Freakonomics Radio - 127. Can You Be Too Smart for Your Own Good? And Other FREAK-quently Asked Questions
Episode Date: May 23, 2013Dubner and Levitt talk about circadian rhythms, gay marriage, autism, and whether "pay what you want" is everything it's cracked up to be. ...
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Hey, Levitt, of all the things that are in your power to do at this very moment in time,
what would be your very most favorite thing to do?
If I could be doing anything right now, what would I be doing?
Yeah.
Probably playing golf.
All right.
If, let's say, you can't play golf, what comes next?
Probably sleeping.
If you can't be playing golf or sleeping, what's third? Probably being here talking to you. From WNYC and APM, American Public Media, this is Freakonomics Radio, the podcast that explores the hidden side of everything.
Here's your host, Stephen Dubner. Every now and then, Steve Levitt and I ask you, our listeners and readers, to send us your questions.
Then we try to answer them on this podcast.
We call it Frequently Asked Questions.
I like this question.
It'll be interesting to know if we can be of any help.
From David Rossetti,
he says,
is modern life,
more specifically the fact
that we no longer follow
our circadian rhythm,
killing us?
There are all these rises
in diseases,
cancer, autoimmune, etc.,
in developed countries
that do not exist
in numbers anywhere close
to what they have
elsewhere in the world.
And no one really knows
what's going on.
So could simply going to bed when it gets dark
and waking up when there's light
reduce billions of dollars in healthcare costs,
increase productivity,
reduce addictions to alcohol and drugs
and depression, et cetera.
Levitt, circadian rhythms
having to do with rise in diseases
and more broadly than tied to cost and productivity.
You know anything about that?
We're probably not the right people to answer David's exact question,
which is more of a medical question about is there a link between staying up all night
and dying of things like cancer.
And I do want to challenge his first premise,
which is that cancer and heart disease and all those things are way higher
in the developed world than in other places.
And in part it's because in the developed world we've done such a good job of getting rid of the other things that kill you that you got to
die of something. So that's the sorts of things that now kill us are the diseases of senescence,
old age, heart disease, cancer, things like that. But I think being realistic and not knowing the
facts, but just guessing, I cannot imagine that working the night shift in terms of life expectancy could take more
than a year off your life. I mean, maybe two years, but that it would be amazing to me if the kinds of
things we're talking about could matter that much. And my guess is actually that accidents, accidental
death is the greatest thing that gets elevated when you work the night shift because you're just
so darn tired all the time that you end up getting into car crashes and falling down the stairs and things
like that. So if you're saying maybe a year less of life expectancy, compare that for a minute to,
let's say, an unhealthy habit, whether it's very poor diet or, let's say, smoking. You think that
working the night shift continuously throughout your adult life would have less of a physiological
detriment than the others? That's my conjecture. I don't really know. But whatever it is,
what I want to compare it to is the gains that we've had in the modern world that in some ways
necessitate a bunch of people staying up all night to make it possible for the rest of us
to have a great life. And the gains we've had in life expectancy over the last 100 years are probably, I don't know, 35 or 40 years increased
from maybe 50 years. Yeah, just about doubled in the U.S. for a U.S.-born male, about doubled the
last, so roughly 38 to 76. But again, a lot of that is also hidden in childbirth, death and
childbirth, which,
you know, is still higher in the U.S. and in some countries, but almost went away. And once you get
rid of those deaths, it used to be that once you got to middle age, you did have a relatively good
chance of living longer. Yeah, absolutely. But so I just think it's part of modern life that we
get tremendous consumption value from being able to, you know, go drive late to Taco Bell
and get whatever we want to eat. And if we get sick, the hospitals are open and that the capital
in the factories can be used productively by doing three chefs instead of two. So it's not perfect.
Look, all of us would rather be sleeping when it's dark and be waking up to the sun and the roosters and stuff like that. But I think that it's a cost of modernity. And maybe the answer is how do you lower that cost? What can science and technology difficult to be switching from daytime to nighttime to daytime to nighttime,
which is what sometimes they do in police departments and in hospitals.
I believe there's a body of evidence that says you just kind of get used to the night shift
if you do the night shift for years and years and years in a way that moving back and forth is very hard.
All right.
Let me ask you this.
Here's a question that came in.
Actually, kind of two versions of the same question.
One from Steve Adema and one from Miguel Sandoval.
One asks, is there a hidden cost to intelligence?
I feel a lot of people assume wrongly, question mark.
There's a tradeoff between intellectual and social ability.
And the other fellow asks, can you be too smart for your own good?
I've heard this used often.
However, I tend to disagree that you can be too smart for your own good.
Levitt, you're a relatively smart guy. Have there been instances in your life where you've been too smart for your own good? And do you know
anything about this more generally? I can't say I've ever remembered being too smart for my own
good. I've seen other people, and I'll tell you the biggest thing that happens in academics
is that really smart people become convinced that they can trick not just a single other person,
but they can trick everyone at once.
I've seen it a number of times where the smarter you are, the more you think you can get away with,
and it ends up being your undoing. The people who are really, really smart actually can run circles
around people, but it's the people who are one notch below the very smartest who I've seen
get into a lot of trouble by thinking they're too smart.
What about the related problem of domain transfer?
People thinking that because they're very good or very smart in one arena, they kind
of develop an attitude of confidence that they think, you know, people talk about this
with doctors sometimes called the God complex.
You think that if you can figure out something like the human body, you can figure out just
about anything.
Do you see that?
Oh, yeah.
That's what we're doing right now. Isn't that what our FAQs are? You and I are good at one
thing. You're good at writing. I'm good at taking a pile of data and making sense of it. And we sit
here and talk like we're good at answering questions about whether we're smart. I mean,
it's exactly what we're doing right now. And it's something that you and I rail against all the time.
And we have some fun with it just because we know we're among friends on the podcast,
but the people listening understand that we're just kind of screwing around
when we answer these questions.
We're not really giving the truth.
Now, if you go back to that first question about the tradeoff.
Yeah, the social tradeoff.
I think there are at least two really good reasons to believe
that people who are intelligent will not possess particularly good
social skills. And one of those is that if I take just the example of math ability,
there's a lot of evidence that autism is a sort of extreme form of mathiness and
thinking like a mathematician or like a scientist. And that that interferes with the way that you
think about people and interact with people. And so I think there are potentially some genetic
reasons why being smart in a math way might get in the way of being good with people. I think we've
all seen some of that. I think the other thing is just what you invest in, right? So when you're a
kid, if you're smart, you invest in the things that smart kids invest in, doing well in school, impressing people, trying to get in college. And
if you're not smart, you make a lot of investment in being social and being the cheerleader type or
the homecoming king. And those investments are really important.
That's interesting. That's a good point. So let me ask you this, though, about,
I'm curious hearing you talk, I think, about gender.
So I think two things about gender, one and smartness. So one is, you know, why is the autism spectrum so much more? Why are there so many more males in it than females?
I have a friend, Mehmet Oz, Dr. Oz, who I've known for a long time before he was famous and he's always been brilliant and kind of great. And he was telling me not long ago that with boys, he puts it the way only a scientist would, there's a lot less quality control with boys, he said, right?
So for girls who are going to be carrying the next generation, their wiring needs to be kind of further along than boys who can survive in a different way. But it makes me think when you're
talking about the relation between smartness and either success or social ability, you're answering
from the perspective of a male. What about for women? Do you think women are penalized more for
being smart or smarter than their peers than men are? And if so, on what dimensions?
Well, certainly in the marriage market, right, in the dating market, smart women don't get rewarded in any way like smart men get
rewarded. I think we wrote about it a little bit in Freakonomics, didn't we, about the dating. And
smart men, men who had a lot of education, did quite well. But women who had a lot of education
did poorly. It was hard to tease out the education for women and the income, because both of them
were turnoffs for the other men.
If you go back to the 1960s and you look at the marriage rate of highly educated women,
it was really low. It was shockingly low that they were, of all the people in society,
least likely to be married. It was women who went and got PhDs. So I think women really do
pay the price for, at least historically have paid the price for being
too smart and too successful. Although I think that's certainly the data suggests that that's
changing. And that's my feeling as well, is that there's a lot more room for smart women in society
today than there was. Is it that there's more room for smart women in society or is it the
matching markets are better? There are better, easier ways for
smart women to find the men that they want to find than there used to be.
Well, it's certainly true that places like Silicon Valley, where it used to be that men who would be,
say, computer programs would marry women they met in college. I think now they're more likely to
marry other women who are computer programmers. So to the extent that men and women are more and more doing the same jobs,
I think that that does help very much successful women to meet the kind of men who are equally
successful. But that's also, according to some people, including a student of mine, Hayes Golden,
is one of the reasons why autism is going up, because the men who are good at math are now much more likely to have babies
with the women who are good at math,
and that seems to be triggering an increase in autism. Coming up on Freakonomics Radio, since fighting cancer is big business, what's the incentive to find a cure?
So I would say the incentive for a cancer cure is not really a market incentive.
It's a being a hero kind of incentive. It's a being a hero kind of incentive.
From WNYC and APM American Public Media, this is Freakonomics Radio.
Here's your host, Stephen Dubner.
Here's a question from someone named Dallas.
Would making marriage legal for the LGBT community improve the economy?
If so, how much?
Well.
Pass?
No, let's see. I would say,
I don't think that would have a big impact on the economy for a couple of reasons.
First, I think that when you talk about marriage versus not marriage, if all you're talking about is just everyone has the same relationship,
you just changed the title of the relationship, then maybe you're talking about having some big
weddings. But that to me feels like Keynesian economics and the idea that if there's more
demand for things that will make the economy better. But I think the modern view of the world, or at least my modern view of the world,
is that for the economy to be better, you need to be better at making things, right?
So that the supply side of the economy, productivity, is everything, right?
If we can make workers more productive, then we end up being richer.
But consumption is, you know, if people just consume more stuff,
I very much am of the view that things like
stimulus, government stimulus and whatnot, just aren't very successful, because what you need to
do is figure out how to make everybody more productive and produce, you know.
Okay, but let's talk about, let's say a couple that's not married, that wants to be married,
is not able to versus a couple that wants to be married and is able to legally, and some of the
economic changes that might take place around that.
Let's say health care consumption or at least paying for health care,
how much they're actually paying.
Let's say taxation.
A married couple actually is going to pay more than two individuals not.
Can you imagine any way around those avenues in which it has any kind of real impact,
or is it still not much of an issue in your view?
Yeah, it sounds to me a lot like a bunch of transfers. I don't think that people are going to,
they'll have to make different choices, maybe distort their choices less if they're married.
Let's take the healthcare market. Maybe it's true that because of spousal coverage,
people will make a different set of choices, but that seems to me like a crazy way to think about
the problem. We have a terrible healthcare care system in which employment and health care should not be linked.
We should fix that problem first, not try to backdoor it through.
Right. But until we fix that problem, at least having it linked to one person in a couple's employment rather than two, is that an improvement or a disimprovement?
I think that's a triviality on issues like this, whether it's this or abortion or capital punishment.
I mean, these are issues that economically are just not very important.
I mean, it just doesn't, you know, capital punishment isn't very important to crime.
And abortion and dollars and cents is not important at all.
But they stand for something much, much greater.
They represent what America means or ideology or personal rights or whatever. And the relative
importance of the issues of liberty and fairness and things have got to be a hundred times bigger
than the direct economic impact. So I think it's just confusing the issue to even talk about
economics when these are moral issues, not economic issues?
That would be my good answer to that question.
So skip all that other junk I said.
This is interesting.
A question from Damon Bevan.
What would be the economic impact of a cheap, readily available cure for cancer?
Here's the basic scenario, he writes.
Imagine that somehow we find a cure for cancer that involves something cheap and simple like drinking a spinach smoothie with every meal for five days.
We have entire industries and charities that are geared toward finding cancer cures and treatments. What would be the economic impact if those
industries and charities were suddenly out of the business overnight? One reason I ask is because I
often argue that there is no clear market incentive to find a cure for cancer. Treatments are expensive
and there are repeat customers. It's a nice profit model. A cure would slowly eliminate the customer base for treatment. So other than altruism,
where is the incentive for a cancer cure? So I would say the incentive for a cancer cure is not
really a market incentive. It's a being a hero kind of incentive, that there are so many doctors
out there, researchers, medical researchers, who if they could be the one who is
forever remembered as the one who prevented cancer, who got rid of cancer, they would do anything to
do that. So I think there are really strong incentives out there, and they aren't exactly
market incentives, although I think that person would be quite rich anyway, but incentives that
are even more powerful than markets. But on the flip side, this is a really important point in economics that many
people don't understand. It is always better to be able to get something for nothing than to have
to put real resources into doing it. So any time that we can find a way to get rid of a problem
for nothing, we want to do it. So we right now invest enormous resources in trying to fight
cancer. But if we didn't have to spend those resources fighting cancer,
we would spend them on something else that people liked.
And the world would be a much better place.
A good example of this is labor.
Let's say that instead of it taking eight hours for a person to produce 100 wallets or whatever their job is,
let's say they could do that in four hours.
They could produce 100 wallets.
Well, then they just bought four free hours of leisure.
And that would be a great thing.
The less labor you need, the less capital you need to make something, the better.
And so there's this crazy, Keynesian argument about, oh, you need people to be busy.
You need demand and whatnot.
But absolutely for certain, no doubt about it, if you can suddenly make things for free that used to cost
you money, the world is a much better place because you just reallocate all the resources
you were, quote, wasting on solving cancer before and put them to do something else.
It also makes me think of, on a smaller scale but not insignificant, what happened in this
country and elsewhere with polio, right? Which is at one point, even though polio was never that
massive disease, it was crippling for those who had it. If it didn't kill them,
it crippled them. And most of the money was put into treatment. And for a long time,
there was not much thinking about the idea of a vaccine. It wasn't really the main line of thought
than that came to be. And then a vaccine mentality took and a vaccine, two vaccines were actually created. So, Damon's question is a little
bit like saying, you know, the incentives of the people who make the iron lung are so strong that
they will prevent anybody else from actually pursuing a vaccine. But as we've seen over and
over again, those aren't the same people and they pursue different paths. Yeah, I think that's right.
If you compare that, though, to something more like car seats, I think it is true that right now, the people who make car seats are the same
kind of people who might push for other ways to keep kids safe in cars. And there, I think there
are more obstacles. It's just that in the world of medicine, the particular pharma companies who
make a particular cancer drug have zero control over the thousands of medical researchers who are
scattered across the globe trying to solve these problems. And so I think you're exactly right,
that there's no cartel which is blocking the production of a cancer vaccine. It's just a
really hard problem that people are trying to make headway on and not yet succeeding.
Levitt, here's a question from Marie.
She writes, since people are genuinely fair and pay for bagels on the honor system.
Okay, that's referring to our bagel study in Freakonomics.
We can explain that a little bit more.
Why does this not apply to song downloads?
Or do most people pay for music?
I do, but my students don't if they can get it for free from their friends or online.
Is the payment on the honor system only for smaller businesses where people feel a personal attachment?
I think that's a great point.
I think that on these issues of honor, it's very predictable the kinds of factors which make people be honest. One is
scrutiny. If you know you're being watched, you're much more likely to be honest. I think if you
believe that the recipient of the money is deserving, you very much tend to be honest.
And I also think that if you are in settings which in general evoke honesty, like it happens to be inside of a church or a hospital, I think, again, you're more likely to be honest.
Okay, so how do we compare from the bagels, which have a lot of these features of scrutiny and the bagel man was a sort of sympathetic character who didn't have a lot of money, to big business and the downloading of songs.
And I think here it's my impression that there's an amazing generational break where people who grew up having to pay for music when they were young,
people of our generation, Dubner, understand the idea that you should pay for music,
and it doesn't seem strange.
Whereas I do think with young people the natural instinct is that the Internet is a place for free things and that they deserve to get their music for free. for some reason, consumed like half of his donuts. Everybody else mostly wanted bagels. But he would deliver them and put a box out for money,
and he would post the price,
and he would then come back later to collect the money,
and it worked.
It was an honor system scheme that worked.
But I think the key differences,
so there are all these pay-what-you-wish schemes
and honor system schemes
that have floated up in the last many years.
And I think there are a couple of huge differences between them and the bagel story that people don't get.
One is it wasn't a pay-what-you-wish, the bagel thing.
There were prices posted.
The bagel costs whatever, a buck, and with cream cheese, a buck and a half.
So what's interesting to me about this is not only do a lot of people pay something,
but they pay exactly the right price in part
because it seems, and we've written about this a good bit, that you can really herd people into
doing what you want them to do simply by telling them that everybody else is doing it and by kind
of setting the parameters, right, Levitt? It seems that people are much more willing than they might
think to kind of go along with the herd. Yeah, that's absolutely true.
But this is also a case of technology where you and I don't actually know how to steal music.
Well, I do.
Do you know how to steal music?
I do.
Oh, I don't know how to steal music.
I could teach you.
Okay. I think the other thing about the bagel story that people miss and they try to apply it to other instances is that he, Paul Feldman, the bagel guy, had some real leverage, which was this.
If the payment rate from the whole group in a given office fell below a certain amount, he would stop bringing them bagels.
And that's what all these other schemes almost never have.
Well, they may have it and it may be a bright line, but you don't know when you're getting to it.
So if you know that this thing that you want and that's being offered at a price that you have to contribute a certain amount toward will no longer be delivered to you, a nice warm bagel to your office, then that's not really as altruistic as people seem to think.
And so therefore, it doesn't surprise me that when there's no leverage exerted, that people would steal as much as they can get away with.
All right.
Thank you very much. Sorry, that was terrible.
No, that was fine.
That was one of my worst performances in ages.
No, you did.
There were really good sputs.
Do you still have 10 minutes or no?
You know, I should probably go in a couple, actually.
All right.
I think we're good.
Okay.
Good job, Levitt.
Okay.
Great.
Great.
Great. Put down that steering wheel. That's right. The driverless car is coming.
So the throttle, the brake, the steering wheel, the turn signals,
everything is being controlled by a computer right now.
I'm just sitting here.
A few weeks ago, I went for a ride in a driverless car,
and I'll tell you all about it next time on Freakonomics Radio. American Public Media, and Dubner Productions. This episode was produced by Susie Lechtenberg.
Our staff includes Catherine Wells, David Herman,
Bray Lamb, and Chris Bannon.
Colin Campbell is our executive producer.
If you want more Freakonomics Radio,
you can subscribe to our podcast on iTunes
or go to Freakonomics.com,
where you'll find lots of radio, a blog, the books, and more.