Freakonomics Radio - 186. Why Do People Keep Having Children?
Episode Date: November 13, 2014Even a brutal natural disaster doesn’t diminish our appetite for procreating. This surely means we’re heading toward massive overpopulation, right? Probably not. ...
Transcript
Discussion (0)
My name's Emily Oster. I'm an economist. I work at Brown University.
Cool. And let me ask you this easy question. We'll start. Why do people have kids,
Emily? I mean, biological imperative apart, unless it's all the biological imperative.
I think this is probably an open question for debate. I think many people would tell you that
it's the biological imperative. I think that some people would tell you that it's the biological imperative.
I think that some people would tell you, you know, kids are enjoyable.
I think that some people would tell you, particularly in developing countries, people have kids as an investment in their old age or even, you know, to work on their farms when the kids are young.
So I think those are probably the leading candidate explanations.
Okay. And those are all good and believable in theory. Do we have any data that suggests
that we actually know anything about this question or not really?
We have some data and I think that probably you'd see all of those things show up as explanations.
I mean, we certainly see people having remittances from their kids and telling us that, you know,
remittances from their kids are an important that, you know, remittances from their
kids are an important reason to have children. And certainly, you know, many people will tell
you I enjoy having my kids, maybe not at every single moment, but that broadly, I like them.
And that that was a reason to do it. But I think it's hard to separate the biological imperative,
because of course, your biology is telling you that that's something you want to do. And once you've done it, you hardly want to say, actually, that was, it was all biology.
It was all biology. And you know, yeah, exactly.
From WNYC, this is Freakonomics Radio, the podcast that explores the hidden side of everything.
Here's your host, Stephen Dubner. We're talking today about fertility and then mortality and then how fertility is affected by mortality.
We might even get to overpopulation.
The economist Emily Oster has done a lot of research on fertility. She's also the author of a book called Expecting Better, Why Conventional Pregnancy Wisdom
is Wrong and What You Really Need to Know.
Let me ask you this.
When you bring up, you know, the different economic parts of the reason why people have
kids or maybe explain after the fact why they've had kids, what do we know generally about
the factors that make a given
person or family more or less likely to have kids? Let's say socioeconomic status, maybe the
political environment in the place you live, personal philosophy or religion, access to
technology. I mean, those are just a few of the ones we can think of.
Yeah, I think many of those things are going to matter. I think certainly, you know, what kind
of birth control you have access to is going
to influence how many kids you have because your ability to control it is influenced by
birth control.
I think income is an important component of this.
One of the most striking facts about fertility over the last several decades is that as many
countries have gotten richer, fertility has gone down really dramatically, even in places
that used to be very poor. And I think many people interpret that as an effect of income, that as you get
richer, you want fewer children for various reasons. So I think that looks like a very strong
driver of this effect. You wrote a paper that I love about India and the introduction of TV
in different areas in India, which allowed you to
measure well the changes that TV brought. Can you talk about that in terms of fertility?
Yeah. So in that paper, we look at what happens when people get access to cable television,
and we find something which actually has also been echoed in a study in Brazil,
which is that when people get access to cable TV, which really lets them watch soap operas,
it actually decreases their fertility. And one interpretation of that is that people see, you
know, the people on TV, they have fewer kids, and they have this really fancy life, presumably
because they're on television. But you know, maybe if I had fewer kids, I could have that also. And
I think that's sort of one interpretation of that. I guess another interpretation might be that soap operas are not as sexy as previously thought.
No, true. And also people are too busy watching TV to have sex is another interpretation we
considered. What do we know, if anything, about, I don't know quite what to call it, I guess,
mood or affect, you know, whether, let's say someone who is optimistic about their own future,
maybe their country's own future is more or less likely to have children? Yeah, I think the best evidence we have from that is
about what happens in recessions, which is that fertility goes down. So even though broadly,
as countries get richer over periods of decades, fertility goes down as money goes up.
In the short term, when we see a recession, we tend to see declines in
fertility. And that sort of suggests that when people are less optimistic and, you know, maybe
things are more complicated economically, that that's a time if you will choose to delay.
But how can you tease out the, you know, economic optimism versus the economic reality? In other
words, maybe I want to have kids right now, but I or a partner just lost a job or
just got downgraded somehow. How do you tease out the mental effect? That is a very hard thing to
tease out. I think you could do it by looking, you can do it by looking at people who haven't lost
their job. On the other hand, those people may be more at risk of losing their job. So separating
those things out is hard. And looking at people's affect by
asking them, like, how do you feel about this? And so on is, of course, confounded by a lot of other
things. You want to find something that changes people's mood about, say, their economic
circumstances or something else without actually changing those circumstances. And that thought
experiment is very hard. So to me, one of the most interesting, if not necessarily broadly compelling arguments
for the relationship between, let's say, you know, optimism and fertility is contained in a paper you
wrote that's so fascinating. We talked to you about it earlier about Huntington's disease and whether people who are genetically predisposed toward carrying it will want to get the test.
And if they do or don't, how their lives may change or not change in light of that.
So one surprising finding, at least surprising to me, is that people who know that they may be genetically predisposed to Huntington's disease aren't less likely to have kids.
Yes. Yes?
Why is that?
Why, in your view and from the data, do you believe that's true?
So I think our view when we looked at the data on this, and again, this is something
where we can see the fact, but it's harder to see the interpretation.
Our view is that people are not interested in facing the possible negative reality, and they would like to sort of take actions which make them feel like things are going to be okay.
And if you want to have kids, you want to have kids.
And that is something you're going to do anyway.
And better to do it sooner so you're healthy for longer with these kids than you would be otherwise. And so
I think that was our interpretation in that. So if I'm an HD carrier, or I may be, and I don't
know yet, there are two potential consequences to consider if I'm thinking about having kids. One is
I, as a parent, may die relatively early, relatively young, and I, as a parent, may bequeath
to my offspring this same genetic
predisposition to this disease. Do you have any idea how those two potentialities are
weighed in the minds of people with HD? I think we don't, although, you know,
from some anecdotal stuff, I think one of the pictures you get is that many people are
optimistic, and I think we can all be hopeful about this, that there may be a better treatment
or a cure for Huntington's disease in the future. And when you think about a disease like this,
which has onset in adulthood, like in the 40s or 50s, and you think about having a child now,
it's easy to imagine that maybe something will be different about treatment or cures later on.
And so I think the sort of feeling of salience about passing on
the gene is perhaps less strong than it would be if it were something which you knew would manifest
right away, like Tay-Sachs. Yeah. It strikes me as we're talking about this, that optimism
or pessimism are almost impossible really to measure, aren't they? I mean, you can ask people,
but that doesn't really get you very far, does it?
Yeah, I agree. I don't think it gets you very far. And I think people will tell you
things which are not right or a very person specific. I mean, my impression from some of
the psychology of this is that, you know, people's level of optimism is pretty similar within a
person, no matter what's going on. So, you know, if something really good happens, you're happy for like a few days, but you know, then you go back to baseline and sort of similarly,
if something really bad happens, you're unhappy for a while, but you go back to baseline. And I
think that's sort of something that, that means it's hard. A lot of what you're going to pick up
is sort of constant differences across people rather than changes over time that might affect
their behavior. Gotcha. Okay. So considering that and considering everything that you, Emily, know about fertility and pregnancy and mortality, let's say that there's a terrible, terrible natural disaster that kills hundreds of thousands of people, including many, many, many, many children who are very vulnerable to a natural disaster. What would you expect to happen in that kind of circumstance, that people would
hurry to repopulate or that they'd be so stricken that they'd not want to have kids?
It's an interesting question. I mean, it feels like a question for the data. I think both of
those things would happen. My instinct, based on what we know about fertility and high mortality
environments, is that people would try to replace lost children.
Because one of the explanations for why there's such high fertility in the developing world,
sort of, you know, many decades ago is that child mortality was so high, you want to have a lot of
kids to replace the children that do not survive. And so an extension of that would be if you sort
of lost a child or God forbid children
in a disaster, that you would want to have more children to replace them. But as you say,
on the other side, there's sort of this terrible thing has happened and there's sort of incredible
pessimism. And so that might affect fertility in the other direction.
But it's not like you can come up with an experiment to answer this question, right?
It's not like you'd want to randomly kill a thousand children in one state and not kill any children in the next door state and see what fertility looks like in those two states.
I agree. That does not sound like a great idea.
And I think this is a hard thing to imagine.
It's a hard thing to imagine testing for that reason. Sometimes, nature provides a tragedy that, on top of being a tragedy,
is also an opportunity to answer this kind of question.
In this case, it happened on December 26, 2004.
Good evening. The depths of the Indian Ocean have spawned a natural disaster enormous in scale.
The most powerful earthquake in 40 years hit Asia overnight,
the epicenter 40 miles off the coast of the northern Indonesian island of Sumatra,
but it triggered massive tsunamis, tidal waves...
Here, this shocked family in Banda Aceh watched from the second floor of their home
as water engulfs the town, devouring
almost everything in its path. Tsunami waves made no distinction between rich and poor,
foreigners and locals. Children suffered particularly because they couldn't run away.
This was an awesome, appalling and extraordinary event.
The power of nature against the flimsy will of man.
The tsunami killed more than 200,000 people, the vast majority of them in Indonesia.
One of the things that the tsunami did in terms of its impact on mortality was create large gaps in the population. Women were more
vulnerable to being killed in the tsunami, and young children and older people as well. And so
in the communities that were very badly damaged, you can actually see gaps in the age structure
and the sex composition of the population. That's Elizabeth Frankenberg. I'm a demographer
and a sociologist at Duke University.
I teach in the Sanford School of Public Policy.
And for the past 20 years or so, I've been studying various facets of demography and
economics, particularly in Indonesia, but in developing countries.
And most recently, my colleagues and I have been working on a project to understand how
the tsunami that occurred in 2004 affected well-beingbeing both in the short term and the longer term.
Frankenberg has been going to Indonesia for many years.
Well, the very beginning was way back in 1985. I was an undergraduate at the University of North
Carolina. And I, you know, my dad was curious what I'd University of North Carolina. And I, you know,
my dad was curious what I'd do when I graduated. And I said, well, I really want to work on issues
in developing countries. And, you know, his advice, which was good advice, was, well, you probably
ought to spend some time in one first before you commit too much to that. And I really love
Indonesia. I love traveling there. I've made probably one trip a year or so in many years, two or three or four trips. So I've gone a lot. I go regularly. I have great colleagues there. You know, a lot of my work is with Duncan Thomas, an economist here at Duke. We worked with our colleagues.
Now, you ended up marrying him a little bit, didn't you?
I did marry him. 100% married. After the tsunami, Frankenberg and her colleagues had a specific
set of issues to explore. Well, we wanted to look at two questions, really. What happens to women's
fertility in the aftermath of a shock of this nature that has several different components to it.
One is mortality, mortality in communities, but also mortality within families.
Another is the trauma that people were exposed to as a result of what had happened, because the people that survived, many of them were caught up in the water or experienced other
traumatic experiences.
And comparing at an aggregate level, fertility
for women from two different types of communities, communities where the mortality impact had been
very large relative to communities that had no tsunami mortality. And then within those communities,
fertility of women who had lost a child relative to fertility of women who had not lost any children.
Had this kind of idea linking mortality, kind of a mortality shock and the resultant fertility been studied before?
Or was this sort of the first of its kind?
This is fairly unusual, really quite unusual. So people have certainly been interested in how fertility
changes in the aftermath of large-scale social upheavals, so wars and things like that.
But there have been relatively fewer efforts to look at fertility
directly in relationship to levels of mortality.
So what'd you find?
So we found a couple of things. One is that if you start from
the perspective of communities, we compared fertility before the tsunami in communities
that would later be strongly affected by tsunami mortality to fertility before the tsunami in
communities that did not later experience these high death rates. And before the tsunami, fertility was a little bit lower in the communities that would later experience such high mortality.
Which we shouldn't draw any conclusion from.
That's just random, I assume.
Well, yes.
If not random, maybe is it a socioeconomic?
Yeah, it's more of a socioeconomic thing.
Okay.
So then we look at what happened after the tsunami. And what we find is
that fertility rose in the places that had very high levels of community mortality from the tsunami,
but fell for women from communities that had not had high levels of tsunami mortality.
And so they really respond in different ways with respect to fertility. And that introduces this
gap. So we see this big fertility increase
in the places where mortality from the tsunami was very high.
And can you just specify a little bit here,
we're talking about mortality of any and everyone
or mortality particularly of children?
We looked at it from both perspectives,
but I've been talking about mortality of any and everyone.
But the results are the same
if you limit it to mortality of children.
Okay.
So, so far, the baseline, what you've established and told us is that in the areas where the mortality from tsunami was higher, fertility rates went up.
Yes, exactly.
All right.
Tell me more.
So, then we also wanted to know for individual women whether their characteristics were linked to their fertility behaviors after the
tsunami. And so demographers have long wondered about whether when women lose a child, a child
dies, whether they become pregnant again to replace that child, effectively having a birth
that would not have otherwise occurred. So we looked at whether losing a child in the tsunami predicted a birth after the tsunami.
And the answer to that question was yes.
Women who had lost a child in the tsunami were about 10 percentage points more likely to have another birth after the tsunami than women whose children had survived.
10 percentage points.
And how many percent would that be?
I assume that's quite a big rise.
Yeah, that was about a 37% increase.
And did that surprise you or no?
I would say that it did not.
We didn't know what we would find, but, you know, we thought that it could have perhaps gone either way.
I mean, perhaps women would be stressed and sad and grieving and not ready to do this again.
But, you know, they might also, it might also be natural to have another child.
So we thought it could go either way.
So I would not say I was surprised by the finding, but I didn't have a strong prior that it would turn out that way.
So that was one piece of it was that women who had lost a child to death in the tsunami were considerably more likely to have a baby again after the tsunami.
And then the other question was whether women who had not yet had children after the tsunami had children.
And what we find then is that as the mortality rate rises in the community, women who had not yet had children were more likely to become mothers.
So there's an interaction between the amount of mortality in the community going to have a first birth sooner than a woman in
province B where there was low mortality or would have more children over time?
Or do you not know that yet?
That's a great question.
We don't know that yet.
What we know, well, we know that they had the children earlier than would have otherwise
been the case.
But whether they will ultimately go on to have more is a question we can only answer
when we have data from later waves.
And we have a 10-year survey in the field right now, and that will help us answer that question.
But that's absolutely an important question to know the answer to that we don't know yet.
Right. So let me ask you the most obvious and maybe the hardest question, and maybe there's no answer for this, or maybe you don't have the answer for this, but why? So if you observed a strong boost in fertility among communities where
there was a lot of death from the tsunami, and you make a point of noting that there are two kinds,
there's women who lost children who are, quote, replacing, and women who haven't yet had children
who are having them sooner. Is there anything you can say about the why other than typical human
speculation? So some of it's speculation speculation and some of it we know a little
bit about. And so we did ask people after the tsunami whether they wanted to have more children.
And, you know, the women we observe having more children indeed articulated a desire to have
children after the tsunami. So it certainly doesn't seem to have been an accidental result
or a result of poor
access to contraception. Right. It could be that the tsunami wiped out all access to contraception.
But then on the other hand, there's available mates, too. How does that factor into it?
So marriage and childbearing are certainly tightly linked. But because so many more women
were killed in the tsunami than men, more of the men in our study lost spouses than women lost spouses.
So marriage is certainly a part of it.
And it's, you know, part of that fertility increase is younger women marrying and going ahead and having children.
You know, as to the why, so we do ask people whether they want more children.
We don't ask them why they want more children.
And, you know, then you start to be more speculative.
But I have to say, as I've traveled in Indonesia and watched the recovery in Aceh unfold, you know, one of the things that strikes me about Aceh is it's a place with such a strong sense of identity, of ethnic identity as Acehnese.
And so I do think that there was a tremendous will to rebuild.
And that's, you know, part of that is rebuilding families and population,
but it's also rebuilding homes and livelihoods and the province overall. And, you know, I think
that's a really important theme of, you know, both the fertility results, but also in some
of the other work we've done, recovery
more generally.
Coming up on Freakonomics Radio, people don't have children today for the same reasons they
used to.
You know, childhood used to be like,
by the time you're six,
you're up at 4.30 milking the cows.
And now it's like, you know,
I'm taking you to soccer practice
at 14 different locations.
So you can, you know,
get into the right college
or whatever it is.
And one more thing.
If you have about 150 hours
with absolutely nothing to do,
check out our back catalog of Freakonomics Radio podcasts on iTunes or at Freakonomics.com.
And if you subscribe on iTunes or using another podcast app, you will always getonomics Radio. Here's your host, Stephen Dubner. So Elizabeth Frankenberg, a demographer my mind, at least for whatever that's
worth, is that it's a very, I don't know about inspiring, but hopeful finding in that here's
a terrible tragedy that affects a lot of people. And rather than swear off community and, you know,
country and family, the opposite happened. And I'm curious what you think may have driven this
on a broader scale.
Do you think religion plays a role? Do you think the regional or cultural attitudes play a role?
In other words, if a tsunami hit, you know, the southeastern United States, do you have any idea
whether the findings might be remotely similar or South America?
Well, let me come back to Southeast United States and South America.
So I definitely think that the fertility response, I mean, I agree with you that there's a strong sort of signal about hope in seeing this impact, this fertility impact. villages and watching these new homes be built and go from empty to inhabited to places where families live and families with little kids live and these kids are out there playing and helping
their parents do various things. You know, it really does create this sense of renewal in a
way that's very, very fundamental. So I think you're right about this sense of hope coming out of these results.
And, you know, I suspect that religion is involved in it.
Aceh is a very, very strongly religious place.
And in addition, the Acehnese people are very proud and independent people.
And so I think it's both, you know, faith in religion and also faith in identity in some sense. You know, and I should say, in addition to the family rebuilding,
there was all this rebuilding of housing and infrastructure and roads and schools. And,
you know, that was a function both of Atini's perseverance, but also of an incredible outpouring
of funding for recovery effort from all around the the world and a very strong effort by the
Indonesian government to channel that money into effective reconstruction policies and
assistance.
And so I think, you know, an important backdrop of rebuilding families is the fact that assets
were also getting replaced.
People were working those sorts of economic aspects of recovery as well.
Okay.
And answer, if you feel like it,
if you feel you have an answer to the second half of that very long question I asked about
whether the same event, not a different event, but whether the same event had happened elsewhere in
the world, if you have any knowledge at all into whether we'd see a similar effect.
Well, I do think that we would see this effect of fertility rise in places where children are killed suddenly and unexpectedly as a result of natural disasters. And so there has been a little work on other earthquakes that shows something similar, I guess, you know, schools were very, very badly damaged and many children were killed and many of those children were only children.
And Chinese government actually put in place a policy to try to help people who wanted to have an additional child at that point get access to reproductive, assisted reproductive technology if they wanted to try to have children again.
So I don't think this fertility response is unique to Aceh or to Indonesia.
So we've learned that fertility tends to rise after a natural disaster,
which might easily be interpreted as purely good news,
as a triumph of the human spirit. On the other hand, what about overpopulation? For much of the
past century, one of humankind's most pressing fears is that we're putting way too many people
on the planet. Now, among population scholars, there's a famous saying, development is the best
contraceptive. That is, as countries get richer,
their population growth tends to slow. I asked the economist Emily Oster how well this saying
is supported by the data. I think the data suggests that's very true. So some of the
changes in fertility over time in countries that are relatively poor have been incredibly striking. So for example, in the 1960s, India's fertility rate was at six. It is now at 2.5. In that period,
Singapore's fertility rate was 5.6. It's now at 1.3, which is far, far below replacement.
And even in Kenya, which isn't like a particularly rich country, the fertility rate now is about 4.4, down from eight
or nine in the 1960s. And those changes have been achieved. Yes, there has been some increase in
birth control access, which we don't want to dismiss, but I think it's pretty clear from the
timing that the development effects are just incredibly, incredibly important in driving this.
So this leads us to a future that doesn't resemble at all the future that was predicted by demographers not even that long ago, 20 years ago. So let me
ask you this, Emily, if you and I went out and did a survey right now on the streets of New York,
on the streets of Providence, and asked 100 people the following question, the world population today
is X. What would you expect the world population by the turn of the next century to be in relationship
to X? What do you think would be the median or the average response there?
Yeah, I think people would think the number is 2X or something. But I think the number is not 2X.
I mean, there's actually increasingly few countries whose fertility rate is above
replacement, and many countries where the fertility rate is substantially below replacement.
So the UN is currently projecting that the global population will peak at around 8.3 billion in
2050 and then fall to less than the current 7.2 billion population by 2100. So keeping in mind
how terrible most predictions are, just let's take
that prediction on its face value, at least when factored into everything that you've been telling
us about fertility and development and so on. What is the kind of headline for that set of
statistics? How would you describe where we're heading globally in terms of population and how we got there and what it means?
I mean, I think the two factors that this change are likely to produce is one,
the population is going to be much older. So for most of human history, the kind of population
pyramid has been more people who are young, fewer people who are old. That's still going to be true
to some extent. You're not going to have the population primarily made up of people who are old, that's still going to be true kind of to some extent, you're not going to have the population primarily made up of people who are 120. But the balance between,
say, 65 year olds and 25 year olds is going to be very different. And that's something that's going
to, you know, drive a lot of policy and the way that demographics work. I think the other thing
that's going to happen is for a while, at least, relatively poor countries are going to continue to have
fertility above replacement, while relatively rich countries do not. And that's going to change
the balance of population counts across these places even more so than now.
So is that the driving factor in lower fertility rates is income? When you look at the countries
with the lowest fertility rates around the world, is that what they primarily have in common?
When you start trying to distinguish among fertility rates, all of which are below replacement, the links with income become more mushy.
So the places with the lowest fertility rates are like Singapore and Hong Kong and Taiwan.
I mean, those are rich countries, but they're not as rich as, say, Finland. Right. But there are other parts of Asia where the fertility rate is still relatively low, way, way, way lower than similarly poor parts of Africa, let's say, right?
Yes, I agree. So income sort of operates in like the places the highest fertility are very poor, Niger, Mali.
But the income fertility relationship does seem to break down a little bit when you get into the very low fertility rates.
The U.S. has higher fertility than, say, most of Europe, even though the U.S. is relatively
richer. That said, fertility is falling pretty much everywhere around the world, correct? I mean,
yes, pretty much. So why have we seen such sharp declines in fertility, even in so many developing
countries where kind of the promise of the economic future isn't there yet?
I think the promise of the economic future is there more than we think.
I mean, even places which are very poor, where things do not seem to be going that great.
I think if you look sort of broadly since in the last 50 years, actually, the economic climate has improved.
The health climate has improved.
One of the reasons to have fewer kids is because fewer of them die in childhood. Once we start vaccinating people, which we're actually
getting very good at, even in poor places, then you don't need to have as many kids to achieve
the number you want to end up with. That's something called the demographic transition,
which I think has sort of started happening basically everywhere. So I do think actually
many, many, many places in the world, things are getting
better, not worse.
Can you talk to me for one sec about how the reason for having children has changed over
the centuries? And obviously, there's still variants around the world.
But, you know, from sort of captive workforce and insurance policies to, in many countries, at least, almost consumer durables or luxury goods.
Yeah. I mean, if you think about a place like the U.S., there was certainly a time.
It wasn't that long ago, 200 years, maybe, when a lot of the reason to have kids was you had a farm.
There's a lot to do,
people got to work on it. That was a major source of motivation for childbearing. That really isn't
true anymore. I think over time, we've sort of moved to a place where children have gotten to be
more of an investment and a consumption good. And even if you expect to get something out of them,
it's kind of like very far in the future. And it's more of an enjoyment thing than actually this person is going to pay for me to live a
life of luxury. So I think that has really changed and it's changed the way we approach
childhood. I mean, I think there's a lot of discussion of, you know, childhood used to be
like, by the time you're six, you're up at 430 milking the cows. And now it's like, you know, I'm taking
you to soccer practice at 14 different locations so you can, you know, get into the right college
or whatever it is. You know, when people listen to economists, they hear two things that to me
at least sound contradictory. One is if you don't have enough people being born in a given place,
you're in economic trouble because there won't be enough young workers to shore up the economy and the older retiring workers and so on.
But you also hear if you have too many people born in a given place, you know, there won't be enough jobs and funds for all those people and everyone in that place will suffer.
So tell me, Emily, are these two arguments as contradictory as they seem to me?
And if not, maybe even if so, is there some perfect magic
fertility rate that makes an economy hum? It's 2.2. No. Okay. See you later. Thanks.
Thanks very much. No. So, I mean, I think these are, both of these things are true.
They are true for different reasons. You know, it is true that if you have a very old population,
there are not as many people to support them. It's not that you couldn't design policies that would allow that to work fine. It's just that the current policies most places have
in place are not designed for that. So if you think about Social Security,
it relies on people paying in so it can pay out. If you don't have enough people paying in,
you're going to struggle to pay out. You could design a different system where people pay in and they get out what they put in.
That would be sustainable no matter what your fertility rate is. It just isn't the system we
have set up now. On the other side, on the sort of population growth side, I think it is true that
as places grow very quickly in terms of population, that that can be problematic for finding jobs.
But again, it's a question of how you set up the incentives population, that that can be problematic for finding jobs. But again,
it's a question of how you set up the incentives. And that can also be good for places because they get a lot of new workers and new people to do stuff.
And that is an important aspect of economic growth as well. So tell me if the following statements are true.
You, Emily Oster, along with your husband, Jesse Shapiro, who's also an economist,
currently have one child named Penelope, who's roughly three years old.
Yeah, she's three and a half.
Okay.
Furthermore, you, Emily Oster, presumably along with your husband, Jesse Shapiro, once more,
are expecting a second child. Yes, we are. Okay. Furthermore, you, Emily Oster, presumably along with your husband, Jesse Shapiro, once more are expecting a second child.
Yes, we are.
Okay. So in summary, why? Why are you having a second kid?
Well, the first one is so great. No, I mean, I really like I love having a kid is like the greatest thing that ever happened.
And I think, you know, we would like her to have a sibling. And so we're going to see how that goes. Hey, podcast listeners on the next Freakonomics Radio. I don't know what's on the next Freakonomics
Radio. We've got so much good stuff cooking, we haven't been able to decide yet. You might hear
Boris Johnson, the mayor of London, talking about his new Winston Churchill book.
It's the gift he had for using very, very, not just long or a ton bombastic
Churchillian circumlocutions. Or you might hear about what's wrong with American education. So I think, yes, the way we train teachers is fundamentally broken in this country.
And you might even hear Steve Levitt talking about, well, about this.
Oh, it's disgusting, but honestly, I really try to avoid
restrooms where there are lots of men doing fireworks, you know?
That's next week, one of them at least, on Freakonomics Radio.
Freakonomics Radio is produced by WNYC and Dubner Productions.
Our staff includes David Herman, Greg Rosalski, Greta Cohn, Caroline English,
Susie Lechtenberg, and Chris Bannon, with help from Joel Werner.
If you want more Freakonomics Radio, you can subscribe to our podcast on iTunes
or go to Freakonomics.com, where you'll find lots of radio, a blog, the books, and more. Thank you.