Call Me Back - with Dan Senor - The Summer of Shortages - with Scott Lincicome
Episode Date: July 28, 2022Air travel this summer seems broken. On some days, major airlines have been canceling 10 percent of their flights. In normal times, it’s something like one in a hundred that are canceled. How di...d this happen? Is there an explanation beyond just the obvious – which is the turbocharged rebound from the past two years of pandemic-induced turmoil in the airline industry? Today’s guest thinks there’s something else going on that the post-covid travel summer has simply revealed. It’s a structural problem that predated the pandemic, and he also sees similar forces at work in other industries, including the baby formula crisis. It’s the structural roots of crises of scarcity that we get at today, with Scott Lincicome. Scott is at the CATO Institute, a Washington think tank, where’s he’s the director of General Economics & Trade Policy Studies. He’s also a visiting lecturer at Duke University Law School, and spent two decades as a trade law negotiator, advising some of the largest multinationals. He also writes a Substack called “Capitolism”. And he’s with The Dispatch news & analysis site.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
As you all probably know, air travel this summer is broken.
On some days, major airlines have been canceling 10% of their flights.
You show up at the airport, security lines lasting four, five, even six hours. But at least
you're hoping that you're not booked on a flight that is among the one in ten flights canceled.
Keep in mind, in normal times, it's something like one in a hundred that are canceled. So from
one percent of flights canceled in normal times to ten percent now. Now, how did this happen?
Is there an explanation beyond just the obvious, which is the turbocharged rebound from the past two years of pandemic-induced turmoil in the airline industry?
After 9-11, we saw a single-digit percentage decline in air travel in the year or so afterwards.
In 2020, during peak pandemic, the drop was north of 70%, so consumer demand has come barreling back after the entire industry was
all but shut down. So of course there was going to be some inevitable stress on the system.
But today's guest thinks that there's something else going on that the post-COVID travel summer
has revealed. It's a structural problem that predated the pandemic. And he also sees similar
forces at work in other industries,
including the baby formula crisis. It's the structural roots of crises of scarcity that we get at in today's conversation with Scott Lincecum. Scott is at the Cato Institute,
a Washington think tank, where he's the director of general economics and trade policy studies.
He's also a visiting lecturer at Duke University Law School and spent two decades
as a trade law negotiator, advising some of the largest multinationals. He also writes an
indispensable substack called Capitalism. Capital, with an O in the middle. We'll post it in the show
notes. I highly recommend that you subscribe to it. And Scott is also with The Dispatch, a news and policy and political
analysis site. The summer of shortages, what's really going on? This is Call Me Back.
Scott, welcome to the conversation. Thanks for having me.
All right. So, Scott, I inhale what you write about badly needed public policy reforms, especially as it relates to our economy, before the pandemic, but especially during the pandemic. pandemic sparked or a pandemic catalyzed crisis which is what we're all dealing with this summer
for anyone who's tried to travel by air commercial air travel uh seems to be in a crisis
and i you've written a lot about what's happening and then like what's really happening so let's
before we get to what's really happening let let's start with what's happening. Because like on the surface, it looks like, I mean, as I said in the introduction, you
know, I went through some of the data, you know, normally you get like 1% of flights
domestically in the U.S. on major carriers being canceled.
And now depending on the day or the week, you're somewhere between 8, 10, 12, in some
cases, 14% of flights being canceled in a given day.
So the number of cancellations has gone up exponentially this summer.
And like I said, on the surface, it just looks like the economy shut down and therefore air
travel shut down, or big parts of the economy, but specifically air travel shut down during
second half of 2020, 2021, beginning of 2022.
So demand goes down, supply therefore goes down, and then demand comes barreling back this summer. And supply just hasn't caught up with the demand.
So can you just first talk about that this is just, is this just a normal trajectory coming
out of the pandemic for just about any industry for which there was lower demand during
the peak of the pandemic. And you're right. I mean, some of this is very much your classic
pandemic story. When everybody stopped traveling, the airlines shuttered capacities. So they,
you know, idled workers, put them on furlough or had them some early retirement for pilots and the rest.
And then all of a sudden, faster than expected, demand roared back this spring.
Everybody was sick of being stuck in their houses and in their towns and they wanted to fly.
And they, of course, fueled a bit by stimulus and good old monetary
policy, but also just stopping. We were all buying goods and now we're back to buying services.
That kind of demand also rushed back as well. And airlines just simply could not get things up and
running again most quickly. And the biggest issue was again, um, on the, on the labor
side of things. Okay. So what, so where the shortages were that they, that they, uh, reduced
the airlines reduced during the pandemic were pilots, crews, baggage handlers, maintenance.
And even at the, even on the regulatory level, uh, air traffic controllers and stuff also. And so really
severe staffing shortages across the industry. But I think the biggest one is pilots because
a lot of pilots went into early retirement and that was encouraged by the airlines.
And then when they needed, there was intense demand for pilots. Well, pilots in the United States need a
lot of training and by regulation. And we can, you know, you can debate whether that's needed,
whatever, but that's, that's the rule. Well, no, it's an important point though,
because to be a U.S. certified, a U.S. licensed commercial pilot, you have to do
a minimum of 1500 hours of flying before you can be hired by an airline, right?
Right.
And that was increased dramatically after there was an air accident several years ago.
And that increased, Congress increased the requirements dramatically.
People in the aviation industry will disagree about this, but I think most would say that
that number is sort of ridiculous, that
it's really about the type of training you get, not the number of hours you get. But look, I mean,
and 1,500 hours is a lot of training. You just simply can't snap your fingers and get new pilots.
And the U.S. number on the number of hours is considerably higher than
countries in other parts of the world, specifically Europe.
Right. Exactly. And, you know, the airlines have looked at bringing in foreign pilots.
We have a small immigration program for the U.S.-Australia FTA that lets certain pilots, Australian-trained pilots, come here.
It's really small. And let's face it, it's Australia. It's not going to do the trick. And so there's been a really dramatic staffing shortage. But that again,
I mean, regulatory stuff aside, that is a very classic pandemic story. Intense demand,
you don't have the supply, you can't find the workers, add the training bit in there
that adds to the problem. That's your pandemic story.
Okay, but just before we move off that, though, two questions.
One, if you furlough pilots,
and can't you then try to rehire those pilots?
They're already trained,
and they seem like much more of a turnkey solution than relying on newly trained and licensed pilots.
And that's what I think has been going on, is airlines have been trying to coax pilots
out of retirement.
And that has happened, but it just doesn't happen very quickly.
So you hear that the projections are that this will eventually get better, but it's just, you know,
it's a wave of demand hitting a pretty slow moving supply adjustment. And so you're just
going to get these problems. And then of course, you know, look, you have other pandemic related
problems in the supply chains on the repair and maintenance side of things,
on getting equipment, on jet fuel prices. I mean, you name it. There's just a lot of this stuff
that's gumming up the industry and preventing the supply side from adjusting really, really quickly.
The federal government bailed out something to the tune of about 50 billion with a B, billion dollars during the
pandemic of the airline industry. What was that money supposed to be used for?
It was supposed to be used to keep the workers employed. And this goes a little bit out of my
specialty, but it's my understanding.
I think there's going to be some hard looks at where that money went and how it was spent.
Because, again, some of the stuff I've read about this is that they were paid basically early retirement packages.
Some of that money, instead of keeping them actually employed, it was basically to get them off the books, right?
And that goes back to like a lot of industries, auto industry this crisis this summer that aren't necessarily related to the pandemic.
I mean, they are exacerbated by the pandemic, but they existed and their roots lay long before the pandemic.
So before we get to that, can you just, for purposes of background for our listeners and
for me, can you talk about the deregulation of the airline industry in the 1970s and why
that was so important before we get to what we're dealing with now. So the United States airline industry back in the golden era of flight, you know, we see all those
hilarious pictures of people in suits smoking cigarettes and having, you know, Chateaubriand
on those airplanes. Well, the golden age of flight was not so golden for most people. Prices were insanely high on an inflation-adjusted basis.
There weren't a lot of carriers. There weren't a lot of routes. So as part of the unheralded
Carter-era deregulation, and then going into the Reagan-era too, the airline industry was
dramatically deregulated in terms of controlling prices,
so controlling fares, and in terms of allowing new market entrance, deregulating the types of
routes and where planes can go. It used to be basically the market was all carved up and fares were set, and that was it. So all of that was deregulated in the late 70s and 80s.
And the result was a really wonderful free market success.
Not only did fares drop dramatically, but also routes increased.
So we now had planes flying to a lot of places
that there used to not be planes flying.
You had, and air travel in general
became widely accessible to the masses.
Now we certainly today complain
about having to pay baggage fees
and about long lines and stuff.
But essentially,
the market did what the market does, and that is kind of commodify air travel, making it accessible
to the common man. So if you look at statistics on the price of a commercial fare, or sorry, economy fare. And you see that, you know, there's really been a
dramatic decline in inflation adjusted terms over the year. If you look at just nominal terms,
it's been about the same price for the last couple of decades, which is really incredible.
And that even for high cost, you know, first class business travel stuff, it's about the same price as
it was back in the day.
And business first class travel is basically comparable to what it was back in the day.
So you can still get that level of service.
I mean, other than the smoking cigarettes and that kind of thing, you can still get
that level of service.
But now everybody else can fly, too.
So it's been pretty impressive.
Now, that said, all of those deregulatory benefits slowed down, other than prices, slowed down pretty substantially about 10, 15 years ago or so.
We actually saw, because airlines, there was a lot of
consolidation in the industry, we saw airlines adopting this hub and spoke model where, you know,
you have just a couple major airports and then airports, you know, the airlines fly into that
and fly out to smaller destinations. You started to see after years and years of increasing routes and increasing availability,
starting to see some consolidation and actually a reduction in routes.
And so while prices have continued to be pretty good and quite accessible, there have been
some warning signs in the industry, particularly related to market concentration and, again, the reduction in the number of available flights.
Okay, and that then set up a perfect storm or contributed to the perfect storm that we have right now for this summer.
So can you explain what a cabotage law is?
And then we'll talk specifically about how it manifests itself in the airline industry. But what is a cabotage law is, and then we'll talk specifically about how it manifests itself in the airline
industry. But what is a Cabotage law? So Cabotage, a very funny word, looks like
sabotage, just with a C, essentially is restrictions on transport of goods or individuals
by various means of transportation. In this case, we're talking about air cabotage rules. We have similar ones for cruise ships and
container ships in the Jones Act. People might know about the Jones Act. It's been in the news a bit.
Essentially, we have the Jones Act for air travel,
for civil aviation. So wait, just can you explain what the Jones Act is? Yeah. So the Jones Act
is a law that restricts container shipping, commercial shipping between
two US ports to ships that are made in America, that are owned by Americans, that are crewed
by Americans. So we essentially have the same law for air travel. The only difference is that
the crew requirements are not there. And also, we don't have the made in America requirements.
But the big ones are that it has to be owned and operated by Americans or American companies. So essentially, that means that you're
only going to have US-based carriers operating between two US airports. And that's the key,
right? You can still fly internationally, just like the Jones Act. You can still ship
products using international shipping companies like Maersk. You can still fly internationally using foreign carriers,
British Airways, Lufthansa, whatever.
But you can't do that if you want to fly from, say, Miami to New York.
You have to use an American carrier.
So if Emirates Airline or Lufthansa or Air Canada
wanted to offer a flight, say, between New York and Miami,
and many of these airlines would like to compete in this market, they are barred by U.S. law from
being able to participate in the U.S. market domestically. Right. They would basically have
to create a U.S. shell company, and there's a lot of stats because basically it's a foreign investor rule.
So the big example of this is that Richard Branson actually wanted to have Virgin Airlines
or Airways, he wanted to have Virgin running domestically.
And he looked at all these potential ways to do this, and he finally gave up because
he was simply going to have to give up too much control
of the airline to a US-based entity and said, to heck with this, I'm not going to do it.
So all of those airlines that listeners might know from traveling abroad, whether it's in the
Middle East or Asia or Europe in particular, or Canada or wherever, sorry, wherever, um, sorry, they don't, they are not allowed to operate here by
law. Um, and that as we'll, I'm sure you'll get into has significant economic implications.
Okay. So can you explain? Yes, let's get into it. So, so what are the economic implications?
Exactly. So, uh, the biggest and most obvious one is on price. If you compare and the comparison
that the experts make is if you compare the United States
with Europe, where Europe has had a modest liberalization of its air cabotage rules,
in part because of the creation of the EU, but also they've expanded this out to some of the
kind of peripheral countries that are attached to Europe, but not part of the EU. So if you compare prices in Europe versus prices in the United States for very comparable flights,
you find that prices, fares in Europe are 25 to 50 percent lower depending on the flight.
So the first big one is that cabbage rules in the United States raise prices. Now, I said at the beginning, deregulation has been great for prices,
but we don't know just how great they could be.
It could be even better if we liberalized some of the restrictions on air cabotage here.
So, for example, instead of it costing maybe $ bucks to go from atlanta to new york
it might cost 200 or whatever which is let's face it a nice nice savings for uh for for the folks
out there right um but and by the way in europe you see incredibly competitive pricing particularly
with these airlines like ryanair and whiz and easy. I mean, they're offering like $50 between Paris and London
for what seemed like crazy discounts across the board.
Yeah, and importantly, the discount airline stuff is crazy.
You're right.
I mean, $50 fare is even cheaper sometimes.
I remember I was over there once and I was stunned
that there was some deal.
It was like $20 fares or something,
which made like no sense to the American me.
But the other big thing is that it drives down good old competition doing what it does.
It drives down the fares of these legacy carriers.
So Air France, Lufthansa, BA, you name it, they're forced to compete.
And they offer – it is a different quality of service. There's no doubt, right? I mean, Ryanair is, is basically a bus with wings,
which I think this is what exactly what the CEO called it. Um, but, uh, so, so the,
these legacy carriers are, are not going to go that cheap, uh, but they know that they're
offering a better quality and they're still going to have to compete a bit on price. They have to make it worth passengers' time and worth their money to fly on their airlines.
And airlines, what one could think are comparable airlines in the U.S., like Spirit Air or Southwest, they don't – I mean, they're competitive, but it's nothing like what you see with these european
uh exactly no frills and they're much smaller um you know that's the other thing that even i was
startled when i was doing the research for this column is that um some of the discount airlines
now run uh more routes have more capacity than the legacy carriers. In Europe. In Europe, correct. Whereas here,
even today, even here in Raleigh, where we have a little Southwest hub, the legacy carriers
dominate. The discount guys, they can provide a little help on the price side. They're going to
be able to run to certain destinations, but they're not doing anything like what's going on in Europe.
So obviously price is an issue and would and on simply the availability of total system-wide
capacity, right? So when Europe liberalized, yes, they got lower fares, but they got tons of far
more capacity. So far more flights, far more destinations. And that is critically important right now for the United States because we're suffering
from a lack of capacity.
And in fact, there are big problems out in smaller places, smaller airports out west.
They can't even get carriers to come to their airports anymore. The legacy carriers, American, United,
Delta, are cutting routes dramatically because they don't have the resources, they don't have
the labor. So then they're scaling back. So these airports are having to bribe legacy carriers to
service them, or they're using the federal government to
essentially force the carriers to service them because there's a law in place that simply requires
there to be air service in some of these places. So they're essentially saying you can't leave,
which is not a great business model either., air cabinage provides a potential safety valve
in this regard. You know, one of the things I write about a lot is that, you know, we tend to
think of things as US capacity and foreign capacity, but it's better to think of it as like
total global capacity, right? And to the extent you can create a larger system, you have better
opportunity to mitigate potential shocks, right? So we have a shock to domestic air capacity,
and there's the potential for having additional foreign capacity to kind of fill those fill those gaps and the primary uh objectives behind the the
air cabotage laws uh or air cabotage law is are include obviously protecting domestic carriers
so part of it's just plain old you know economic protectionism right okay yeah for sure and then what about security could an argument be made that you know
the nature of air the nature of air travel and the kind of security threats and actual uh incidents
crises security crises we've faced here in the united states around commercial air travel is
such that we we're going to have a higher standard and we are going to have some good old-fashioned protectionism, not only for economic protection of certain industries,
but to actually make sure we dramatically heighten our oversight over these players
that are coming in and flying, these foreign players that are coming in and flying around
our skies. I mean, I think there's a national security
argument against unlimited air cabotage, right? I mean, I think you can come up with, even a zany
libertarian like me can envisage some sort of limitations on liberalization, right? But that doesn't really seem valid when you're talking about
large carriers from Europe or Korea and Japan and these other places, right? Where the safety
standards are the same, the jets they're flying are the same, and they're all flying Boeing,
Airbus, Embraer, those types of jets. The training is comparable.
The safety records are comparable. The vetting of the personnel operating the planes?
Yes, the vetting is comparable. And of course, you could have your own vetting. There's no
reason why there couldn't be a rule that said that foreign pilots flying here have to go through a
screening of some sort, right?
And we're already allowing these airlines to fly into the United States.
So it's not like they're being kept out. They're already flying into the United States because the cabage laws does not affect international travel.
And they're flying into the largest metro areas in the country, say maybe Chicago.
But even there, they're flying in because we of course have international flights
going inland as well. So yeah, and I think that's another great point that these things are already
happening. And it's again, very much like the Jones Act. You hear all the time, we can't have
foreign ships going from port to port, but we already do. The only difference is they're not going in between two U.S. ports. So
it's a very artificial restriction. But I think the other thing to note is that to the extent
we're worried about from a security perspective, you know, just and from a safety perspective,
you know, the age of planes, the availability of the total capacity here in the United States.
You know, the fact is that protectionism does kind of what protectionism does, and that is it discourages innovation, it discourages upkeep, it discourages, you know, the constant improvement of the facilities and the services. And so, you know, more competition
would likely produce a better industry in the long term, a safer industry as well. Although
safety's, look, safety's pretty darn good these days compared to the old and the good old days.
But there's no, you know, for somebody like me who flies a lot, particularly on these kind of regional jets, it's not like we're flying, you know, tip top models of wonderful brand new jets out there.
And that part of the reason for that is just simply there's no reason that they don't have to compete.
Why would they provide a nice, fancy new jet for me to fly on?
Okay. So I want to pivot from air travel to the baby formula shortage, the other big
shortage news story of the summer. And obviously they're very different, although maybe not.
And so I just, so for starters, we're experiencing the context of the pandemic,
shortages, we're hearing about shortages of chips, computer chips, semiconductors of used cars. I mean, just every other week, there's a new story of some major shortage, obviously
construction supplies, um, baby formula. So what on, again, on the surface, what is the story of
the baby formula shortage? And then
I want to get into some of the regulatory issues. Well, yeah. So the surface, you again start with
the pandemic, right? Baby formula producers in the United States were expecting depressed demand
because nobody was having babies. And then when the economy bounced back and everybody started to have babies again, they were scrambling.
Producers were scrambling to catch up.
And then you throw in, again, the usual supply chain stuff, trucker shortages and the rest.
You had problems.
And then the real match that kind of set the blaze, though, was this Abbott Laboratories factory closure in Michigan.
There were a couple unfortunate infant deaths that they thought might be connected to some
Abbott baby formula. That still hasn't been totally proven, but better safe than sorry,
Abbott did this massive voluntary recall, and the FDA swoopedoped in as they do. And Abbott's biggest
facility in Michigan was shut down. Now that was in late February, early March, and it just punched
a massive hole in the U.S. market, which is 98% supplied by domestic producers. We'll get into why that is in just a sec.
But look, you punch a massive, massive hole in the supply. You have continued demand. Plus,
people start getting worried. You know, as a parent myself, you get you like your formula,
you like the formula you're on. If you start seeing those shelves get a little bare,
you're going to buy a little extra. Everybody does that. Boom. You have a big demand side problem. So that's that's again, that's very much a a pandemic story with the added factory closure, adding insult to injury.
But again, we see that the on imported infant formula from basically everywhere.
Okay, so just again, for our listeners, just think of tariffs as taxes on imports.
Yeah, sorry.
Yeah, that's all right.
So taxes on imports. if you want to buy baby formula from a foreign country, you are paying a higher price because of a tax that the U S government mandates the, the, uh, foreign supplier, the foreign brand,
uh, pay that gets priced into that product. Right. And, uh, in this case, you're looking
at effective tariff rates of around 25%.
But it's actually worse than that, because these are things we call tariff rate quotas,
which means you actually, the tariff rate gets higher as more quantity is imported.
So if you're an importer and you aren't sure about whether you're going to trigger that higher duty, what are you going to do?
You're not going to import, right?
So that's a further, that uncertainty further discourages importation. So that's our first wall around the country. But we also have really onerous FDA regulations
related to infant formula. In the United States, we regulate infant formula more like a pharmaceutical
than a food product. We're one of the only countries that does that. But the FDA also has very strict rules on labeling and scoop size and, of course,
nutritional information and the rest. And those rules are a non-tariff barrier to imports and
have really created, combined with the tariffs, an effective blockade on imported formula.
So if a foreign producer of baby formula wants to compete in the U.S. market, they have to go through this, what some would argue, an onerous FDA process in order to play in the market.
Right. At the very least, we can say it's a costly and time-consuming process,
right? Even though those producers' products have been approved in their countries where there are
regulatory bodies that are well-respected by the FDA and are, you know, in other contexts,
we'd be perfectly prepared to recognize the approvals given to other products by those
regulatory bodies in other countries. Yeah. And where there are Americans clamoring
for these products, there is demand for that product. So the big producer, big region here
that everybody's talking about is Europe. So Europe is the largest formula producing region in
the world. Europe exports a ton of formula around the world. There is high demand for European baby
formula in the United States. But like we said, there is no European formula here, I mean, until
very recently, because of the combination of tariffs and FDA requirements.
Manufacturers in Europe simply said, you know, to heck with this, I'm not going to, the United
States is not a growing and dynamic market for baby formula. We're not having a lot of babies
these days. And because of that, they basically have said, you know, look, we're just not going
to spend the time and expense to, you know, in the sales and distribution channels and all that kind of stuff. We need to compete in the U.S. market.
So instead, importation of baby formula from Europe has been left to third parties in kind
of a gray market and has actually resulted in there were seizures at the border by customs and
the FDA because the scoop size was wrong or the labels
were in German or Dutch or whatever. And a lot of crazy stuff like that. And again,
leaving the market to a handful of domestic producers. Now, adding insult to injury is that
the domestic market was further distorted by a welfare program, a food assistance program we call WIC, Women, Infants, and Children, part of the SNAP program.
Okay, let's just spend 30 seconds on that.
So Women, Infants, and Children is one of the largest programs from within the Department of Agriculture. and it it basically provides it's a government subsidy understandably for uh baby formula
and baby food for segments of the population that can't otherwise afford it exactly and and again
even heartless libertarians like me were like you know what feeding poor babies that's that's okay
but but it does mean that the federal government now is basically
responsible for about half of the entire infant formula market?
Yes. And there's two problems with WIC when it comes to supply chain stuff. And the first is that
WIC has grown to encompass more than half of all baby formula sales in the United States. So
we effectively have a government monopsony, we call it, right?
You know, monopolies on the producer side.
Right, so not a monopoly.
Monopoly is when the producers have all the,
there's a concentration of producers who have all the power.
Monopsony is when the buyers,
there's a concentration of buyers that have all the power.
And in this particular case,
you're saying that buying power is the federal government. Right, and so the federal government used that mon all the power. And in this particular case, you're saying that buying
power is the federal government. Right. And so the federal government used that monopsony power to
essentially lowball formula producers, requiring formula producers that want to participate in WIC
to offer discounts of up to like 90%. And look, that's a great deal for taxpayers. That saves taxpayers a lot of money.
The problem, however, is that it dramatically limits the number of players that can participate
in the WIC system because you have to offer massive upfront discounts.
Now, the government realized this.
So the government gives them some enticement to participate in the WIC program.
And that is that if you win a WIC contract,
which are administered at the state level, you get an effective WIC monopoly in that state.
It's a sole source contract. So what that means in practice is that parents that have
WIC vouchers can only buy from one producer, Abbott Laboratories, or there are a couple, Rickett is out there
as well.
And that is another concentrating effect for the domestic market, because studies have
shown that a company that wins the WIC contract ends up becoming the dominant seller in the non-WIC
market. They get preferential shelf space. They get the government street cred, right? You get
the stamp of approval and all that kind of stuff. People are very brand loyal. So if they go off the
WIC program, they stay with those brands, whatever it is. And that allows them to use that market power to effectively push out new market entrants. So you combine the WIPP program's effects with basic heavy regulation of infant formula, like I said, like a pharmaceutical, and you have like no market entrant in 15 years until just a few weeks ago. And it costs millions of dollars, hundreds of millions of dollars to meet all the FDA requirements to get up and running and years to do. And so you combine that together and we have a market that is walled off from foreign competition and concentrated domestically among a handful.
Four producers control basically the whole market here.
Now, if that sounds familiar, it should because it sounds a lot like the airline market, right?
Exactly. shouldn't be surprising. If you know the economics literature, you know that the two things that
dramatically increase market concentration are protectionism, so protection from import
competition, and regulation. So the higher the level of regulation, the fewer players you're
going to have. And then you combine the sole
source contracting and government procurement on the airline side, and boom. I mean, you have very
similar effects in terms of having a highly concentrated, but also highly fragile market.
And to be clear, fragile, you meaning we have no redundancy built into the system.
And yeah, no redundancy and no flexibility.
So what happens when you have any sort of shock,
whether it is a factory closure
or a domestic labor dispute,
if you're talking about airlines, whatever it is,
the system simply can't adjust
because there's no additional capacity.
Again, globally or domestically,
you don't have new market entrants rushing in. Normally, when you have a supply problem,
prices go up. The prices are a signal to other suppliers to enter the market. Well, we have
all these rules, tariffs, FDA regulations, cabotage rules in the airline side that don't allow new suppliers
to come in. And then the political economy is the last nugget that is very similar. And that is that
you also, when you have these, this protectionism and these regulations, you create new constituents
that are going to fight like heck to keep those protections and those regulations
in place. And so, for example, when I talk about air cabbage liberalization, the first thing you
hear is, yeah, but the legacy carriers would fight that to the death, that unions would fight that to
the death. When I talk about liberalizing the infant formula market, people say, yeah, Abbott Labs, the dairy farmers in the United States, which are very powerful, very powerful.
We would never let that happen.
And we're seeing exactly that, right?
Going back to infant formula, Congress just today, the Senate just today announced that it unanimously passed a six-month waiver of the
tariffs. But that's five months. It's been five months since we've had an infant formula crisis.
And what was Operation Fly Formula? This was the Biden administration's,
what was their initial response or initial attempt to deal with it? That's right. So immediately after the White House realized there was a crisis here,
they looked to import supplies and they initiated Operation Fly Formula, which
is a very well-intentioned idea. We're going to have military jets and commercial planes flying
in formula from all over the world. The problem is that there's the scope
of this project, of this initiative, is just simply not enough to fix the US market. This
week, I wrote an update on infant formula. And you're looking at through the middle of July,
there were about 55 million bottle, eight ounce bottle equivalents of formula brought in through Operation Fly Formula.
That sounds like a lot, except it's less than a week of US consumption. And you're talking about
store shelves that remain 30, 40, even 50% empty, just not doing the trick. And you need, again,
broader, more systemic reforms to kind of allow for the market to
have sales and distribution channels in place, to have reputable, you know, reputational
effects for consumers to actually want to buy this formula and, you know, retailer agreements,
all that kind of stuff.
It just doesn't exist.
So the government can't flip a switch.
As well-intentioned as Fly Formula is, they can't flip a switch because these are much bigger markets than something that a few C-130s can handle.
Okay. So why is government so ill-equipped to anticipate these shortage crises? I mean,
if you talk to people in the airline industry, you certainly talk to people in the auto sales industry.
I mean, this is all anecdotal, but I just remember months and months ago, they were talking about the coming shortage crisis.
They were anticipating it, those in private industry, and yet it was not on the radar at all of government.
Why?
I think it really boils down to incentives, right?
You know, whether it is grocery chains, and I've been stunned, amazed by the level of
granular real-time data we can get on infant formula store shelves, right?
I mean, infant formula is not a huge product, but yet we know exactly- They're like online trackers, right? There's these sites, right? I mean, it for me is not a huge product, but yet we know exactly-
They're like online trackers, right? There's these sites, right?
And every week Bloomberg's like, Des Moines, Iowa has 53% inventory. And you're like,
this is incredible, right? But that's because grocery stores, wholesalers, producers in the business have an intensely strong profit motive to know inventory levels, to know their supply chains, and to make sure that they can get out in front of any problems that arise.
Now, they're not perfect.
You can't stop a pandemic from happening.
You can't stop natural disasters, whatever.
But it is their jobs. It is their sole focus to know what's going on in these markets at an extremely granular level and, again, in real time. Not what the government, I mean, leaving aside, except for maybe the defense supply chain,
which, you know, DOD in that case does have a grasp on and should and has a strong motivation to do that.
Outside of that, when you're talking about commercial markets, I mean, first of all,
there's a classic Hayekian knowledge problem, right?
I mean, you're talking about millions of private actors, thousands of grocery stores and so forth and so on.
But the other thing is just simply and then the availability of information.
You know, the government when the government wants information has to ask for it generally.
Right. You know, we were trying to map semiconductor supply chains and semiconductor companies said that's proprietary.
We don't want to give that to you. We don't exactly trust you
to keep it private. When I was in private practice, I remember in being involved in a couple
government investigations, and my clients were like, there's no way in heck we're giving that
to the United States government. These were foreign companies. No way we're giving that.
I mean, you can kind of get it, right? So there is an
information problem and then an incentive problem. The government just simply doesn't have the same
motivations. This is classic, what we call public choice, right? We think of government officials,
whether they're politicians, elected officials, or bureaucrats, as being these wholly disinterested public servants that have nothing but the national interest in mind,
but the reality is they are human just like we are, and they will be concerned about their own
self-interests a lot of the time. And so you combine the informational asymmetries with the motivation and incentives, and you just don't have an entity in government that is really good at knowing, you know, seeing crises on the horizon and then adapting and sharing information when the crises hit. Before we wrap, I just want to hit one other point, which you've alluded to
earlier in this conversation, but I just want to put a kind of a fine point on it.
In much of the policy debates these days that have outflowed from the pandemic response,
there's a big push for reshoring or onshoring or whatever term you want to use, bringing supply chains into
the United States, not relying on global supply chains.
And in many industries, it makes a lot of sense given how dependent we are on certain
industries and what bad shape we were during the pandemic when we couldn't access some
of these key supplies, specifically medical supplies, some pharmaceuticals.
So I hear this now more and more.
And by the way, it's historically been a province of the left,
and now I hear it on the right,
that we need to think from a nationalist perspective
on this sort of bringing supply chains home.
And you are skeptical of that. And you think actually what we're experiencing
now is like, you know, case, you know, like it's like a case study in what can go off the rails
when you are dependent on a domestic, solely dependent on a domestic supply chain.
Sure, sure. So let me say as an initial matter, um, I am perfectly fine with private companies
deciding as many have to, uh, reshore or friend shore. That means moving them kind of nearby to
Mexico, Canada, wherever, um, certain supply chains, you know, where there is a business
case to do that, whether it is for efficiency reasons or
resiliency reasons, go for it. That is their business. They know it better than I do.
But again, to be specific, that is the private enterprise making that decision.
Exactly. And look, we're in a big debate in Washington on semiconductors right now,
but private semiconductor manufacturers have dedicated tens of billions of dollars to the
U.S. market, primarily not because they're going to get a subsidy from the federal government,
but primarily because they see the need to have more capacity in the United States. They see
a workforce and equipment and stuff, and they want to do it. There's a lot of industries
that, at least at the micro level, have decided to do that, bring it to the United States or to Mexico as well. And that's all well
and good. The macro story is still pretty muddled. I don't know if it's actually happening en masse,
but some companies are doing that. Great. Go for it. My problems come in with the forced
reshoring model, essentially using tariffs and subsidies and regulations and
procurement contracts and the rest to either coax or coerce companies to manufacture here.
And I think the reasons that my skepticism arises from three places. One is in terms of natural disasters and global pandemics and labor shortages and material shortages here in the
United States, similar to what they were having in Germany or Japan or China or wherever.
You know, certainly there were discrete issues at ports that were very specific to kind of
the global supply chain.
But a lot of the problems that affected global supply chains affected domestic supply chains
as well. But the bigger problem, I think, is that
reshoring really just trades one vulnerability. So you're no longer vulnerable to external shocks,
to foreign shocks. You're just trading that for vulnerability to domestic shock, right?
So maybe, you know, you're not vulnerable to the Fukushima disaster in Japan or China going zero COVID and shutting down its ports. You're not vulnerable to that. But you are vulnerable and, in fact, more vulnerable to, say, a freak ice storm in Texas, which shut down tons of chemical supplies here in the United States, and it's still actually rippling through certain supply chains even today in things like foam for furniture. But then also a factory closure
in Michigan can shut down a collapse, a domestic supply chain and domestic supply of infant formula.
So you're really just trading shocks. But the economics literature shows you're not just trading shocks. You actually end
up worse off. Shocks that hit nationalized supply chains, domestic shocks, actually impose greater
damage, which makes, I think, sense from kind of a basic rational logical level. You know,
when you put all your eggs in one basket, and then the basket breaks,
you have bigger problems than if your eggs are spread out all over the world. And that's,
you know, basically what the economics literature shows, that you actually become worse off. And
then, of course, you know, you're poorer in the process. You know, reshoring, protectionism,
all these things tend to raise prices. That's the whole reason why offshoring occurred in the process. Reshoring, protectionism, all these things tend to raise prices. That's the
whole reason why offshoring occurred in the first place was to deliver benefits to consumers in
terms of cheaper prices and more availability. Well, you're going to reverse all that. You're
going to get higher prices, less availability. You're going to be dedicating resources in the
United States that could go to higher productivity activities, whether it's tech or whatever,
and is going to be dedicated to lower productivity activities like low-skill manufacturing or whatever. So you end up
poorer in the process. But then the third big reason is that the reshored system that relies,
again, on government policy inevitably becomes sclerotic and inflexible.
So you go back to baby formula or airlines, and I mentioned this already, but look, to the Biden
administration's credit, they realized during the infant formula crisis that they needed to bring in
imported supplies. Even the FDA has realized, the notoriously sclerotic FDA has realized, wow, this is a pretty,
this is not good for resiliency. That was their word, not mine. That we need more import
competition to boost national resiliency. The problem is that the system just can't adapt that
quickly. You know, again, you have the political economy issues, you have protected interest groups, you have bureaucrats that like their turf, whatever it is, the system just doesn't want to adapt. And of
course, outside players can't enter the market until the system, until the policies adapt.
And then of course, you have just simple congressional inaction, right? Congress is
more of a debating society today than a legislative body.
Tweeting, tweeting society. Right, tweeting society, right. And so you combine all of those things together, and you see that
the closed system is almost impenetrable, even in times of crisis. And you know, you go back to baby
formula, where it took Congress five months to do a very simple thing like suspend tariffs for a mere six months to the end of the year on infant formula.
So for the last five months of empty shelves, we've had 25% tariffs on infant formula.
That's crazy.
But the system just doesn't work quickly to fix problems.
Whereas a open system, surely vulnerable to shocks, there's no doubt.
But the open system adapts very quickly because, as we talked about, the players in that system
have a really strong profit motive to adapt quickly. Automakers don't like empty car lots.
Grocers don't like empty store shelves.
And they are going to work like heck to do whatever they can, whether it's reshoring
or finding new suppliers or whatever, to get those supplies back in stock for consumers'
benefit as well.
And that system, for as messy and unpredictable as it is, turns out to be more resilient in the long run than the supposedly resilient protected one.
Before we let you go, what is the next shortage crisis that we're not paying attention to where we'll be talking about it the way we've been talking about baby formula and air travel?
Oh, gosh, that's tough. But the one we might have a re-crisis of sorts. But I think the one that I'm
looking at right now is West Coast port situation. You know, we had a big backup on the West Coast
ports last year, and that was a big story. But that seems to have died down. And you know,
supply chains seem to be doing a lot better. But that seems to have died down. And supply chains
seem to be doing a lot better. So I don't really see major goods shortages on the horizon, except
there are a confluence of events happening at West Coast ports right now that could really
cause some problems here in the fall. The first is that California labor law called AB5, which was
intended to turn gig economy workers into employees, has caused some pretty serious blowback
among truckers in California because its application to truckers was delayed pending
a Supreme Court case, but the Supreme Court rejected it, the case.
And now AB5 is applying to truckers who have an owner-operator independent model that has suddenly become illegal.
Now, that has pushed about 70,000 truckers in California into this zone of uncertainty,
where they don't know where they're going to work and what they're
going to do. But now you have like a thousand truckers or so are protesting at the ports.
They're protesting AB5. And a group of truckers is even blockading the port of Oakland right now.
So that is a first problem. 70,000 truckers in California, where our biggest ports are located, are now suddenly in limbo
and there's major protests.
The second big port issue out there is the unions and the ports themselves are in a labor
negotiation.
So the Longshoremen's Union out there. And that has become quite contentious, too. The contract is officially expired, but nobody has walked off the job yet. But there is a chance that if the two sides don't agree this fall, that you're going to have some sort of work stoppage, lockout or strike that would affect all West Coast ports, including L.A. Long Beach, which handles about 40% of all
container traffic in the United States. So potential crisis number two. And then third
is we have rail labor negotiations that are nationwide, but again, would have a really
particular impact on the California kind of ports out there, because a lot of rail that comes inland from there into
Chicago and the rest. And there again, the rail companies and the unions are at loggerheads. And
in fact, under U.S. rail labor regulations, the president has appointed an emergency board to try
to oversee this. But that board's cooling off period, so nobody can strike,
no lockouts, ends again in the fall. So here we have three huge labor-related events happening
all basically at the same time and all affecting the most important ports in the entire country.
So if I were to pick one area where we could potentially see some pretty serious problems in the months ahead, it would again be back out there.
Wow. Well, thank you for the good cheer.
Maybe it will work out.
I know, I know, right. We will leave it there. I'm listening to you. I'm reminded of that
essay by Tom Wolfe many decades ago called The Great Relearning, where he says these policy debates seem obvious to us and the policy prescriptions that flow from them just become the way we govern ourselves.
And they should endure, but they don't.
And then we forget and we have to relearn all over again.
And so having you on is helping me at least think about getting back to
basics. I think it's important and I have a feeling we're going to need more of it. So I hope to have
you back on. Hope you'll come back. Definitely. Thanks a lot. It was a good time.
That's our show for today. To keep up with Scott Lincecum, you can follow him on Twitter at Scott Lincecum, L-I-N-C-I-C-O-M-E.
You can also follow his work at the Cato Institute.
You can find them online or at Cato, C-A-T-O Institute.
And also, you should follow and subscribe to The Dispatch at The Dispatch, D-I-S-P-A-T-C-H. Call Me Back is produced
by Ilan Benatar. Until next time, I'm your host, Dan Senor.