a16z Podcast - a16z Podcast: Knowledge Builds Technology and Technology Builds Knowledge -- with Joel Mokyr

Episode Date: November 27, 2016

The Industrial Revolution (and period between 1500-1700) was an unprecedented age of technology and economic progress — not unlike today’s, in fact — where we took “quantum leaps” forward in... tech by taming electricity, making cheaper steel and refining iron cheaply, automating fiber looms, pumping water out of coal mines, figuring out how to measure longitude at sea, improving the quality of food, preventing smallpox, … even bleaching underwear. But what really triggered the Industrial Revolution? Why did it take place in Europe and spread beyond? It has to do with a competitive, open market of ideas — a transnational “Republic of Letters”, not unlike the early days of the blogosphere. And the conditions that created it (virtual networks, open access science, weak ties, and so on) are the very conditions we may need to sustain growth and prosperity even today, argues Joel Mokyr, professor of economics and history at Northwestern and author of the new book A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern Economy. Despite fears of what new tech may bring, the alternative to not innovating is stagnation — “not doing it is worse”, argues Mokyr in this episode of the a16z Podcast. So how do we then measure that growth? How does this all play out internationally, and institutionally? And what happens when we bring shared focus to big problems, like climate change? If there’s one pattern that continues to play out throughout history to today, it’s that “Knowledge builds technology and technology builds knowledge.” image: Library of Congress

Transcript
Discussion (0)
Starting point is 00:00:00 Hi everyone, welcome to the A6 and Z podcast. I'm Sonal. Today's guest is Joel Mokir, Professor of Economics and History at Northwestern. His new book, A Culture of Growth, The Origins of the Modern Economy, is about what really drove the Industrial Revolution. It was a period not unlike today where we took quantum leaps forward, to quote the author, in tech, from taming electricity to making cheaper steel, refining iron cheaply, improving the quality of food, automating fiberlooms, pumping water out of coal mines, preventing smallpox, and even bleaching underwear. In short, one of the most significant ages of tech and economic progress.
Starting point is 00:00:36 In this interview, we cover everything from the public virtual sphere of ideas that drove this knowledge at the time and internet analogies today. We also touch briefly on how to focus on big problems like climate change to how do we measure growth. But we began the conversation with the then-revolutionary idea of a steam engine. The first steam engine is introduced in England in 1712 by a man called Thomas Newcomen. And, you know, the principles on which that engine was built were not known a century earlier because these are called atmospheric engines. And the idea that the earth is surrounded by an atmosphere, which sounds kind of commonplace
Starting point is 00:01:16 to us, actually was not realized until the 17th century by one of Galileo's more famous students, a man called Torricelli. And while you have the concept of an atmosphere, then the notion of creating a vacuum and having the pressure of the atmosphere push a piston down in a cylinder in which you have created a vacuum, that idea can then follow. But in order to do that, you also have to realize that a vacuum is possible. And thereby hangs an important part of the story so now because Aristotle taught that there is no such thing as a vacuum. And Aristotle was the gospel for many centuries. And basically, if Aristotle said something, that was true,
Starting point is 00:02:02 people thought. And then, you know, in the 17th century, damn it, people start building vacuum pumps. Now, you have to have these principles to build this machine. And so it couldn't be built in the Middle Ages, and it couldn't be built by any other society, because the fundamental notions on which it was built just didn't exist and just couldn't be realized. Now, what is true for steam engines is essentially true across the board. Knowledge builds technology and technology builds knowledge. And that synergy between these two sort of different aspects of human knowledge is what drives essentially our modern economic growth. And it still does to the present day. I think we can accept that today. Generally speaking, an important nuance in what you just described
Starting point is 00:02:52 is that the people who are working on the steam engine were going against people they respected. There was a certain movement that we now take for granted that was actually very difficult to do at the time. And so I'd love to drill down on that a little bit more as well. Well, the key word to describe what's happening is contestability. And by that I mean that this is an age
Starting point is 00:03:14 which sheds its deep respect and awe for ancient wisdom. an ancient venerable belief that that is almost religious in nature and it gets just tossed out and essentially every idea that came down from the from the ancients is contested and it is put to the test and people confronted with data with evidence with logic with mathematics now that you know that sounds sort of totally how can you do it any other way And the answer is, basically everybody does it the other way. People rely on the wisdom of earlier generations. And if you're looking for the answer to a question that you have, just go look in the books. You know, the books could be, you know, the Bible,
Starting point is 00:04:04 or it could be Confucius, or it could be the Talmud, or it could be the Koran. You know, there are these sort of revelations of wisdom, and this is an age at which Europe sheds that. Essentially, there are no more sacred cows. So the slogan of the royal society, which is one of the paradigmatic institutions of the age, the slogan is in Nullius Verba. It's Latin for no one's word.
Starting point is 00:04:35 Skepticism and contestability become essentially the key words of intellectual activity. And that's still true today. I have a question about that and how that applies today, because one of the interesting things that we confront when we think about what you're just describing to me is actually very analogous even the business world. You have incumbents and you have new sort of upstarts or startups going against like, you know, established knowledge and the way of doing things. Part of the contestability and skepticism is about criticizing and not taking what's given as a given. But there is also an element when you're building a company or if you're pushing forward an idea back then to now where there's also a collaborative element where there's trust
Starting point is 00:05:13 that goes with that skepticism. So what is the role of trust and pushing forward this engine of creativity? That's a really good question. We should realize that much of the knowledge created at that time is created by single individuals. There's not that much collaboration, you know, co-authorship and these are multiple names on papers and books that we see today. That wasn't very much, that was quite uncommon in those days. But what happens is that, you know, knowledge has to be circulated. It has to be distributed. it. And what is created in Europe is a virtual network. And that plays a very important role in this
Starting point is 00:05:54 book, which is known as the Republic of Letters. The Respublica literaria, as they call it in Latin. And what it is, it's a sort of a virtual network. It's not a formal organization. There is no bricks and mortar institutions involved, but it's based on a network of people who write letters to each other, who correspond. They publish books and they read each other's books. And the reason that Trust emerges is because that everybody knows that if you publish something or some discovery, some mathematical theorem that you have proven or some planet you've discovered or some new species that you found, that others will look at it because they know that this has been vetted by other experts. And so if it survives, that means you must go right.
Starting point is 00:06:39 Trust is created by the fact that experts and specialists and learned people talk to each other, communicate with each other, and essentially spread their ideas around. I'm never one to yearn for a past that never really was, but I can't help but wonder if that was a more civil time because what you're really describing is essentially a market of ideas. And you describe this funny quote from one of those people where I very humbly beg of all those whose opinion I have attacked, perhaps at too much liberty, not to take it in a bad way, since I have most often done this only to invite them to do the same to mine. This philosophical war will likely cost a bit of ink, but there will be no spilling of blood.
Starting point is 00:07:22 And I think it's a very telling quote because it's in stark contrast to a lot of what's happening and playing out today. I mean, just to sharpen the contrast of what you're describing between then and now. I guess I see a certain similarity there as well. The notion that this was kind of an harmonious, sort of friendly organization in which all these scientists were sitting around the campfire and singing kumbaya, that clearly isn't the case. There was jealousy, there was rivalry, there was vindictiveness, just as there is today. I mean, even down to credit, right? It's very similar to today where we talk about who had the idea first.
Starting point is 00:08:00 What really matters is who took it to market and executed on it well. So it is really interesting that when you think about authorship and the previous models of knowledge, that were produced, that it's not necessarily the person who received credit is the person who was like the first to discover it or like say it, you know, talk about it or label it, but the one who really sold it effectively in this market for ideas. And very much like today, there are priority fights. You know, now, so, you know, just as there's this big priority fight today about who's the first to discover Chris C-A-S-9, you know, the new... Christopher, right. Oh, gosh, I'm a topic, right. I just heard a talk about. about that yesterday he had Northwestern. But, you know, there's a very famous priority fight between two of the giants of the age, Isaac Newton and Leibniz, about who invented calculus. Basically, each of them argued that the other one stolen from him. And it got to be quite ugly, just as it sometimes
Starting point is 00:08:57 gets today. I actually think much like today, what made progress possible in this market for ideas is that it was a competitive market. And one thing economists know, competitive markets, by and large, work better than uncompetitive markets. And what is critical in understanding about the European system is how competitive it was. There are literally scores of countries and states and cities that compete with one another. Competition may not be much fun for the people engaged in it, but it produces the results. Right.
Starting point is 00:09:35 But a key enabler behind. that competitive market for ideas or any competitive market, for that matter, is a certain symmetry of information or transparency. I mean, a lot of what matters here is a role of reputation, there's peer assessment, there's a lot of ways of sort of assigning credibility in the marketplace of ideas. And this is even true in the internet today when you think about the internet as like a massive enabler for this kind of openness and transparency. But the key word and that you're going to hit the nail on the head there is reputation, because you need to build a reputation among your peers if you're going to get patronage.
Starting point is 00:10:09 I mean, that is still true today. That's what the authorship model is, right? I mean, that's what peer review is at the end of the day. The way my university and any other university gives tenure is they look at your reputation. That's how these things are being decided. And so Joe Blow has the incentive to publish as much as he can because that's how he gains a reputation. And so everything is put out there in the open. And, you know, if you're writing open source software, it isn't any different.
Starting point is 00:10:37 And it's interesting, though, because it was still a very small proportion of the population. It wasn't as egalitarian as one might think based on this beautiful idea of a marketplace of ideas. I mean, yes, it's a different type of egalitarianism because the credibility is not bestowed based on family connections or how much money you have, but more about the meritocracy of your ideas and creativity. But it still was a very elite phenomenon. And even when we think about credentialed institutions today, there is a certain elitism associated with that. I think what's really interesting about the internet and the production of knowledge on the internet is that there are unknown names that are essentially building credibility reputation now in a completely different way. It's not necessarily leveled it equally, but it's definitely created a far more equal level playing field than ever before for that kind of knowledge. Well, yes and no. You're right. The internet has changed the rules of the game in a dramatic way.
Starting point is 00:11:27 all the same, it remains true that the number of people who are pushing the envelope, who are really making advances, is still probably quite small. And I would guess that internet or no internet, a disproportionate number of them come from a dozen institutions such as Caltech, MIT, Stanford, Carnegie Mellon, you know, and northwest in places like that. Now, that doesn't mean that new people coming out of nowhere or college dropouts, you know, you know, people like Bill Gates. Even he comes from a long history of coding as a child,
Starting point is 00:12:04 just not in their traditional system. Exactly. And in some ways, the period I'm looking at when there's similar transformation is the printing press. So all of a sudden, somebody can come out of nowhere and publish a book that everybody takes notice of. Right. But even still, like the friction, I mean, the friction of creating knowledge.
Starting point is 00:12:24 And I think this is a really important point you touch on. at the end of the day, knowledge is a really unusual commodity. It's a public good. It's non-excutable to others can use it. You know, the sharing, the cost of sharing is very low unless you think about things like intellectual property or patents, you know, and secrecy. But at the end of the day, it's zero marginal cost. And it's really fascinating because what the internet has done, the printing press still required a certain amount of friction, some knowledge to use it, some technical thing, access availability. You now have a situation where someone anywhere in the world, I think of our, you know, we did a podcast with entrepreneurs in Iran. And there were sanctions in place at the time and they were creating businesses on the internet. It's literally bleeding into borders and barriers in a way that's unprecedented. I think that's absolutely true. And I would certainly subscribe to the notion that our own age is in many ways totally unique. And which is why I am not really a great believer in the hypothesis that there's an awful lot we can learn from history about our own age, because our own age is so different in so many ways. But in some ways,
Starting point is 00:13:26 It's everything that you see in the time I'm looking at is true multiplied a thousand times over. Everything moves a thousand times faster, a thousand times cheaper. Yeah, it's a difference of a degree, but the degree is so huge that it becomes a difference in quality. I totally buy that. So one question I have for you, so far we've been talking a lot about knowledge and production at sort of a more individual level in this marketplace of ideas. What's the role of institutions in this, like both then and now and how do you see that evolution happening? Well, so the way we think about institutions today is that we don't really think about them as the state or any sort of formal organization.
Starting point is 00:14:04 Institutions are ways in which we set the rules of behavior that individuals observe when they're active in the marketplace, but also when they're playing basketball or something. The institution that I am interested in here are the institutions that govern the markets for ideas. And you get two kinds of institutions. You get national institutions and you get transnational institutions. And my way of thinking about it is that the national institutions probably play a relatively secondary role. Quite frankly, you know, if you put a gun to my head, I would say what happened, happened despite the best efforts of these states, not thanks to them.
Starting point is 00:14:44 What is far more interesting, I think, is this spontaneous emergent body of the Republic of Letters. which is an institution, even though it doesn't have a headquarters and it doesn't have a CEO and nobody designed it and nobody founded it. It's a result. It's one of those spontaneous virtual networks, a little bit, if you want, like our virtual communities today. You know, honestly, when I was reading about your ideas of the Republic of Letters,
Starting point is 00:15:16 this sort of epistolary knowledge world, the first thought that jumped into my mind was actually the early days of Internet at the blogosphere where you had this, you know, bloggers in a smaller community exchanging ideas back and forth was literally the Republic of Letters. And it was similarly elitist in the sense that a small proportion of the population was doing it. Not everybody was doing it, but it was based on this meritocracy of ideas and creativity, then past connections and everything else. Excellent analogy.
Starting point is 00:15:42 And I totally agree with you. And you will see that these blogs, blogosphere was not set up by any individual. It wasn't designed. Nobody would have dreamed it at the time. Out of that came our modern world. Out of that came every technological advance that made a big difference in electricity, in textiles, in steel, in, you know, in transportation, in medicine, you name, it came all out of those interactions. And that's basically the central message of my book. It's a weirdly unexplained driver of the Industrial Revolution.
Starting point is 00:16:16 People usually fixate on the more obvious things like the printing press, et cetera. And the equivalent today, the online communities, these makers, these early indies that help push and share ideas in the spontaneous virtual world, arguably are also the drivers, a lot of our tech advances today. I think we could even make that same kind of inferential leap. So my question for you was, what are the biggest enablers of that both then and now? Because one of the, besides the things that we've talked about so far, one of the things that really stuck out to me and it's a favorite concept of mine, I know it's credited originally to Granavetter, but I remember it from Ron Burt's work, this idea of structural holes and this
Starting point is 00:16:50 the importance of weak ties versus strong ties and being able to exploit these ideas? Like, what role does that play? Well, so I use some of my former colleague, Mark Granovellers, work in this, and I think you're absolutely right. What you get in the Republic of Letters is a bunch of people spread all over a continent. Remember, transportation at the time was slow and difficult.
Starting point is 00:17:14 So if you live in Warsaw and somebody else lives in London, they could well be living on the moon. You know, you'd never meet these people. They don't have any obvious reason to trust each other very deeply. But what is happening is that because of these weak ties, as Granavetta points out, you actually learn more from each other. At Xerox Park, one of the things that we used to talk about a lot is that the most interesting innovations, and they produce innovations over and over and over again.
Starting point is 00:17:39 It wasn't just one time happened at the interstitials between disciplines and weak ties in networks. And you make this statement of this idea that progress occurs at the margin. And I wanted you to explain what you meant by that, because that was a very fascinating concept to me. Well, I think what happens in many fields is that they tend very quickly to reach a situation in which progress becomes rather incremental and that people basically take the sort of sense. Well, what we know is basically the older is to know. And so we can sort of make little small steps in it, but not really step outside. and make a huge quantum leap into the unknown.
Starting point is 00:18:24 And in order to do that, you need either one of the two things. Either you need to recombine two different fields, you need to acknowledge from one field and transplant it into another so that it becomes a completely different way of thinking. I mean, that's the kind of thing that happens with the Newtonian Revolution or later on with Einstein. Actually, today, an example I would think of is with deep learning and computer science, this opportunity of training data on much smaller data sets
Starting point is 00:18:51 and barring from the worlds of developmental psychology in order to see how a computer could truly learn like a child. That's a brilliant example. I think that's exactly the kind of thing that I'm thinking of. So you look at my own field of economics, you know. And, you know, the last, I think, 20, 25 years, almost all of the major breakthroughs have occurred by people coming in with ideas from psychology
Starting point is 00:19:12 or from mathematics and basically introducing these into economics. So the major changes in economics just to give you this one example have happened through game theory. And game theory was originally devised by mathematicians to solve very, very simple and situations unrelated to economics.
Starting point is 00:19:33 Or Khanaman and Turski with like the ideas of prospect theory versus utility. That's exactly right. So these people coming from psychology, both Kanemann and Tversky are trained psychologists, and they're sort of coming to economics from the outside. And John Nash, who won the Nobel Prize and economics for his contribution to game theory, comes to it from mathematics.
Starting point is 00:19:53 And so they say people like, say, John von Neumann and so on and so forth. And I think this has been happening across the board. And even in the humanities, that's what's happening. You look at major transformations in, say, history, which is my other area, and a lot of it comes from people in philosophy. So that's how major steps forward happen. And I think if you leave a field to its own devices and without interacting with other fields, eventually it will start to stagnate. But of course, that doesn't happen in a competitive market for ideas because they're always sort of wise guys who say, hey, you know what, I'm going to study chemistry, then apply my knowledge in chemistry to, I don't know what, biology.
Starting point is 00:20:36 Today's wise guys might be computer scientists who, and I sometimes make fun of this. will think that they can take on any industry and any problem. And frankly, it's true. You can do things like bring that mindset to biology, to health care, everything related to new areas. But I want to make one more point since you asked me, and you asked me, what's enabling this? And I already talked about competition. Just one more thing, because this is something that happens throughout history. Success in making breakthroughs in science and technology often depends on focus.
Starting point is 00:21:08 that's to say people have to agree that a particular issue, a particular question is something that we need to solve or a particular technological bottleneck is something that's really bothering us. And so, for instance, at this time, one of the big issues, this is a seafaring time, and everybody has a problem with measuring longitude. Columbus sailed across the oceans, not never knowing where he was longitude-wise, you could only measure latitude. So this is a big issue, and everybody knows it.
Starting point is 00:21:38 and ships get wrecked and so on and so slowly but certainly society puts its minds together to solve the issue of longitude and it's not an easy problem it takes centuries but they crack it and the same is true for something entirely different
Starting point is 00:21:55 but also as a big issue smallpox so smallpox is a real scourge of this age and people feared it greatly not only because it killed people but also because it disfigured them so the age puts its mind in fighting smallpox.
Starting point is 00:22:09 And lo and behold, they quack it. Again, it takes a long time. There are lots of false starts and, you know, half-hearted. But in the end, smallpox get conquered. And this is something that happens throughout history,
Starting point is 00:22:23 all the way down to Project Manhattan, you know, and on and on. So it's something that we think we can do and it needs to be done urgently that becomes a focus of intellectual activity. And I think our own age, is going to go through a similar thing as climate change becomes more and more the central issue that the human race is coping with.
Starting point is 00:22:47 I actually think it doesn't only apply to problems to be solved, but even areas of opportunity like the focus now on Mars that isn't necessarily being driven by government but private sector, which I think is really fascinating. And that is where an enormous amount of human ingenuity is focused on. And this kind of pattern, I see repeated again and again and again. And by this kind of pattern, you mean the focus on intellectual activity. The focus of intellectual activity, the best minds in the world. I mean, look what happens with polio or with AIDS.
Starting point is 00:23:20 Same thing. You know, a disease pops up and everybody goes, oh, my God, you know, this disease becomes a threat to us. And so we put our best minds to it. We took our best tools, not always within people's capability. So when the black death occurs in Europe in the 14th century, you know, they had no clue what it was that hit them. They had no tools. They had no idea what was causing this.
Starting point is 00:23:42 And so instead of preventing the problem, they killed the Jews because they saw the Jews were poisoning the wells. So, you know, we should hope that that does not happen, finding a scapegoat instead of a solution. That's really important reminder to think about. Here's another thing that people really focus attention on defeating gravity. So flying. They couldn't build airplanes. because for an airplane, there's certain things that they didn't have. But what they did invent, albeit late in the 18th century, is hot air balloons.
Starting point is 00:24:13 Ballooning is the first real triumph by which the human race defeats gravity. But they've been thinking about this since days immemorial. I mean, think about the Greek mythology of deadless and all. I can tell you stories about medieval monks, you know, building themselves wings and jumping off church towers, breaking their legs. I mean, people have been dreaming about flying. Even beyond the Western knowledge sphere, there's so many wonderful examples coming out of Asia, in China, India, as well, where there's a lot of ancient, like, work in that area. Everybody tries it and, you know, and then all of a sudden, a bunch of Frenchmen basically say, hey, you know what, if we heat air, the air expands, it becomes lighter than the air around it, it will go up.
Starting point is 00:24:56 It seems obvious on the surface, but this idea that you can actually truly solve anything by putting focus on it, we again, take that for granted. And I think that's really important. You have this newest book talking about the drivers and the cultural that drove the cultural progress of this, you know, unprecedented industrial revolution. And we're talking about today as being a different time, again, maybe a difference of degree that becomes so much a difference of kind because of the sheer degree. How would you think about the role of technology today and what's playing out? Should people not, because there's a lot of fear, I think, from a lot of people. Like, should they not consider the cost of technology advances? how do you think of what you've learned from the past, how can we sort of apply it to now?
Starting point is 00:25:37 This is a big question. And I've thought about the great lengths. I must say before I engage in this, that by and large, the lessons we learn from history are fairly limited to the period what we're talking about. Extrapolating the lessons from one period to another period is extraordinarily dangerous. But what I would say is that one of the obvious things that screams, at you. When you're looking at the economic history of technology is that almost every
Starting point is 00:26:07 technology that's ever been introduced has had unexpected, unintended, unforeseen consequences. This is a pattern that goes through history. People notice, they may say, well, maybe we should just stop
Starting point is 00:26:23 innovating because there's always something bad is going to happen. And I think that is an extremely dangerous conclusion to draw. The alternative to not to not innovating is stagnation. And I don't think we can afford that. We cannot afford that because the world has major problems that can only be resolved by new technology.
Starting point is 00:26:45 And of that, I think primarily of climate change. Because climate change cannot be solved by any means except technology because a political solution is clearly not going to happen. Not doing it is worse. and that I think is the great lesson that history teaches us. If any nation is going to decide to not innovate because they're like stability, they will end up like 19th century China.
Starting point is 00:27:12 19th century China wanted stability. The West wanted progress. I was just thinking and look at them today. I mean, talk about a culture of growth. It's an origin of the modern economy happening right now in a weird way, even though it's a very ancient society. It's a very ancient society. but it all happened the last 30 years because between 1850 and 1950 China was not growing
Starting point is 00:27:34 and wasn't developing and it wasn't catching up and then of course you get communism for another 25 years that's even worse but at some point the Chinese get themselves together and they start growing they still have a long way to go but clearly stagnation is not something that's in the cards for them and I think the West is going to decide to stop innovating which of course will never happen Sometimes you think about the political climate and frankly, you know, there are certain rules of law and conditions that need to be in place to support innovation. And it is a little frightening to think that that could be, if not stopped, slow down in comparison to, you know, a place like China where it's like the Industrial Revolution is playing out like right now. I am just as frightened as you are and many of these things worry me and in some ways defy my understanding, you know, like one of the things that defies my understanding is there. inexplicable resistance of many nations to genetically modified organisms, which, you know,
Starting point is 00:28:33 the evidence does not support it as any danger. This whole notion about Franken Foods is completely made up, but people just keep going, resisting this. I actually don't think it's wrong for, like, as we've talked about, for people to consider the consequences and think about, you know, some of the third, you know, the second and third order effects. But the reality is we've discussed is you never actually know how those things play out. And you can think about them, but that doesn't mean you should actually preemptively stop them,
Starting point is 00:29:00 which is, I think, what happens a ton with Europe. And frankly, if you look at Europe in the era of the Industrial Revolution and today, it's quite a stark contrast. It is indeed. They say, why should we grow? You know, we're happy as we are. I don't need more income per capita. You talk a lot about this tension between growth and stagnation.
Starting point is 00:29:16 And we talk a lot about how the previous drivers of this were basically material prosperity in terms of measuring progress. But a lot of our progress today is sort of dematerialized. And so it begs, of course, the question of how do we actually measure that progress? And there's a lot of debates around the notion of measuring GDP. And I'd love to hear your thoughts on that. Well, there's a growing literature on missing growth. And as I see it, the main reason is that the relative importance of product innovation
Starting point is 00:29:44 compared to process innovation is rising. We have new things appearing on the horizon or vastly improved things, which is the main form technological change takes today. not nearly as good at making the same things we used to make before, only cheaper, which is what standard productivity measurement usually does. And so we are mismasuring growth. Or to put a slightly different, we're overmeasuring inflation because those two things boil down to the same thing.
Starting point is 00:30:16 And we've known this for a long time. But it turns out the process is getting worse and worse, simply because so many new products appear on the market, that costs nothing. And that's good for us, but it's bad for national income accounting, because if they cost nothing, then how, you know, then how do we enter them? What's the value that we put on them in the international income account? So if you look at something that we all use. Wikipedia is a great example. What's the contribution of Wikipedia to GDP was nothing because you're ever having you click on it. You're not charged. And that's the best thing about Wikipedia, right? But that means it's of great value to us.
Starting point is 00:30:55 but it doesn't enter the national income account. And what's true for Wikipedia is true for scores of websites and services that we get. The other thing that, and this is sort of something that I'm not 100% ripe on, but, you know, there are things in life that are subject to technological change that never show up in the national income account. And I think of these as sort of transactions cost in consumption. So here let me give you an example. on. What is the full cost of going to the store and buying a gallon of milk? The transaction that's
Starting point is 00:31:32 recorded is $3.19 or whatever for one gallon of milk, that's what entering the national income account. Of course, that's not the full cost that you pay because you have to spend your time driving to the store. You're using up, you know, gasoline and you're wearing, you know, wear and tear in your car. And then it's not just the time getting there. There's the time of standing in line in front and so on and so forth. The cost is actually higher than the $3.19 that you pay for the milk. But they don't get measured. And as long as they don't change, that's okay because then it's just a constant that's dropping out.
Starting point is 00:32:06 And so, you know, but suppose that shopping became easier and easier because you no longer have to run your bottle of milk through a cashier who actually has to look at the price and then punch it in, but you run it through a barcode reader. You just run it to an automatic cash register or even better. You order it online, and it just arrives at your doorstep. Well, then the cost for you have come down, so you're better off. It doesn't get registered anywhere in the national income accounts. And this is true for thousands of things that we do every day.
Starting point is 00:32:39 Everything gets, in some sense, easier. The one thing I always detested has been shoe shopping. I hate it because I have 11.5 shoe size, and most stores only have 11 and 12. And then the only pet have an 11-5 and this kind of pluggy, ugly brown shoes that I want. They have to drive to a different store and so on. Now I go online and I basically click 11 and a half. And, you know, two days later, it's sitting in front of my door. You know, that is a major improvement in what I call consumption transactions cost.
Starting point is 00:33:11 Because the transactions cost were for me to go from store to store, gets frustrated, stand in line, not find the stuff, you know, and on, no, it doesn't happen anymore. Using that mindset, frankly, even Netflix binge watching is an amazingly incredible thing, but that's not being recorded in any way. It's not being recorded. And that's precisely. So here's another example, which I take something like Spotify. What Spotify gives me is not only something that is extremely inexpensive or virtually free, but it also gives me a variety. And again, variety is something that national income accounting cannot deal with.
Starting point is 00:33:46 They can deal with... Variety gets so overlooked when we talk about this topic. Measurement GDP in the past, like the efficiency would have been more important than something like recording the variety. Yeah, exactly. The whole GDP accounting system that we have today was designed for an economy that produced wheat and steel. And so progress occurs because you can produce a bushel of wheat or a ton of steel with less capital and less labor than last year. And so that's how we measure total factor. productivity, it's sort of the difference between the growth of output and the difference
Starting point is 00:34:22 of the dose of input. But if the output, nature is changing, either in fact that it is much better than it used to be, or because it is very different, or it has more variety, something that wasn't there in the first place. You look at the way cellular phones were 20 years ago and what a cellular phone does today, you know, when looking at the decline in price, we'll tell you nothing. My cellular phone today does things that nothing could do 20 years ago. Here's one more point I'd like to make because it's often overlooked.
Starting point is 00:34:54 And that is what's happening to leisure. Look at the amount of spectator sports available. So I'm saying this in a city where the baseball team finally made it both serious. It's because of technology. It's because people have access. People can watch this on the telephones, on their televisions, on, you know, I don't know what day. It's all over the place. And that is, in my judgment, a major improvement in people's lives.
Starting point is 00:35:22 I mean, this is something they enjoy, they find interesting. It fills them with a sense of satisfaction. We didn't have anything like that before. So how does this show up in an national income accounting? So these are the issues, I think, that we need to struggle with if we're going to assess what technology does to our lives. There's a very large number of nations in the world who are still struggling with. with poverty. But more seriously, eventually we need to keep science and technology advancing because new problems are cropping up on the horizon. Why are the ice caps at the poles
Starting point is 00:35:57 belting? And these are the problems of our time. We just should all read your book. And while I understand we have to be careful about how we extrapolate from history, we can certainly learn a lot from it. And it really sheds light even on our modern world in new ways. And I want to thank you for joining the A6 and Z podcast. It's been an absolute delight.

There aren't comments yet for this episode. Click on any sentence in the transcript to leave a comment.