
coincided with the lowest point in many people's lives.
Soon, Congress picked up on all this outrage.
A&P built up its power during an era of relatively lax antitrust enforcement. But as part of FDR's New Deal,
corporate power was under intense scrutiny.
And with one new piece of legislation,
two lawmakers set their sights
on breaking up the power of AMP.
So in 1936, they passed a law called
the Robinson-Patman Act.
And it's an antitrust law, and it outlaws what is known as price discrimination.
The Robinson-Patman Act was the brainchild of Senator Joseph Robinson from Arkansas and
Congressman Wright Patman from Texas.
And it gave the federal government a new tool to rein in monopolistic power.
The law was even nicknamed the Anti-ANP Act.
For years, AMP pressured suppliers into giving them the best deals.
But the Robinson-Patman Act changed that dynamic.
It outlawed price discrimination, which means that whatever sweet deal AMP received from a supplier
had to be the same sweet deal offered to other retailers, including small independent grocers.
The law makes it illegal for suppliers to provide different prices to different
buyers. It also makes it illegal for retailers that have market power to
demand special deals, discounts, other kinds of favorable treatment.
One big hang up that people had with the Robinson-Patman Act is this idea that it banned bulk discounts.
But that's not exactly true.
Big chains could still get a lower price for buying in bulk.
Other retailers just needed access to the same terms.
The goal was to make retailers compete over things like innovation, product selection,
and customer service, rather than using purely market power to shove competition out.
A&P tried to persuade the public that its size wasn't a problem.
In a magazine profile, the president of the company warned that breaking up their power would actually raise grocery prices.
And in one newspaper ad, ANP thumbed its nose at antitrust enforcers by showing a picture of the Empire State Building with a caption that read,
It's far too big. It ought to be seven buildings.
Still, the Federal Trade Commission and the Department of Justice kept pressuring the company.
And after Robinson-Patman went into effect, the changes
to the grocery business were almost immediate.
The law ate into AMP's profits.
And within a few years, the company's exponential growth
looked a lot more like normal growth.
The steep decline of the small neighborhood grocer was headed off.
AMP is no longer, you know, sort of aggressively like gobbling up the entire market. They're
stopped from doing that, but they're still, you know, a force.
The Robinson-Patman Act didn't destroy AMP. It just stopped the company from abusing its
power. Big chain grocers continued to thrive and operate nationwide.
And small grocers could still serve their communities.
There was a semblance of balance in the grocery business.
Independent grocers, you know, including, you know, sort of single location grocery stores
and very small, like family owned chains that had a handful of stores.
Those retailers maintain more than half of all grocery
sales from the 1940s all the way through the early 1980s.
So from a consumer's perspective, it's like the best of both worlds because almost every
neighborhood has this choice.
If you want to shop at an independent grocery store, you have that option.
But if you prefer to shop at, say, Kroger or Safeway, you
also have that option. There's this incredible diversity and variety and competition, and it's
all really resting on the fact that we had the Robinson-Patman Act and enforced it.
For decades, the Robinson-Patman Act helped create a more level playing field in the grocery business. But it would soon get swept up in a huge campaign
to rewrite the rules of American antitrust.
After the break, one man's quest to break the Robinson-Patman Act
and the rise of food deserts. From the 1930s into the 1970s, the Federal Trade Commission aggressively enforced the
Robinson-Pabin Act.
It issued citations and cease and desist orders to companies who violated the law.
This had the effect of reining in powerful chains like AMP.
It also acted as a deterrent to other businesses who might be on the verge of their very own monopolistic power trip.
But the backlash from big business was always coming.
Since the New Deal, antitrust laws like Robinson-Patman acted as a check on corporate power.
But in the 1970s, a new school of economic thought took hold.
It argued that traditional FDR-era antitrust enforcement was actually holding the American
economy back.
And to unlock America's full economic potential, we needed to completely
rethink antitrust.
A key figure in the dismantling of our antitrust laws is Robert Bork.
Robert Bork was a professor of antitrust law at Yale, but he's probably best known for
his political career. He was the one who carried out Nixon's order to fire the special prosecutor
investigating Watergate. The Saturday Night Massacre? That's Robert Bork.
Bork's name was also famously turned into a verb after his failed confirmation to the
Supreme Court. He got Borked.
As an academic, Bork was part of this rising tide of scholars trying to reshape antitrust in a more free market direction.
And to help do that, he published a book in 1978 that became a manifesto for the movement.
He writes this book called The Antitrust Paradox.
And you know, it is a kind of bestseller, if you will, for a policy book.
And it has this incredible influence across the right and even to some
degree among Democrats.
In the antitrust paradox, Bork argues that for decades American antitrust claimed to
be about protecting competition and consumers.
But in reality, antitrust only protected inefficient companies and punished the successful ones.
And this paradox, he said, actually harmed consumers because it led to higher prices.
At the time, Bork's argument had a receptive audience.
The American economy struggled during the 70s with high inflation and low growth.
Grocery prices were skyrocketing, and Bork insisted traditional antitrust enforcement
was making
things worse. And he didn't just throw tomatoes from the sidelines. In his book, Robert Bork
laid out a new vision for antitrust. One that he claimed was based on a close, accurate
reading of the nation's first antitrust laws.
You know, Bork very much believed that corporations should be free to wield their power and do
what they want and that the laws that we'd always understood to mean that we should disperse
power, that we should prevent too much consolidation, that's not really what those laws were about.
He thought that antitrust was all about efficiency, and big corporations tend to be more efficient.
So you know what?
We should actually use antitrust to encourage corporate consolidation.
So he like turned antitrust on its head?
In Robert Bork's view, antitrust enforcement had been overly concerned with fairness.
After all, fairness was subjective.
A truly objective policy would use what he called
the consumer welfare standard.
And this new standard he came up with
focused on prices over basically everything else.
Part of how Bork and his cohort sell this idea
is by saying that prices are measurable, efficiency is measurable.
Like it's like one North Star.
We can point antitrust to this.
Like there's an answer to the problem or any question that's asked.
We can find an answer.
Like is this merger good or bad?
Well, will it lead to lower prices?
That's one question, one answer that then guides policy.
That's the thinking behind it.
And to really help drive home his case for the consumer welfare standard, Robert Bork
turned the Robinson-Patman Act into his punching bag.
It should be said that almost the scholarly opinion on all sides of the antitrust issue
is that the Robinson-Patman Act is a peculiarly pernicious
statute.
In his book, Bork calls the law, quote, anti-trust's least glorious hour.
Elsewhere, he called it the typhoid Mary of anti-trust.
Robert Bork didn't just dislike the Robinson-Patman Act, he loathed it.
So in his writing, he characterized it as this crazy,
stupid law.
And he creates this environment where for decades, any economist worth their salt, any
legal scholar worth their salt, would never say that the Robinson-Patman Act was a good
thing. You couldn't venture it. Your professional career would be destroyed by saying that.
It would be like saying destroyed by saying that.
It would be sort of like saying the earth is flat.
In the 80s, Bork's ideas made the leap from the page into the halls of power.
All throughout government, antitrust positions were filled with appointees who agreed with
Bork's philosophy.
Laws were reinterpreted and new policy guidelines were issued. The Bork era of antitrust was underway and it was built on the consumer welfare standard.
And in this new era, the Robinson-Patman Act wasn't so much killed by authorities as it
was disappeared.
They just kind of decided, well, we're just going to put that law up on a shelf and we're
not going to enforce it.
For decades, the Robinson-Patman Act remained up on that shelf, gathering dust.
Still technically a law, but ignored.
The occasional person might come by and flip through it like an old photo album.
But it was understood through different administrations, Republican and Democrat, that this was a thing of the past, a relic of a bygone era of antitrust.
That is until the 2010s,
when some prominent researchers and legal scholars
started to really assess the impacts of its retirement.
Is it almost like literally the case
that businesses are checking the antitrust landscape
and are just like, nobody's looking at Robinson-Patman anymore.
So like, do whatever you want.
Absolutely.
I mean, I had, you know, lawyers and even a general counsel at a company tell me that
they don't even advise their companies to follow the Robinson-Patman Act because it's
not enforced.
This is Lena Kahn.
She was appointed chair of the FTC under President Biden.
Kahn is often talked about as the antidote to Robert Bork, which is kind of funny because
they're both Yale Law School alums.
Yeah, the class where I learned antitrust law in law school had a big portrait of Bork
in the back.
Did having that portrait like behind you make you feel any kind of way?
It felt very apt.
I mean, Robert Bork's taught at Yale Law School,
the professor who was still teaching anti-trust had been close with Bork,
a colleague of his, and so it felt very fitting in that way.
Khan is one of the leaders of what's known today as the anti-monopoly movement.
And she first rose to prominence after writing a paper that really stuck it to Bork.
It's titled Amazon's Antitrust Paradox.
And as far as academic papers go, it was a real bombshell, setting off big debates in
antitrust circles.
In her research, Lena Khan says that understanding antitrust through Bork's framework is entirely
too narrow.
It allowed companies like Amazon to amass power with very little scrutiny.
And she thought this level of consolidated power has actually resulted in bad outcomes,
not just for consumers, but for society.
And one way to plainly show these bad outcomes is by looking at what happened to the grocery
business.
When the government deep-sixed Robinson-Patman, it was too late for the grocery giant AMP.
The company eventually went out of business.
But in its place, another Goliath had emerged.
Walmart. In the late 1980s, Walmart entered the grocery business
and quickly took a page out of A&P's playbook
from back in the day.
Well, once the Robinson-Patman Act is shelved,
you see big retailers like Walmart
start demanding discounts from their suppliers
and not just demanding discounts,
but demanding that they get systematically lower prices
than what their rivals are getting.
The suspension of Robbins and Patman
created a new incentive in the industry.
Who could get bigger faster?
Because the faster you grew,
the quicker you could leverage your size over suppliers.
The incentive to get bigger faster
resulted in a massive merger spree in the 1990s. Independent
and even regional grocers were swallowed up by the big national chains, like Kroger and
Albertsons and Safeway, all of which are huge companies in their own right. But even they
were looking to bulk up.
Certainly when the big grocers have been consolidating, one of the arguments that
they make is that we need to get bigger so that we can actually get the same
discriminatory discounts that the big guys are.
This new dynamic in the grocery business, rampant consolidation in search of the
lowest prices,
absolutely decimated small neighborhood grocers.
The waterbed effect was in full effect.
Big chains like Walmart could extract discounts from suppliers, and in turn, suppliers would
make up for any shortfalls by charging smaller stores more.
In effect, what you have then is the smaller retailers subsidizing the discounts that Walmart
is getting.
And what's going to happen over the long run is those independent grocers are going to
get squeezed and are going to get pushed out of the market.
For people in places like Woonsocket, Rhode Island, all this consolidation meant more
residents had to rely on big chains
for groceries.
Walmart opened a store in Woonsocket back in 1994, and as the company captured a bigger
slice of the market, locally owned grocers felt the pressure.
Many of them closed.
But in a pattern that has played out in lots of communities, after Walmart helped drive
a bunch of grocers out of business.
Walmart closed too, only to open a new store in a more central location a few miles down the road in another town. Here's Stacey Mitchell again.
You know, kind of looking back at this history, the sort of question becomes, well, you can
understand how the suspension of Robinson-Patman led to the demise of independent
grocers. But the question becomes like, well, why didn't chains fill those gaps?
And the answer is that they didn't have to because we know people have to eat, so
they're going to come out to our other stores and we don't have to actually spend
the money to operate a store in the neighborhood.
When Walmart or another big chain leaves town, they don't just abandon the place.
Sometimes they make it impossible for other competitors to move in.
For example, Walmart owns most of their buildings and when they sell it, they can impose a
restriction on the deed, banning, say, another grocer from opening up in the same place.
These scorched earth covenants, as they're called, can last decades.
So not only are the scales tipped in their favor, but some national grocers are known
to salt the earth on their way out.
This is the playbook Walmart used to become America's grocer. Today, the company captures one in every four dollars Americans spend on groceries.
In some metro areas, Walmart has captured half the grocery market.
In others, the number is closer to 70 percent.
This is a level of power that is way beyond anything that AMP ever got to.
Stacey Mitchell and Lena Kahn both agree that the decline of small local grocers paired with the rise of Walmart and other big national chains has
fundamentally altered the food landscape, especially in low income neighborhoods,
where these deep concentrations of corporate power
have left residents traveling further and further for groceries.
39 million Americans live in an area that's classified as a food desert.
There are food deserts all across the country.
There are so many communities that have been hollowed out, where people are struggling
on a day-to-day basis.
Not having a grocery store nearby is a daily hardship and an indignity.
By Robert Bork standards a food desert is actually in its own twisted way an
efficient economic outcome. If large companies like Walmart drive out smaller
less efficient grocers and nobody chooses to serve that low-income
community that's not a market failure.
It's a market outcome.
It's just something that happens.
Lena Kahn believes by favoring what Bork would call the most efficient grocers, consumers
have been harmed in other ways.
The geographic distribution of stores is a problem.
The health outcomes of people living in food deserts is a problem. The health outcomes of people living in food deserts
is a problem.
And in case you haven't paid attention to our politics
in the last four years,
the price of groceries is still a problem too.
The attack line was Robbins and Patman enforcement
results in higher prices for people.
That was the argument that was offered.
But once you try to trace that argument back
to actual evidence or support,
there's no evidence. It's really arguments that are made on theory,
and they're not actually supported by what's happening in the real world.
In the real world, national chains have amassed so much power in some places that they're actually
able to inflate prices.
We saw this play out during the pandemic. At the time, supply chain issues were driving prices up.
And big chains used that as an opportunity to turn bigger profits.
It was really striking to hear some of the executives from these big grocers talk on
their earnings calls, where sometimes there was a recognition that even though the costs were going to go down because those
supply chain issued would resolve themselves, the grocers decided in some
cases to keep prices high anyway.
And that's something that you can only get away with if you're not being
disciplined by competition.
The retirement of Robinson Patman was supposed to drive prices down for
consumers. But in an industry as consolidated as the grocery business,
monopolistic power starts to act in monopolistic ways.
And so when Lena Kahn was appointed chair of the FTC, she decided to do
something bold.
So the FTC during my tenure ended up reviving the Robinson-Patman Act.
During her time at the FTC, Lena and her team pursued the first Robinson-Patman cases in over 20 years.
One of those cases was against Pepsi, which, by the way, doesn't just make soda.
They're also one of the biggest suppliers in the grocery sector.
Quaker Oats? Pepsi.
Ocean Spray? Pepsi.
Rolled Gold Pretzels? Pepsi.
It's really just Pepsi all the way down.
The FTC's case alleged that Pepsi was giving unfair price advantages to
Walmart at the expense of competing retailers.
So should I explain waterbeds again?
Okay, so if you sit on one side, I'm just kidding.
I'm just kidding.
You know, I went and visited some of the independent grocers and independent wholesalers that said
they were being discriminated against in this way.
And what they would tell me is that if they went to a Costco or Walmart or Target, the prices on the shelves would be lower than
what was being made available to them at a wholesale level, which is pretty staggering
in terms of just the types of huge price differences that may be happening.
For too long, the FTC hasn't been skeptical enough towards monopoly power.
Bringing this case was just one way Lena Khan hoped to change that and at the same time show the public that the government can truly take on big problems.
I think people had in some ways lost hope that the government would really go back
to doing its job in this way.
And so I heard a lot from people that, especially for grocers and other independent stores that
had been feeling squeezed for a very long time, this was a sign of hope for them.
In recent weeks, Trump's FTC voted to drop the Pepsi case, calling it a legally dubious
partisan stunt.
Lena Kahn says that lawsuit would have helped stop conduct that squeezes small businesses.
And dismissing it was a gift to giant retailers.
The FTC is still technically pursuing one more Robinson-Patman case,
but it's hard to say what the future of that case looks like.
Regardless, Kahn's criticisms of Bork's antitrust ideas have already started to make
an impact.
Last year, when the Kroger-Albertson merger was blocked, courts cited evidence that this
amount of consolidation would lead to more food deserts and higher prices.
Kahn also helped implement new federal merger guidelines, which the Trump administration
kept.
And that means any merger that crosses the government's desk will have a much higher standard to meet.
Not just Robert Bork's consumer welfare standard.
Sounds like you're wrapping up.
Yeah, they're wrapping up.
You're hanging it up.
And you just fill the water up.
Hang me out.
How old are you?
84?
84. Back in Woonsocket, when me out. How old are you, 84?
84.
Back in Woonsocket, when I met up with Jean Michon,
she was in her element, inside a kitchen.
Jean actually runs an organization named New Beginnings.
It's a community kitchen that helps feed some of the city's
most food insecure.
On a warm, sunny April day, the first of the year, she had 40 paper boxes laid out in a neat square to pack leftovers.
That's like none of this goes to waste.
No, absolutely not. Absolutely not. I've been doing this 39 years. I don't waste anything.
Jean has been around one socket long enough to see a food desert emerge, and she decided to do something about it. The whole organization at New Beginnings has created a vital piece of infrastructure in the city.
For a long time, kitchens like hers have helped feed people who don't have the means.
But over the years, she's noticed more people drop in who simply can't make it to a grocery store.
And to help serve these families,
she's planning to work even longer hours.
Right now we just do lunch.
So if there's working families who can't get to food,
they can't get to lunch with us,
we want to expand to do meals at night as well.
So we'll reach one population during the day
and one population at night.
Decades of neglect created One Socket's food desert.
Laws went unenforced and corporate power ran amok.
Recently, lawmakers in Rhode Island proposed a package of antitrust laws aimed directly at the grocery business, including a local version of a Robinson-Patman Act.
But until something really changes,
Jean is just gonna be here, in her kitchen,
doing her best to serve the people
this whole system left behind.
99% Invisible was produced this week by Jason DeLeon and edited by me, Chris Borube, and the team at 99% Invisible.
Mixed by Martin Gonzalez, music by Swan Royale, fact checking by Graham Hayesha.
Special thanks this week to Stacey Mitchell over at the Institute for Local Self-Reliance.
She's been writing about food deserts in the Atlantic and other publications for years now. You can find
links to some of her articles on our website. Also, a special thanks this week to Ethan Shorry over
at the Valley Breeze. There are not a lot of local publications covering places like Woonsocket
at this point, and the archives of the Valley Breeze were tremendously
helpful in the research for this story.
So thank you.
An extra special thank you to Jean Michon and the whole New Beginnings organization.
Their work out in Rhode Island is truly heroic.
Cathy Tu is our executive producer.
Kurt Kolstad is our digital director.
Delaney Hall is our senior editor.
And the rest of the team includes Emmett Fitzgerald, Christopher Johnson, Vivian Leigh, Lasha Madan, Jacob Medina Gleason, Kelly Prime, and Joe
Rosenberg.
And of course, Roman Mars is our fearless leader.
The 99% Invisible logo was created by Stephen Lawrence.
We are part of the SiriusXM podcast family, temporarily headquartered this week between
Providence, Rhode Island and beautiful
downtown Toronto, Ontario, Canada.
You can find us on all the usual social media sites, as well as our Discord server.
There's a lot going on there.
You can find a link to that, as well as every past episode of 99PI, at 99PI.org.