Freakonomics Radio - 273. Did China Eat America’s Jobs?

Episode Date: January 26, 2017

For years, economists promised that global free trade would be mostly win-win. Now they admit the pace of change has been "traumatic." This has already led to a political insurrection -- so ...what's next?

Transcript
Discussion (0)
Starting point is 00:00:00 I entered the profession late, actually. I had several failed careers prior to economics. That's David Autor, A-U-T-O-R, if you want to look him up. I'm a labor economist at MIT. And what does a labor economist do? I work a lot on skill demands and changes in labor markets having to do with technology and with trade as well. As Autor said, he came late to academia. I did software development for a while, and I also spent several years directing a nonprofit in San Francisco
Starting point is 00:00:33 that did computer education for the poor, and then I also did a lot of work in fast food. I spent a month working at McDonald's and half a year working at Papa Gino's, which is a kind of pizza franchise in the Boston area. So I just I did a lot of blue collar work. I also worked as a temp. I did, you know, light construction and cleaning. I also fix cars and motorcycles and electronics.
Starting point is 00:00:57 So Otter hasn't spent his entire adulthood in the ivory tower, and that is reflected in his choice of economic specialty. I think we labor economists like to think of ourselves as being closer to the people. I'm pretty cognizant of how tough the labor market has been for them for the last 35 years. For the past several years, Autor and several colleagues, including Gordon Hanson, David Dorn, Darren Asimoglu, Brendan Price, and Kaveh Majlesi, have been analyzing huge data sets to try to answer an important economic question. The objective was to understand how China's very rapidly rising exports to the United States were affecting U.S. labor markets.
Starting point is 00:01:39 Today on Freakonomics Radio, the answer to that question, how it relates to American political rhetoric and what economists got wrong. I think if we had realized how traumatic the pace of change would have been, we would have, at a minimum, had much better policies in place? From WNYC Studios, this is Freakonomics Radio, the podcast that explores the hidden side of everything. Here's your host, Stephen Dubner.
Starting point is 00:02:36 Our previous episode looked at the degree to which the American dream has been damaged. You're twice as likely to realize the American dream if you're growing up in Canada rather than the U.S. This topic was a main feature of the 2016 presidential campaign. Sadly, the American dream is dead. As for who killed the American dream? Donald Trump had a long list of suspects, but very near the top was China. We can't continue to allow China to rape our country. And that's what they're doing. It's the greatest theft in the history of the world. This was a theme that President Trump returned to during his inaugural speech.
Starting point is 00:03:17 We've made other countries rich while the wealth, strength, and confidence of our country has dissipated over the horizon. One by one, the factories shuttered and left our shores, with not even a thought about the millions and millions of American workers that were left behind. During the campaign, many people had been so focused on Trump's outrageous persona that perhaps they saw his claims about China and trade as similarly outrageous, hyperbolic at best, outright wrong at worst. Wasn't the U.S. a willing partner and an architect of the huge push toward globalization? We endorsed sending low-wage manufacturing jobs overseas, believing we'd get cheaper imports and newer, better jobs to replace
Starting point is 00:04:14 the offshored ones. So how well has that dreamy scenario worked out? I'm much less sanguine about it than I used to be. Let's start with a bit of history between the U.S. and China. The adversarial relationship kicked off by the communist revolution in 1949 blossomed into a full-blown Cold War, which began to fizzle out quite shockingly in 1971. That's when President Richard Nixon, a devout anti-communist to that point, reached out to Chairman Mao as a partner. The meeting between the leaders of China and the United States is to seek the normalization of relations between the two countries. China was sort of a perpetual state of economic crisis
Starting point is 00:04:58 from the Mao Zedong era forward and really didn't have its act together as a trading country or producer, and it was largely closed. David Otter again. And it wasn't until Deng Xiaoping took power and began changing things in the late 1970s and began what he called reform and opening, which meant setting up export zones in the southern parts of China across from Hong Kong, allowing foreign direct investment, allowing use of market prices, allowing for mobility of labor. So over the course of 20 years, about a quarter of a billion people migrated out of a relatively unproductive rural agriculture into cities to do production. Just incredible. Between 1991 and 2013, Chinese exports grew from roughly 2% of the world's total to nearly 20%.
Starting point is 00:05:47 And China marched from being, you know, 30 or 40 years behind the frontier of production to being really a world-class producer with, at that time, lots of available labor and lots of available land and, you know, lots of resources. Other countries had taken the same route as China, but China was different in several ways, but most significantly in size. So, you know, if a country like Vietnam or Cambodia or something went through the exact same developmental process as China, it would quickly run out of capacity. And after a very little while, it would have made all the,
Starting point is 00:06:21 you know, the iPhones and the apparel and the toys and so on. It could. And then wages would rise, prices would rise. It would just be a blip on the world scale. But because China is so enormous and had so much slack, it took decades for that string to play out. And in that time, it was just producing goods, high-quality goods at low prices that were extraordinarily competitive by world standards. And this had the effect of displacing a lot of competitor countries' production, including the United States. So, David, you and some colleagues have taken a hard look at how globalization
Starting point is 00:06:58 has had some profound effects. So, tell us broadly what you know and how you know it. Sure. So economists have known forever or, you know, since the 1950s that globalization or the integration between trading partners raises GDP, raises national incomes in both countries if they're consenting partners, but can have adverse distributional consequences. Adverse distributional consequences being economists speak for a rising tide that does not lift all boats. So even as it makes a country wealthier, it can make some people in that country poorer in absolute terms. So it can grow the size of the pie pie but make some slices sufficiently smaller that in net they contract. However, literature had failed to find any strong evidence that those adverse distributional
Starting point is 00:07:52 consequences were coming to pass. The literature being the economics literature, meaning that as economists watched globalization accelerate, it seemed to be working out pretty well. I think labor economics sort of 15 years ago, a lot of people saw it as, oh, well, now we're sort of studying well-functioning markets. It's about characterizing equilibria and explaining why it's all efficient. We should turn our attention to the developing world where all the problems are. That view turned out to be illusory or at least short-lived.
Starting point is 00:08:22 But now we have lots of problems. People recognize that and they sort of see labor as being part of the big challenges facing lots of countries, including the developed world, in terms of income distribution, opportunity, the sort of changing share of national income going to capital versus labor, the role of globalization in shaping opportunities, and even the way that labor markets feed into political outcomes and people's sense of party identity and the type of candidates that they vote for. That said, David Autor is not willing to throw his profession under the bus. I don't think the old evidence was incorrect.
Starting point is 00:09:01 There are two big differences of the last two decades relative to earlier periods. One is that a lot of our trade prior to China's rise, a lot of it was North-North trade, you know, trading between wealthy nations. So, you know, we sell aircraft engines to France and we buy, you know, cheese and wine and Renaults, or maybe we buy Mercedes from Germany. And so, it's a lot of high-skilled people trading high-skilled goods, and we're trading on the basis of taste. Like, I like your vehicles, you like my aircraft.
Starting point is 00:09:31 It's not trying to see who can make the cheapest version of X, Y, or Z. We're often focusing on a set of expensive goods in which we all are differently good at different subsets. But when China opened up, that changed. A lot of what we're trading there is labor-intensive goods. Nothing that China was selling the United States, especially up until recently, couldn't be made in the U.S. It just couldn't be made as cheaply. So this was actually about price competition rather than simply having
Starting point is 00:09:58 a better or different variety. On the surface, that might seem fine. Again, it would mean Americans and many others getting to buy cheaper goods because they're made in China. But the surface, that might seem fine. Again, it would mean Americans and many others getting to buy cheaper goods because they're made in China. But of course, the calculus is trickier than that. So when the United States trades with the developing world, we're going to typically export skill-intensive products, you know, aircraft engines, electronics, movies and TV programs, and things that use a lot of highly educated labor. And we're going to tend to import low-skill or what we would call labor-intensive products like, you know, footwear and textiles, leather goods, things that require a lot of hand assembly.
Starting point is 00:10:37 And so, what does that do? Well, when we export those high-skill intensive goods, we're basically raising demand for skilled or educated workers in the United States. When we import those labor-intensive goods, we're going to reduce demand for blue-collar workers who are not doing skill-intensive production. Now, we benefit because we get lower prices on the goods we consume and we sell the things that we're good at making at a higher price to the world. So that raises GDP, but simultaneously, it tends to make high-skilled and highly educated labor better off, raise their wages, and it tends to make low-skill, manual intensive laborers worse off because there's less demand for their services. So there's going to be fewer of them employed or they're going to be employed at lower wages. So the net effect, you can show analytically, is going to be positive,
Starting point is 00:11:26 but the redistributional consequences are, many of us would view that as adverse because we would rather redistribute from rich to poor than poor to rich, and trade is kind of working in the redistributing from poor to rich direction in the United States. The scale of benefits and harms are rather incommensurate. So, you know, for individuals, you know, I have less expensive consumer items because of imports from China, but it hasn't affected my employment or my wages. For many others on the order of at least a million U.S. manufacturing workers, it meant the end of their jobs and in many cases, the end of
Starting point is 00:12:01 their industries. But that wasn't even the worst of it. Coming up on Freakonomics Radio, the true breadth of the problem and we talk about solutions. I don't think there are any easy solutions. I don't think if I were, you know, labor secretary, I would just be able to get in and, you know, turn this ship around. That's coming up right after the break. David Autor, a labor economist at MIT, has spent the past few years working with fellow economists to measure the effects of global trade, especially between the U.S. and China.
Starting point is 00:12:49 A lot of political rhetoric argues that China has damaged the U.S. economy via currency manipulation, making Chinese goods even more attractive to American consumers. It's the single greatest tool they have, currency manipulation, and they're grandmasters. They do a great job. I congratulate them. I'm not angry at China. I'm angry at our country for allowing them to do it. Autor's research reveals a story
Starting point is 00:13:17 that is in some ways more complicated than Donald Trump's explanation and in some ways simpler. What occurred is not primarily the result of currency manipulation or cheating or unfair trade deals. It was a function of China's extremely rapid development, which, by the way, is a very good thing, you know, brought 400 million Chinese out of poverty, raised incomes in Central and South America, caused investment throughout Africa, right? This is sort of the best thing to happen to the global middle class in at least a millennium, right? But it was tough on U.S. manufacturing.
Starting point is 00:13:49 Very tough, especially after 2001, when China was accepted into the World Trade Organization. China's entrance into the World Trade Organization has enabled the greatest job theft in the history of our country. We would conservatively estimate that more than a million manufacturing jobs in the U.S. were directly eliminated between 2000 and 2007 as a result of China's accelerating trade penetration in the United States. Now, that doesn't mean a million jobs total. Maybe some of those workers moved into other sectors. But we've looked at that, and as the trade shock that occurred in that period,
Starting point is 00:14:46 which is really following China's accession to the WTO in 2001. Are you controlling for the effects of technology here? Yes, to the best we can, to the best we can. We do have measures of sort of exposure to automation and so on. And as far as we can tell, that's not really the main driver. Now, I think it's reasonable to argue, well, you know, given 15 or 20 more years, it would have been. So the question then is, well, what happens? Where do those workers go? In a canonical economic model, they just costlessly reallocate to their next best opportunity.
Starting point is 00:15:26 Ah, the lovely language of economics once again, costlessly reallocate to their next best opportunity, meaning that some American who loses his manufacturing job just hops over to the next good job, which just happens to be available near where he's already living and for which he just happens to be perfectly qualified for, which is, you know, some other sector elsewhere in manufacturing, elsewhere in services. And kind of that plays out across the entire United States. So even though it's very concentrated locally, it diffuses over space. So it's small relative to the entire labor market. And so it shouldn't really have a big local effect. It shouldn't be very long lasting. So that's the economic theory. Is that what David Autor and his economist colleagues saw in reality? That's not what we see. We see those falls in
Starting point is 00:16:16 manufacturing employment correspond to about equally large falls in overall employment rates over the first 10 years in those trade-impacted locations. So every half a point that manufacturing falls, we see about a total decline of about a half a point. So some people are leaving the labor market, some people are going into unemployment, some people are going on to disability. And so the reallocation process seems to be slow, frictional, and scarring. Okay, so until scarring, those words sounded fairly clinical and academic, but what you're describing here is really bad, A, correct? And B, I'm just curious, before we move on, you looked at a whole lot of different manufacturing
Starting point is 00:17:01 ecosystems. I'm sure there's great variants, or I'm assuming there's great variants from one to the next. Can you talk about some ecosystems, some manufacturing industries or jobs where people did do a better job adapting? You know, actually, the real differentiator is the kind of skill level of the worker. So higher paid and more highly educated workers, they seem to reallocate successfully out of manufacturing into other jobs. So the shocks to manufacturing affect everyone in the immediately targeted industry. But the differentiator is not what industry you were in specifically, but how skilled you were initially. So the HR person at a big textile firm gets an HR job elsewhere and the manufacturers on the line are probably not.
Starting point is 00:17:47 And the line workers are much less likely to do so, exactly. Right. And what's important to emphasize, you know, if I say a shock to furniture, that's not just one plant, right? There are multiple plants in, you know, Tennessee that have 10,000 plus workers and they all kind of shut down within a few years of each other. And so, you can think of this as it's like, you know, a certain element of blight that sets in, right? You know, look, there are 3,000 counties in the United States. If 10,000 workers were eliminated, you know, three from each county, you wouldn't even notice it,
Starting point is 00:18:14 right? But if 10,000 workers are eliminated simultaneously from your, you know, local labor market, that's very noticeable. And it has kind of add-on effects because, gee, well, then those manufacturers also stop, you know, buying the delivery services and the catering services. People have less income, so they go out to dinner less. So, all kinds of kind of adverse multipliers, not huge, but noticeable and measurable, set in. Maybe this is not a multiplier. Maybe I'm defining it wrong. But what about with all those relatively low skilled workers out there floating around looking for jobs? Presumably that could lower the wage of other existing jobs or no?
Starting point is 00:18:55 Yes. Yeah. That's what we find, actually, that you see a kind of decline in the wage level, not just in manufacturing. You also see people going on using public transfer benefits like unemployment and trade adjustment, but actually much more numerically, quantitatively large are disability, Medicare, Medicaid, food stamps, TANF, early retirement. So those programs actually are numerically, you know, fiscally much, much larger. Look at all those downstream effects from China's manufacturing growth that David Autor identifies in the U.S. Job loss, wage depression, higher welfare spending. In another research paper, he and his colleagues found yet another downside. Many economists had suspected that greater competition with China would create incentives for American companies to invest more in research and
Starting point is 00:19:50 development and become more innovative. But it hasn't worked out that way. Instead, Autor and his colleagues found, Chinese competition has lowered profit margins for American manufacturers, leaving less money for R&D and resulting in less innovation. People like you, meaning economists, not like you, David Autor, necessarily, you know, have been telling us for several decades now that globalization would be largely win-win. I'm not so naive as to think that there are no losers. I get that. But the overall, we Americans should kind of sit back and relax, that it would be good for the median U.S. resident. So I don't feel that way anymore. And tell me if I'm wrong to not feel that way. And additionally, if I'm wrong, maybe to blame
Starting point is 00:20:39 you and your cohort a little bit. I think if we had realized how traumatic the pace of change would have been, we would have at a minimum had much better policies in place to assist workers and communities that suffered these very severe and immediate consequences. And we might have tried to moderate the pace at which it occurred. And let me add another factor that really augments
Starting point is 00:21:05 this is we also had a huge trade deficit. And that meant that we simply did a lot less manufacturing. So that meant that workers had to make a tougher transition out of manufacturing into something altogether new. And I think that upped the challenge. It made it harder for people to reallocate. If it was one thing, if they were going, you know, they're getting out of textiles and moving into automobiles or tools, but that's not what happened. They're getting out of textiles and moving into Walmart, you know, moving into fast food. I think the other thing that we have to recognize and that economists have tended not to emphasize is that jobs aren't purely income.
Starting point is 00:21:44 They are part of identity. They structure people's lives. They give them a purpose and a social community and a sense of relevance in the world. And I think that is a lot of the frustration that we see in manufacturing intensive areas. We saw a lot of that actually in the recent election. People feel like their place in the universe, or at least in the economy, has really been kind of reduced, made less valuable. And I think that that's costly even beyond the direct financial costs. So President Trump did not choose you, David Autor, as labor secretary, but he did choose someone else with a fast food background, Andrew Puzder, who's chief executive of the company behind Hardee's and Carl's Jr. Yeah. So if it had been you, and maybe someday it will be, what to do about it? You acknowledge
Starting point is 00:22:40 that you're not as sanguine as you were or thought you might have been. You acknowledge that the degree of pain and the pace of the change has been really severe. Tell us some things that are potential remedies or at least better thinking frameworks to approach the future of labor in this country. So it's a challenging question. I don't think there are any easy solutions. I don't think if I were, you know, labor secretary, I would just be able to get in and, you know, turn this ship around. But a couple things I would do. One thing is I would expand the earned income tax credit, which is a federal wage subsidy for people with low incomes. It's a really generous and effective program,
Starting point is 00:23:26 but is targeted at adults with dependent children, primarily women. So if you're a mother with two dependent children, you can get up to $6,000 a year in EITC support up to a household income of about $40,000. So it raises incomes and it also causes people to participate more in the labor market. It makes low paid work better paying effectively. But if you're a man without dependent children, you can get about $400 a year total from the EITC, not $6,000, $400 a year. And many of the men that are struggling for employment, in fact, many of them do have children. They just can't claim them as dependents. They're frequently not married to the mothers. So this is a group that is experiencing falling wages.
Starting point is 00:24:13 Labor force participation rates are declining among less educated men, even less educated young men. So one policy I would use is to provide your income tax credit basically makes it more rewarding, financially rewarding, more worthwhile to work. That's one thing. I do think there are tax changes that we ought to make that could be beneficial. One of them is actually being talked about in the Trump administration.
Starting point is 00:24:38 It's a so-called border adjustment, which is a way – it's a complicated story, but it's like a value-added tax. And if it were used to offset other taxes, like our payroll tax, for example, right now our payroll tax raises the cost of producing in the United States, but foreign countries, when they import here, they don't pay our payroll tax. If we had a value-added tax, that would be levied both on things produced domestically and on things that are imported. If it were used to offset the payroll tax, why, that would have the effect of basically making imports a little bit more expensive
Starting point is 00:25:13 relative to domestically produced goods. I don't think that's a terrible idea. Many countries do something that looks a bit like that. I think the other things are, importantly, are skills investments, and then I think also things that make the quality of life better for people with low incomes, including, I'm afraid to say it coming primarily from one direction, which is basically they're costly ways to support the people who have lost out because of this economic change. What about reversing that dynamic? So obviously this president, that's his gospel on the labor
Starting point is 00:26:00 front to date, which is reshoring, or I don't know what you call it in the case of Carrier, where you don't let him get away in the first place. What's your view on that? to come back. Even if the production returns to the United States, it would be done with a lot more machinery and robotics. I think manufacturing will continue to occur in the United States. I just don't think it's going to use that much labor. I think it's perfectly reasonable to aggressively enforce our trade deals. There are certainly countries that dump products, that steal intellectual property, that create anti-competitive barriers in their own country so the U.S. can't export to them even though it's importing from them. But I don't think we can turn back the clock. And moreover, remember that many of those imports, for one, they do make consumer prices lower.
Starting point is 00:26:57 And two, they're often inputs into things that we're making and then exporting or consuming domestically, right? So as soon as you start taxing Chinese goods, you're taxing car parts that end up in GM and Ford and Fiat Chrysler automobiles. So, you'll quickly find that there's a lot of opposition from U.S. manufacturers to restrictions on trade or tariffs. You might think, oh, no, we're doing you a favor. We're, making your products more competitive. Well, not if you're importing a lot of your components. It strikes me that his views are kind of aligned quite closely with the views of economists like you who do see evidence that supports some of the at least his proclamations about the cost of globalization. Where do you find yourself on that spectrum, whether politically per se or just philosophically? Well, I want to be clear. President Trump makes a lot of unfounded claims about trade that I do not agree with. For example, that NAFTA was a disaster for the United States. Very, very little evidence to suggest that was true. It was actually mostly a win for the United States, but pretty
Starting point is 00:28:21 modest. I also, you know, strongly disagree with the idea that we ought to be slapping extremely high tariffs on importers. I think that would be quite damaging to the U.S. Similarly, I don't favor strong-arming companies to keep employment here if it's going to deter others from creating jobs here out of fear that they'll then be forced to retain them. So, I don't even think trade has been a net bad to the United States. I just think it's created real concentrated adverse impacts, which I, you know, Trump was right to recognize.
Starting point is 00:28:54 And that's where I'm more in sympathy with the administration than on other points. I'll finally say that a good example of where bad thinking and bad trade policy has come in immediately is in this whole debate around the Trans-Pacific Partnership, which was basically a forward-looking trade agreement that was set up as a bulwark against Chinese domination of Asia. You know, Trump said on the campaign trail, China will take advantage of us through the TPP like
Starting point is 00:29:20 they always do. The TPP is a horrible deal. It is a deal that is going to lead to nothing but trouble. It's a deal that was designed for China to come in, as they always do, through the back door and totally take advantage of everyone. I don't think he even realized at the point that China was not a signatory to the TPP, and China was the country cheering loudest to see it crash and burn because it was basically establishing rules of the game among with Asia and North America, the United States that would uphold intellectual property agreements, freedom and transparency of contracting market access and so on. So if we don't set the rules of the game in Asia, China will. And I don't think we'll like those rules nearly as much. So that's just this kind of bluster against trade that is ignorant
Starting point is 00:30:08 and harmful to the U.S. interests and really harmful to our allies, including most especially Japan. So, David, I know you've said that economics wasn't entirely wrong on this prediction that global trade would kind of work out okay. But I do think a lot of people would disagree. Obviously, it's a matter of degrees. So if that's my view, and I think that, you know, many or most economists were wrong and something as basic and important as this, why should we ever listen to what you wonderfully educated egghead economists have to say when it comes to something as important and broad as macroeconomic issues that will affect my actual life. You can predict all you want about currency stories abroad, etc. But if it's my life, my livelihood,
Starting point is 00:31:01 my job, my family, my ability to provide for them. You guys are supposed to be the nonpartisan, smart, apolitical cohort out there. And I trusted you. And now I'm sorry I did. Because if I hadn't, I might have changed course 15 or 20 years ago. And while I might not be in great shape, I'd certainly be in better shape than I am now. Well, I don't know that you'd be in better shape. You'd be in different shape and a different group of people would be benefiting. I don't think we'd be wealthier, but I think it's a really good question. I mean, I think economists have learned a lot from the data and it's actually
Starting point is 00:31:38 credit to the profession that we're not just asserting, we're testing. And when the facts change, we change our opinions. And the evidence that economists were relying on, you know, up through the 2000s wasn't incorrect for its time. It just turned out not to be fully predictive of what happened next. And that's, you know, that's sort of cold comfort, I know, the most important thing to do in a recession is stop spending so the country, you know, saves. You know, there's tons and tons of bad economic reasoning out there. Contemporary economics is quite imperfect, but I think it's at least guided by evidence and economists are fully capable of changing their views based on evidence.
Starting point is 00:32:45 I do not think the profession actually is nearly as ideological as it was 25 years ago when it was guided so much by theory. Now it's really guided by data. And, you know, case in point, the work that we've done, you know, it's been somewhat controversial, but by and large, economists have really embraced and said, oh, yeah, wow, you know, we're surprised and this changes how we think about it. And again, I don't want to claim that we were, you know, some upstarts. We just happened to look at the right data and come away with conclusions that none of us were expecting.
Starting point is 00:33:11 But I think that's, you know, that's about as good as social science does. We're not working with natural laws that can be as neatly summarized as Newtonian physics. I have no idea if you'll agree, but David Autor strikes me as a particularly keen and fair-minded analyst and observer of the U.S. labor markets. It doesn't seem as if he's got a horse in the race, doesn't seem as if he's got his thumb on the scale, and his insights seem useful, at least as useful as a diagnosis can be once you're already sick. There's just one caveat I'd add to his message. It has to do with the predictions
Starting point is 00:33:52 that economists made about how Chinese manufacturing would affect the American labor market. The evidence that economists were relying on up through the 2000s wasn't incorrect for its time. It just turned out not to be fully predictive of what happened next. This program has gone on and on about the folly of prediction. In fact, there's a Freakonomics Radio episode from years ago called The Folly of Prediction. We talked about how one of the most common explanations of smart people when their predictions turn out to be inaccurate was that, well, we did the best we could considering the information we had at the time. If we had better information, we could have made a better prediction.
Starting point is 00:34:35 But you know what? If you had better information at the time, you wouldn't have to make a prediction. The future would have been obvious. But that's the thing about the future. It's rarely obvious, which leaves a lot of room for all kinds of people to make all kinds of predictions that may or may not come true. I'm not calling out David Autor here. Again, I really appreciate his transparency and his doggedness. But the story of Chinese manufacturing and American labor is yet another reminder of how humble we should all be when we make a prediction and how cautious we should all be when we hear one. Think about this. If the vast,
Starting point is 00:35:12 vast majority of political pundits and TV journalists and even the most revered analytics geeks got the 2016 presidential election so wrong, and that's a simple binary choice, the blue team versus the red team, then how much harder is it to predict the downstream consequences of something as vast and broad as a global labor upheaval? I don't mean to get all preachy on you. That is not the Freakonomics way.
Starting point is 00:35:43 But I will say this. Beware the punditry, no matter how well-degreed they are or well-spoken or well-coiffed. Don't assume they can know the future any better than you do. And don't assume you're such a genius either. Coming up next time on Freakonomics Radio, it's an egghead's guide to watching the Super Bowl. We'll tell you how you can optimize the experience, whether you are a football addict or a total newbie. We talk to some of the smartest NFL players, past and present, two-time Super Bowl champion Justin Tuck, Eric Winston, and Baltimore Ravens lineman John Urschel, who is getting his PhD in math at MIT.
Starting point is 00:36:32 So if you look at a wide receiver, what is that wide receiver doing on pass plays where the main route combination is not to his side? What is he doing when it's a run play? Is he running them off? Is he just jogging? Is he talking to the cornerback? We also talked to our resident Freakonomics egghead, Steve Levitt. The other thing that's really special about the Super Bowl, and if you are not a fan but are forced to attend a Super Bowl party, I would highly recommend gambling. And there's one thing
Starting point is 00:37:02 all our eggheads agree is the best part of Super Sunday. You will enjoy the commercials, I can assure you. I'll tell them to pay attention to the commercials. The commercials are really funny. I give special attention to the ads. That's next time on Freakonomics Radio. Freakonomics Radio is produced by WNYC Studios and Dubner Productions. This episode was produced by Greg Rosalski. Our staff also includes Shelley Lewis, Christopher Wirth, Stephanie Tam, Merritt Jacob, Eliza Lambert, Alison Hockenberry, Emma Morgenstern, Harry Huggins, and Brian Gutierrez. We also had help this week from Andrew Dunn.
Starting point is 00:37:41 You can and should subscribe to Freakonomics Radio on iTunes, Stitcher, wherever you get your podcasts. You should also check out our archive at Freakonomics.com, which has every past episode, including transcripts. You can find us on Twitter and Facebook and write to us at radio at Freakonomics.com. Thanks for listening. Thank you.

There aren't comments yet for this episode. Click on any sentence in the transcript to leave a comment.