Cautionary Tales with Tim Harford - Give Politicians a Raise, Smuggle Smartphones into School, and go Full Donk! Cautionary Questions with Risky Business
Episode Date: May 30, 2025Can game theory be used to win a world cup? Can you pay the way out of political corruption? And are there winning strategies in life we don't use because we're too embarrassed? Tim teams up with Nate... Silver and Maria Konnikova, poker connoisseurs and the hosts of podcast Risky Business to answer your questions, tackling everything from sports, to tariffs, to the evils of smartphones. For a full list of sources, see the show notes at timharford.com. Get ad-free episodes, plus an exclusive monthly bonus episode, to Cautionary Tales by subscribing to Pushkin+ on Apple Podcasts or Pushkin.fm. Pushkin+ subscribers can access ad-free episodes, full audiobooks exclusive binges, and bonus content for all Pushkin shows. Subscribe on Apple: apple.co/pushkinSubscribe on Pushkin: pushkin.fm/plusSee omnystudio.com/listener for privacy information.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Pushkin.
This is an iHeart Podcast.
In the fall of 1986, Ronald Reagan found himself at the center of a massive scandal that looked
like it might bring down his presidency.
It became known as the Iran-Contra affair.
The things that happened were so bizarre and insane, I can't begin to tell you.
Please do.
To hear the whole story, listen to Fiasco, Iran-Contra,
wherever you get your podcasts.
You searched for your informant you're on Contra wherever you get your podcasts. While curled up on the couch with your cat, there's more to imagine when you listen. Discover heart-pounding thrillers on Audible.
The Medal of Honor is the highest military decoration in the United States.
Recipients have done the improbable, the unexpected, showing immense bravery and sacrifice in the
name of something much bigger
than themselves.
This medal is for the men who went down that day.
On Medal of Honor, Stories of Courage, you'll hear about these heroes and what their stories
tell us about the nature of bravery.
Listen to Medal of Honor on the iHeartRadio app, Apple Podcasts, or wherever you get your
podcasts. cast, and they are here to answer questions from both sets of listeners. Nate is a political
analyst, he's the author of On The Edge, and Maria is the bestselling author of The Biggest
Bluff, How I Learned To Pay Attention, Master Myself, and Win. Both fantastic books. Both
Nate and Maria are also journalists, and they are both high stakes poker players. I'm a
journalist too, and an undercover economist,
and I'm not much of a poker player,
but between us we should have some good answers
for all of the smart questions that you've been sending in.
We will be tackling smartphones in schools,
tariffs, and how to use game theory to win at sports.
Nate, Maria, welcome to Cautionary Tales.
Thank you, Tim.
Thanks so much, Tim.
Or should it be cautionary business New Business or Risky Tales?
Risky Caution?
Risky Caution.
That's good.
You've been podcasting for how long?
About a year.
About a year.
Yeah, we're coming up on the World Series of Poker begins in every May.
And so yeah, we launched it just about a year ago when we're coming up on our second World
Series season.
Excellent.
When Nate and I are both at the final table of the main event, that'll be really great for our risky business podcast audience growth.
Would you be podcasting from the World Series if you're on the final table?
Not at the final table since there are no phones allowed.
We'll find a way.
I mean, we do have these long days, right? We both have real jobs, and then maybe you'll
do several hours of real work, quote unquote, and then play poker for 12 hours. And then
it's fine. You're 2am Mexican food hangout or something. But they're long days. We do
not get vacation when we're in Vegas, basically.
No, we do not.
Right. Enough poker chat. Let us get into the virtual postbag after we listen to the theme music
for Cautionary Tales. I am here with Nate Silva and Maria Konikova and here is a good question to start with
from listener Alex. Alex asks, have any personal experiences
or academic theories really shaped your decision making?
Let me put this one to Nate first,
and I'd love to hear what both of you think.
I would say my experience with risk taking
and decision making is very hands on.
For the most part, right, when I was a kid,
we would play fantasy baseball and have little
NFL betting pools and things like that.
Obviously, poker, there's good instructional material, but most people are ultimately largely
self-taught.
In my book, On the Edge, then game theory plays a really large role, and game theory
plays a very large role in poker.
There are now computer programs called solvers that literally have solved the Nash equilibrium
for poker. If you've seen
a beautiful mind, a lot of things in life is like, what's the game theory equilibrium of like what
traffic patterns look like in New York or how often you should eat one type of cuisine versus
another or any type of competitive situation when there are lots of optionality? I'd say game theory
is kind of the most important variable there. And game theory, we should say, is really
the use of mathematical equations
to model strategic interactions.
So a very simple example of game theory
is the game of rock, paper, scissors.
If I play rock, you're going to play paper and beat me.
If I play paper, you're going to play scissors and beat me.
And so game theory says, oh, you have to randomize. You have to have a one-third chance of playing
each strategy. I mean, that's kind of obvious. Game theory can be used to model much more
complex situations, including, famously, because it inspired one of the creators of game theory,
poker.
Yeah, I would second Nate on game theory. It was one of the pinnacles of my academic
work. And I'd also say the psychological theories of Danny Kahneman have been hugely
influential in how I think about decision making. He was an absolutely brilliant man
who really unearthed a lot of the ways that our brains misprocess, I don't think that's a word, but I'm going to make
it one, misprocess information and the biases and heuristics that we're up against. And it's
incredibly powerful because even if you know that those biases and heuristics exist in theory,
in practice, you still exhibit them, right? You have the game theory, kind of that mathematical
side, and then the psychological
side of Kahneman. And poker, in my mind, is the life experience that has cemented these
more than anything else in my brain and has made me internalize how this actually works
in reality and how you can try to decide optimally and then take that from the poker table to
real life. because poker is
an environment where you can really sample thousands and thousands and thousands of decisions
sample correctly. And as you know, Tim, that's incredibly important when it comes to learning
and trying to get a sense of probabilities. And in real life, not the poker table, we
never sample correctly, right? So that's where a lot of these biases come from. So I think
poker is a very powerful teaching tool to help cement these theories into practice.
Okay, I've got a great question from Drew.
Loyal listeners to Cautionary Tales know I'm a big fan of board games.
And Drew wants to know, Maria and Nate, do you play board games?
If you play board games, do you bring a poker lens to the table or is it a different vibe?
So I hate board games. I do not play board games. My sister is a little over six years older than I am.
She always loved board games. They bored me. They're just not interesting.
And when someone brings out Southerners of Catan or anything like that, I'm like, Oh, God, no, no, no, no, please take it to ride as a as a favorite in my family. And
I just want to die. You know, for me, if there's game night, please let it be poker. Otherwise,
please don't make me play and let me read my book on the side and cheer you on while
you play.
Yeah, I mean, look, some of the games get quite advanced. And so it's like, where do
you go from a game that takes 10 hours to learn to something that's kind of a broken,
overly simple game, right? But like, yeah, I like games because I'm very competitive,
right? If I'm playing, it's like, oh, people were like, don't have that background in games
or poker, then I'm just going to be honest, I tend to, I tend to figure out the strategy
pretty quick and win.
You crush them, Nate. You crush their souls and their dreams and they wish they'd never
ask you to play. Nate, to your point about the complexity, there's a New Yorker cartoon
that I absolutely love and it's a group of people sitting around a table and one of them
is reading a game instruction manual and the rest of them are all skeletons. He says, and so those are the rules. Shall we start playing?
I love it.
I had the privilege of interviewing Klaus Teuber, the creator of Settlers of Catan,
and he said something that really stuck with me, which I suspect will resonate with you
poker players. He said, you can know somebody their whole lives
and play a game with them,
and you will see something that you've never seen.
That's wonderful, and actually that's how I feel about poker.
Your character comes out.
And by the way, I do have a very strong interest in games
for my next book when it comes to cheating.
So I'm interested in what kind of a person cheats
at Monopoly at home game night.
People who want to win.
It's just totally mind boggling to me
that you would do that, but there you have it, yep.
My partner is also very competitive,
but his main objective is making sure that I don't win.
He will go out.
He will go out of his way to lose himself
if it's a murder or suicide mission basically,
which changes the strategy quite a bit.
I feel seen.
That's amazing.
So here's one for you, Tim.
This question is from Carrie, K-E-R-R-I-E.
I don't know if it's Irish or something, Carrie,
but anyway, hi Tim and team.
I worry that a big problem with the productivity gap in the UK is a lack of high quality data
and data-driven decision making.
I see a lot of investment in data that is overseen by technical experts in a given domain,
but very little consultation of data scientists.
Company and organizational boards also seem to lack the sort of expertise which is often
rolled into a catch-all IT function.
I work in the public sector and so I have framed my question accordingly. Should we have a government
department devoted to data or is that all a bit 1984? Best wishes, Kerry.
Well, I love the question. And we do kind of have a government department devoted to data. It's
called the Office for National Statistics, but it's focused on very old school statistics rather than modern
data science.
And old school statistics tends to focus on smaller data sets,
very well behaved, well formatted data sets.
For example, you might go out and do a survey rather than just
say, hey, well, we're going to just draw administrative data or
we're going to look at data that's coming out of people's
smartphones, which, you know, there's a lot more information in
there, but it's a lot messier. To be honest, what really concerns me at the moment is that
data is systematically underrated by governments. I think they don't realize how powerful it
can be, they don't realize how dangerous it can be, and it tends to be given
a low political priority or misused. So at the moment in the US, for example, we've got
this sort of sudden disappearance of all these government websites. It's unclear how much
data has permanently disappeared or is it just that it's temporarily gone down? Is somebody
archiving it? Will the archives work or not? Archives don't always work.
Are we going to have interrupted data sets? It's very unclear what's gone and what hasn't.
So that's a particularly extreme example. But generally, I mean, I'm working on a history of
data at the moment. It's so powerful. It's so important. It is the foundation of our health
systems. It's the foundation of many of our economic activities. It's the foundation of our health systems, it's the foundation of many of our economic activities,
it's the foundation of science, it's also the foundation of some terrible abuses of human rights in the past.
And yet it's kind of boring and it's kind of geeky and so it just gets overlooked.
And that's what really worries me.
Yeah, I mean, it's interesting that you have, you know, one partisan faction in the US that seems to think that
less data is better
instead of having better data, right? And some types of data you can go back and recollect,
but some things you can't write the UK, for example, has a data set of economic statistics
like GDP that goes back like almost 1000 years or something, right? Because they were collecting
records for tax purposes and estate purposes and everything in real time.
Yeah. Well, we got the Doomsday book from 1086. I'm old enough to remember the 900th
anniversary of the Doomsday book. There's an interesting little cautionary tale there.
So for the 900th anniversary of the Doomsday book, which was in 1986, the BBC organized
this kind of a proto Wikipedia.
They said, we're going to encourage this project where school kids across the country are going
to act as citizen journalists.
They're going to go around, they'll interview people, they'll gather data, they'll write
little essays.
We've got maps, we'll have photographs, and we'll put it all on a laser disc.
You remember laser discs?
You could see the problem, right? And we've got these highly sophisticated
expensive computer systems that are going to be accessible in every school. And it was
called Doomsday 1986, I think. It was super cool. I remember it really well. And then
by about 1998, it was just impossible to even read the laser discs. So this whole project
just went offline. Meanwhile, by the way, the original Doomsday books
from 1086, still available.
Yeah, paper has a certain appeal
and has lasted for centuries for a reason.
You know, the flip side, Tim,
of what you were saying about what's happening in the US
and kind of to address the 1984 element of the question is so, yes,
a lot of data is disappearing and then data that was never meant to be aggregated and linked and
personalized is being shared. And profiles of people, of US citizens and non-citizens,
are being created that should have never been created. There were rules in place to keep those data sets separate for a reason for privacy protections.
And now the government is trying to roll back those rules and collect and de-anonymize the
data that was shared by people with the assumption that that would never happen.
That's really bad.
Right.
So there's this kind of dystopian thing going on.
And there's history here.
I mean, this has happened before.
This happened in the 1940s.
It's not good.
1940s was not a good time in history, if people remember.
No, I think we can all agree on that one.
Thank you very much, Nate and Maria.
We will be answering more of your questions after this short break.
In the fall of 1986, Ronald Reagan found himself at the center of a massive scandal that looked like it might bring down his presidency.
It became known as the Iran-Contra affair.
The things that happened were so bizarre and insane,
I can't begin to tell you.
Please do.
To hear the whole story, listen to Fiasco, Iran-Contra,
wherever you get your podcasts.
You searched for your informant, who disappeared without a trace. tests. while curled up on the couch with your cat. There's more to imagine when you listen.
Discover heart-pounding thrillers on Audible.
The Medal of Honor is the highest military decoration
in the United States.
Recipients have done the improbable,
showing immense bravery and sacrifice
in the name of something much bigger than themselves.
This medal is for the men who went down that day.
It's for the families of those who didn't make it.
I'm JR Martinez. I'm a U.S. Army veteran myself.
And I'm honored to tell you the stories of these heroes
on the new season of Medal of Honor, Stories of Courage
from Pushkin Industries and iHeart Podcast.
From Robert Blake, the first Black
Sailor to be awarded the medal, to Daniel Daly, one of only 19 people to have received the Medal
of Honor twice. These are stories about people who have distinguished themselves by acts of valor
going above and beyond the call of duty. You'll hear about what they did, what it meant, We are back.
I'm here with Nate Silva and Maria Konikova of Risky Business, and we have an interesting
question from a Risky Business listener who asks, one thing that happened during the tariffs,
which didn't get much attention, is the 10-year treasury rate spiked from 4 to 4.5%.
I should say, by the way, I work for the Financial Times, we were paying a lot of attention to that,
but understand that outside Geekland, it was ignored. That basically means, the listener continues, there is less belief that
US debt is a safe bet. It probably means somebody, cough, China, cough, issued a sell order for
a large amount of US treasury with the intent to move the interest rate as retaliation for tariffs.
To cut to the chase, the listener asks, I would be extremely interested in hearing what
are your thoughts on the likelihood of the United States defaulting?
Nate, this one's you.
I used to know more about credit default swaps and things like this.
I mean, look, the US runs up very large deficits.
Neither party has any interest in doing what it would take to cut those deficits potentially,
right? We got lucky in kind of the financial crisis and COVID era of lower interest rates
where you can borrow very cheaply. That's no longer true now. In fact, borrowing is
getting more expensive. And so, you know, I trust the market's fairly efficient here,
but I guess the US is still a bit too big to fail.
Well, normally when we say too big to fail, we're referring to things that the US is going
to bail out if necessary.
Right.
Yeah.
The US is too big to save.
That's your problem.
You know, the world has profoundly been affected by Trump's second term in a way it wasn't
in Trump's first term.
Our neighbors to the north Canada had an election that was entirely upended. The liberals wanted
to back in power even though Trudeau had been very unpopular, right? I would argue that
the election of the new pope was in part a response to Trump in the changing geopolitical
world, right? And say, okay, we want to have some influence on the United States. Have
to figure who's not Trump, it can balance him out somehow. And so yeah, we're a different
world. And I suppose I trust markets and investors are intelligent about that. And I'm not sure
it's, it's China so much as the fact that we're in a new regime.
Yeah, I certainly agree. I don't think China needs to do anything to make the US Treasury
rate spike. When the rate spikes, by the way, it means people are selling US government debt. When they sell it, the price goes down, the interest rates goes up. But
yeah, plenty of people willing to do that without any coordinated action from China.
I mean, there is absolutely zero need for the US government to default because the US government
can always print more dollars. I mean, it could be that US government debt gets less
attractive. It could be that inflation takes off. It could be there are all kinds of problems, but there's never a need to default.
I think the decision to default would be just that.
It would be a decision.
The US government would have to actively decide we want to stiff our creditors.
So you just have to look at the president and say, does this look like a man who
stiffs his creditors?
I don't think so.
I don't think so.
That doesn't sound like Donald J.
Trump to me.
This is President Trump we're talking about, Tim.
In the FT, we have a new acronym. It's TACO. TACO stands for Trump Always Chickens Out.
So the bet is that he will not, in fact, default, even though he's talking about various things
that already look like default, because the consequences would be so catastrophic
that he would look at the consequences
and he would back away.
But that doesn't mean that he couldn't do some damage.
So fingers crossed.
All right.
So listener Jack wants us to explore
the thorny issue of cell phones in school and writes,
Australia has been running an experiment with New South Wales
banning mobile phone use in all schools from October 2023. This is following the implementation
of a ban in Victoria in 2020, which itself cites research from England and other justifications.
So this listener has kids in school. This is not where I thought the question was gonna go.
Actively helps the 14 year old subvert this ban.
So they have an old phone in a locked pouch
and their actual phone in their bag.
This is because they must use their phone
to hotspot the internet to their laptop.
Jack writes, my opinion is the whole thing is stupid as most kids have
some kind of work around and are on their laptops all day anyway. If parents are on their phones
all the time, why are we expecting kids not to be? I still see teachers in playgrounds face and phone
and all the injustices and hypocrisy of my own school days come flooding back. I mean, I know
I'm asking this question. I have so many thoughts, but I'll open it up to you guys first.
I also have thoughts.
I think the hypocrisy thought is real.
I have three children myself, my oldest child is 21,
the youngest is 13.
They see me being distracted by my phone all the time.
And of course, they're going to be influenced by that.
I think that this is an evil device, useful but evil, that we all of us need to fight together because
it's capable of ruining all of our lives. I feel like I should set a good example. And
I don't feel that the fact that the grownups are being distracted by the phones is particularly
a good reason to say the kids should have the phones too. I mean, we would never say, hey, I see the grown-ups drinking
vodka and smoking, so why? Surely it's fine for the nine-year-olds to also drink vodka
and smoke. I mean, I don't think that follows.
It's hypocritical, Tim. It's hypocritical that you do not let your child.
Yeah. I think it suggests that maybe the grown-up shouldn't bring so much
vodka and shouldn't smoke so much, rather than the other way around.
But anyway, yeah, we are setting an example, whether we like it or not.
I completely agree with that.
And to add to it, the use of screens in general, it's very different depending on your age.
There's emerging research, but now we have a few decades worth of what phones do to developing brains and
kind of the habits that you create from a young age. So being on the phone as an adult who grew
up without that kind of access is very different from growing up and actually constantly being
connected to a screen. By the way, there's also research that shows that taking notes by hand is
much more powerful than taking notes on a laptop, right?
You retain more information, you learn better because there's a brain link between the hand
and the brain that does not exist when you're typing.
It would be better.
I totally agree with you, Tim.
Adults should be on their phones much less often.
I write about this.
I think it's actually really great practice to not have your phone.
I've sometimes left my phone at home on purpose
to kind of have a day without cell phones.
I have programs that turn the internet off on my computer
because I lack willpower if I don't forcibly
kind of have it turned off to try to have
some deep concentration, deep writing time.
This is all kind of related to our executive function,
our self-control ability, our ability to learn, our memory.
All of these things are interconnected.
And don't you want your child to actually emerge
as a kind of smart adult who's capable of all of these things
as opposed to someone who is constantly distracted.
Nate strikes me as a three screens at once guy.
Nate, any thoughts?
You know, I just have my laptop. People think I have some big elaborate mod or setup. I
just have my little laptop actually. Yeah, look, is it paternalistic to tell kids they
can't use their phones? I mean, yeah, but they're kids, right? So you're allowed to
be paternalistic toward them. And I don't know. I mean, I guess the one caveat I have
is I was chronically pretty
bored in school, right? And so I'm sympathetic to the kids that are like, okay, I'm bored.
I'm learning things I already know. But like, it is a situation where I think you have to
have some type of consistent enforcement in the rules. But when you're in school, blame
your teachers for not making you interested, but don't blame them for not letting you be
on Instagram while you're supposed to be learning algebra.
SIMON I think it might also be a collective action problem.
I think it's perfectly possible that you've got teenagers who would be quite happy
if nobody in the school had Instagram or nobody had Snapchat.
But if other people are using Snapchat to communicate, to arrange to meet up,
well then I need Snapchat too.
And just talking to teenagers, I think that viewpoint is not unusual.
Some of them are like,
please, can you just ban everybody from using it and then I'll be happy.
Yeah.
Okay, let's move on because I've got a question specifically from Maria,
from a long-time listener from Quebec.
They would like to hear Maria talk about a particular point of her book, The Biggest Bluff,
where she describes the breakfast she had with her mentor.
You were trying to find somebody who would teach you to play poker so that you could write a book about learning to play poker.
He only became interested when he realized you don't know anything at all about the subject. You don't even know how a deck of cards works.
And our listener says, I'm 65 years old, and I went through a couple of career changes.
And I find this story very moving and so true about what it means to learn something and
to teach something.
So what are your thoughts on that?
Yeah, I think so.
So this conversation took place the first time I ever met Eric Seidel,
who is a legend of the poker world. And he had never taken on a poker student before.
And what stood out about me was that I was a complete blank slate. I didn't have any
bad habits. I didn't have any habits, right? I didn't know anything. And so for him, I
think it was a very interesting experiment, just like for me, it was an interesting
experiment from scratch.
What can he do with me, given my background in psychology, in a short period of time?
These days when you've got all these math wizards and solvers and all of these things,
is kind of psychology, hard work, kind of my background, is it enough, right?
Could I do well? And
so if I could, that would be an amazing kind of proof of concept for the way that he thinks
about the game. And so I think to him, that's what made this interesting. And that's what
made it appealing.
SIMON HUGHES-SOMER, PhD Nate, why is Maria so good at poker? Is it the coach? Is it her
training as a psychologist? Is it the coach? Is it her training as a psychologist? Is it something else?
I think it's her and not the coaching, although Maria is a wonderfully well-connected person
who has access to some of the best poker minds in the world. But yeah, look, it's the balance
of the people reading skills and the mathematical skills and the discipline, really. You know,
it's rare to see Maria tilt. I'm sure she does it, right? But I think
she's playing more than I am, frankly.
Tilting is basically where you get emotional and it affects your decisions.
Tilt doesn't have to be anger, right? It can be like, oh, I've had a great day, so I'm
going to not fight for this pot that you're supposed to bluff for. It can be a lot of
different formats of it, but like, you know, we know one always plays their A game, right?
But if you're always playing your B plus game or better
and you're really smart in lots of different ways and read people well
and maybe defy stereotypes a little bit to maybe are more aggressive
than people are expecting.
So, yeah, I would say she's a well rounded poker player.
By the way, it's part of like learning the game later
is that you might wind up being a little bit more well rounded.
When I used to play for a living back, God, 20 years ago now, I'm getting old,
I played a game called Limit Hold'em, which the same amount is bet on every hand.
Or as a no limit, you can bet anywhere from one chip to the entire size of your stack,
and it's a much different game, and so I had to spend a lot of time unlearning habits from Limit Hold'em,
which can be bad habits in no limit hold'em.
We've got more questions coming up, but first let's take a quick break.
In the fall of 1986, Ronald Reagan found himself at the center of a massive scandal that looked
like it might bring down his presidency. In 1986, Ronald Reagan found himself at the center of a massive scandal that looked like
it might bring down his presidency.
It became known as the Iran-Contra affair.
The things that happened were so bizarre and insane, I can't begin to tell you.
Please do.
To hear the whole story, listen to Fiasco, Iran Contra, wherever you get your podcasts.
You sailed beyond the horizon in search of an island scrubbed from every map.
You battled Krakens and navigated through storms. Your spade struck the lid of a long lost treasure chest. While you cooked a lasagna.
There's more to imagine when you listen. Discover bestselling adventure stories on Audible.
The Medal of Honor is the highest military decoration in the United States. Recipients
have done the improbable, showing immense bravery and sacrifice in the name
of something much bigger than themselves.
This medal is for the men who went down that day.
It's for the families of those who didn't make it.
I'm JR Martinez.
I'm a U.S. Army veteran myself.
And I'm honored to tell you the stories of these heroes on the new season of Medal of Honor Stories of Courage from Pushkin Industries and
iHeart Podcast. From Robert Blake the first black sailor to be awarded the
medal to Daniel Daly one of only 19 people to have received the Medal of
Honor twice. These are stories about people who have distinguished themselves by acts
of valor going above and beyond the call of duty. You'll hear about what they did, what
it meant, and what their stories tell us about the nature of courage and sacrifice. Listen
to Medal of Honor on the iHeartRadio app, Apple Podcasts, or wherever you get your podcasts. Welcome back to Courtionary Questions with me, Tim Harford.
And me, Maria Konikova.
And me, Nate Silver.
So here's a question from Mark.
Mark asks, it's no secret that political donations are tied to political favors, legislation
benefiting the highest donors and so forth.
If the politicians are the machine and the machine runs on donors, and so forth. If the politicians
are the machine and the machine runs on money, what if we tweaked the source of the money?
What would happen if by some stroke of magic Congress received vastly larger salaries,
increasing with years of service, but with one big caveat? Politicians cannot accept any donations,
gifts, speaking fees, or favors in any form other than direct money donations
from constituents up to the federal limits without forfeiting their public service salary.
So put simply, what if public service was a bigger, more valuable incentive? Could it
even outcompete the current incentives? Would governing change the better or for the worse
and why?
I like it.
You know, it's a good question, but it's slightly naive
in the sense that we already have rules
against politicians accepting all sorts of things
that Mark wants them not to accept.
And there are ways around them, right?
There are PACs, which are political action committees,
which you can donate to.
There's ways that you can lobby and influence people.
People would get around these incentives very easily,
just like they do today.
This maybe isn't a naive observation,
but I would have thought there was a difference
between donations to a campaign
for the purposes of spending money on adverts
to get re-elected versus just donations
to a politician's bank account. There should
be a bright line between the two of them. I mean, Nate, you're the expert on this.
The answer is you are supposed to report to the Federal Election Commission every dollar
that you spend. So you definitely run a risk of expenses being scrutinized if they're not
legitimate. But of course, there are a million things. A tranche of expenses that are ambiguous
between personal and business expenses, right?
You can also shuffle money to consultants and pay them maybe more than they're worth
in exchange for who knows favors later on and so forth. I think it's probably a good
idea to pay members of Congress more. I think it might help recruit some people who are
not already wealthy to enter Congress. I think in general, top performing government employees should be paid more too.
And make it easier maybe to fire the poor performers.
I don't know, I don't understand why anyone would want to go into politics.
It sounds like miserable to me to be a member of Congress.
My lizard brain can't grok those incentives necessarily.
It is worth directing some attention to politicians' latitude to do things that people might want to bribe them to do.
So the more personal discretion a politician has,
the more it's worth bribing them.
So one of the interesting things about tariffs
is that if you put a large tariff on importers,
it's then worth a great deal of money
to particular importers to be exempt from that tariff.
I mean, it keeps changing, but there was this huge tariff
on electronic goods coming from China, and then it's like,
oh, actually, we're not going to levy that on iPhones,
so Apple benefits from that.
And I'm not saying, oh, Apple bribed the president.
I don't have any particular reason to believe they did.
But the point is that when you've got that sort of personal discretion, it becomes hugely valuable and
those interest groups are willing to pay a lot of money. And so there's the temptation
for bribery.
One of the big differences between first world and third world countries is how prevalent
bribery is kind of in the way that governments function. And yet a lot of so-called first world countries and second world countries, there's a lot
of bribing and corruption and cheating that goes on no matter what.
So sure, it would be amazing if somehow we could create the incentive structure where
that doesn't happen.
But I don't see from a psychological standpoint how the same type of personality
that wants to become a politician and who's successful as a politician, kind of wheels
and deals as a part of what they did to get there, how they would ever be totally above
everything and rise to the heights of government needed to exert real influence. It's a very
cynical take, but that's how I see it.
You mentioned developing countries. This was perceived as being a particular problem in Africa,
both for historical reasons and because a lot of sub-Saharan African countries were very, very poor.
And so this amazing African entrepreneur called Mo Ibrahim, who made a huge amount of money in telecommunications in the 1990s, became a billionaire. He announced the Mo Ibrahim Prize. He was going to give,
it was millions, to any African leader who surrendered power after losing a democratic
election. This is about 20 years ago. I was Googling around. I think the prize has been
paid at least once, but I haven't been able to find any survey of whether it's made a difference
But I just think it's a clever idea whether or not it worked in practice. It's a clever idea
didn't didn't Sam bankman free want to pay or
Bribe Donald Trump like a billion dollars not to run for reelection or something like that
Just cuz Sam bankman free wanted to do it doesn't mean it's a bad idea
I might color my priors a little bit, I'd say.
Fair.
Fair.
Sometimes, you know, a broken clock is right twice a day.
Let's take another question now from Jordan.
And this one was directed to you, Tim.
So first, Jordan loves your podcast and has listened to every episode you've put
out. Good to hear. So keep up the great work and thank you. Jordan is a dedicated fan,
Tim. It's a lot of episodes. I like it. I like it. I love your podcast too, but I've
missed some, I have to admit. They're all available on catch up. So what is Jordan's
question? Yes. It's about penalty kicks. So if you don't move, you're more likely to save them.
I wonder about that since if a goalie never moves,
then wouldn't the kicker behave differently
and make it easier to save shots that don't go down the middle?
I was just thinking about it and was wondering how that was controlled for.
Actually, you two are the perfect people to answer this question
because it's about game theory optimality
and trying to exploit suboptimal behavior. In a soccer penalty, basically you've just
got a striker trying to score a goal, you've got the goalkeeper standing there, and they
can kind of guess. They can dive to the left or they can dive to the right, and that's
really a 50-50, they'll guess right. Or they could just kind of not dive at all and stand
in the middle, which makes them look passive and like they're not even trying. However, it's really a 50-50, they'll guess right.
to dive to the left or right, and I'm going to kick where they were. Anyway, so Jordan's question is, well, hang on.
If the strikers figure that out, aren't the goalkeepers
also going to figure it out?
So it's really a question of people adapting to each other's strategy
and the optimal mix of strategies.
And who better than you two to explain the details here?
I mean, that is such a fascinating element of game theory
that Nate and I talk about quite often
which is kind of this recursive element of it right if I know that you know that
I know that you know and in poker this happens all the time where you're trying
to figure out you know how do I adjust to my opponent if we're both playing GTO
game theory optimal poker then you know, we're both executing a strategy
perfectly. But humans aren't computers and that doesn't happen, right? So if I figure
out for instance that Nate is calling too often, then I should start, you know, changing
my strategy away from GTO. So even if in this particular spot, game theory says that I should check because my hand is
a little too weak to bet for value, I'd bet again because I know that Nate is going to
call me again with a worse hand because he over calls, right?
So I'm kind of adapting to his behavior.
Now Nate is a smart guy who also knows a lot about game theory.
So what if Nate then figures out that I'm doing this, right?
Because we get to showdown and he's like,
Maria, how did you bet three times with bottom pair?
This is crazy.
You were right, you won.
But Nate figures out that, oh, I'm over calling.
So now she's actually playing differently.
So now I'm gonna change my strategy to adjust to that.
So next time I actually try to do that,
Nate ends up having just the nuts, right?
The best hand ever.
And when I have a good hand, you know, he folds, right?
So he's now adjusted and I say, oh, wait, wait, wait.
Okay, he's changed.
So now I need to change.
And with two good players,
this process can go on indefinitely.
And sometimes you psych yourself out, right?
And you start getting into
mind games and sometimes you end up overthinking and just making the wrong decision. Also, you're
making assumptions about the other person, right? And how the other person is seeing you and how
they're adjusting. Now, I'm talking about poker because I know poker and I don't know soccer,
but this is exactly kind of the problem that you have in this soccer question.
In theoretical terms, as an academic would analyze it,
you get to an equilibrium and the equilibrium is a mixed strategy
where it's unpredictable.
So, for example, the striker might go left 45% of the time,
go right 45% of the time,
stick it down the middle 10% of the time,
and the goalkeeper might stay in the middle 20% of the time
and go left 40% and go right 40%.
But the point is, they can't be predictable.
If they were predictable, that could be exploitable.
And they can't just be unpredictable in a foolish way.
So it's like, oh, I could dive to the right 50%
and to the left 50% and never stand up in the middle.
Well, that's unpredictable, but it's also not smart
because actually I need to keep the striker% and never stand up in the middle. Well, that's unpredictable, but it's also not smart because actually I need to keep
the striker honest and sometimes stand up.
Absolutely.
There's always an equilibrium, but that equilibrium will involve a randomized mixture of strategies.
Right.
But in practice, so this is called randomization, right?
The human brain is very bad at randomizing randomly.
Most humans will end up having a pattern and will end up actually
doing one thing more than they're supposed to, right? Doing another thing less than they're
supposed to because they're not optimal game theoreticians.
There was actually a recent example where the English keeper Jordan Pickford in a high
stakes penalty shootout had a water bottle with a list of every player on the opposing team and whether he should dive
to the left or to the right or stand up for that player.
So they had previously analyzed the play.
His coaches had basically pre-randomized.
It's a little risky.
So as long as nobody finds your water bottle ahead of time,
you can pre-randomize and I think he saved some goals
and England won that particular penalty shootout, which is very un-English.
That's great.
If you don't think that athletes are thinking about this stuff, professional athletes, then
you're wrong, right?
They may have their coaching staffs encouraging them to do it.
They may talk about themselves.
They may even do some of the stuff like fairly intuitively, right?
In an NBA game, you have five players and 24 seconds on the shot clock.
So it's kind of a game of like trying to maximize your expected value with the best shot you
can, but the defense is trying to minimize your expected value. And like the decisions
these players make are usually pretty smart about like, it's not quite worth taking this
shot, but now time's running out and now I need to, you know, I think a lot of them are
actually quite high IQ, frankly, there's a lot of money and competitive pride on the line in making the right decisions.
Yeah.
So, Nate, actually, Caleb has been thinking about underhanded free throws in the NBA.
Here's what he says, from what I understand, some if not most players could hit a higher
free throw percentage if they practiced an underhand technique.
Honestly, I respect basketball pros less after learning that they don't use underhanded free
throws because they think it looks goofy.
It's not a winning mentality.
So Nate, should NBA players switch to underhanded free throws?
Nate Yeah, look, there probably are some equilibriums
where strategies that are considered emasculating, right, or embarrassing, somehow might be pursued
a bit less, right? Although maybe that changes too, right? You've now seen a thing in the
NBA where it's a lot more flopping than there once was, meaning that when guys get fouled,
they'll exaggerate the magnitude of what actually happened to them, right? It used to be something
people associate with soccer. It's migrated into the NBA as well. But yeah, sometimes to take strategies that would be seen as embarrassing, there's expected
value there if you don't care about the embarrassment.
I'm curious, guys, is there an example in poker of a strategy that is positive expected
value but everyone thinks it's just embarrassing and only an idiot would do it?
Yeah, there's one that has turned out to be much better
than people thought, and it's called donk betting,
which is leading into the preflop razor.
And so the reason it's called donk betting
is because people thought you were a donk, a donkey,
if you did it, right?
Because the established wisdom is you always check
to the preflop razor.
And once we got more advanced game theory,
it turns out that no, actually,
there are some spots where you should lead. What is leading into a preflop razor. And once we got more advanced game theory, it turns out that no, actually, there are some spots where you should lead.
What is leading into a pre-flop razor?
Betting first, right?
Instead of checking your options so that letting the other person act, you act first.
You bet first.
To this day, though, even though it's now accepted, if someone does it right away, it
still feels donkey-ish even even when it's not right. It's very hard to kind
of wrap your mind around the fact that this might actually be the correct play.
One other play that can be hard to make is folding when you've already put a lot of money
in the pot and there's just a little bit more to put in and see the showdown, but still
sometimes you maybe do have a fold potentially. You know I played one
unusual hand at a tournament a couple of months ago where I raise a second player call and
a third player re-raise and if I was going to call I was committing about half my stack
right, which means ordinarily what you're supposed to do is either fold or go ahead
and go all in. However, I had a hand that I wanted to encourage the third player to enter the pot. So I just called and like, well, I'll have
a lot of good flops. And if I don't have a good flop, then I can get away if it's a bad flop.
And anyway, so yeah, like, so I miss the flop, which is the first three cards in poker. He bets
and I fold getting three and a half to one. It's like, what are you doing, man? You're not allowed
to fold there, right? Which indicated, I think that he had a half to one ounce. It's like, what are you doing, man? You're not allowed to fold there, right?
Which indicated, I think, that he had a good hand
and was hoping that I continued, right?
But like, you know, I ran the math later
and I'm like, actually, this is the right play
by a couple of percentage points.
It was just an embarrassing play to make in the moment.
So I have learned no donk betting for me.
And I've also learned from Nate that sometimes
you have to quit whether or not you are ahead.
We have to quit. We're out of time.
Nate, Maria, this has been such fun.
Thank you so much, Tim.
Thank you for having us, Tim.
I always love listening to Risky Business and thank you so much for joining us on cautionary questions.
Thank you, Tim. We'll do it again sometime.
Thank you. I will be back next week with another cautionary tale.
Cautionary Tales is written by me, Tim Harford, with Andrew Wright, Alice Fiennes and Ryan Dilley.
It's produced by Georgia Mills and Marilyn Rust.
The sound design and original music are the work of Pascal Wise.
Additional sound design is by Carlos Sanjuan at Brain Audio.
Ben Nadaph Haferi edited the scripts.
The show features the voice talents of Melanie Gutridge, Stella Harford, Oliver Hembra, Sarah Job, Masea Monroe, Jamal Westman and Rufus Wright. The show also wouldn't have been possible without the work
of Jacob Weisberg, Retta Cohn, Sarah Nix, Eric Sandler, Carrie Brody, Christina Sullivan,
Keira Posey and Owen Miller.
Co-Optionary Tales is a production of Pushkin Industries. It's recorded at Wardour Studios
in London by Tom Berry. If you like the show, please remember to share, rate and
review. It really makes a difference to us. And if you want to hear the show ad free,
sign up to Pushkin Plus on the show page on Apple podcasts or at pushkin.fm slash plus. Thank you. In the fall of 1986, Ronald Reagan found himself at the center of a massive scandal that looked
like it might bring down his presidency.
It became known as the Iran-Contra affair.
The things that happened were so bizarre and insane, I can't begin to tell you.
Please do.
To hear the whole story, listen to Fiasco, Iran-Contra, wherever you get your podcasts.
The Medal of Honor is the highest military decoration in the United States. Recipients Contra wherever you get your podcasts. On Medal of Honor, Stories of Courage, you'll hear about these heroes and what their stories tell us about the nature of bravery.
Listen to Medal of Honor on the iHeartRadio app, Apple Podcasts, or wherever you get your
podcasts.
This is an iHeart Podcast.