Freakonomics Radio - 303. Why Larry Summers Is the Economist Everyone Hates to Love
Episode Date: September 28, 2017He's been U.S. Treasury Secretary, a chief economist for the Obama White House and the World Bank, and president of Harvard. He's one of the most brilliant economists of his generation (and perhaps th...e most irascible). And he thinks the Trump Administration is wrong on just about everything.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
We'll start today with a quiz. First, name a former president of Harvard.
Okay, now name a secretary of the Treasury under President Clinton.
Now name a chief economist in the Obama White House.
Now name a one-time chief economist for the World Bank.
Now name a White House economic advisor under President
Reagan. And now name one of the most outspoken policy critics of President Trump. How'd you do?
What's that? Too easy? All right, let's make it a little harder. Name a former Harvard president,
Clinton Treasury Secretary, Obama chief economist, World Bank chief economist,
Reagan advisor and Trump critic who are all the same person.
Hello.
Hey, it's Stephen Dubner. Is that Larry Summers?
Hi, Stephen. How are you?
Larry Summers, or Lawrence H. Summers, that's how he signed your money when he ran Treasury,
is considered one of the most brilliant, opinionated, and influential
economists of his generation. Summers' reputation is that he's so smart that if you have a huge
position open, you would be an idiot to not consider him, but that he's so irascible,
so radically candid, such a non-sufferer of fools, you may live to regret it. As Harvard learned when Summers, after five years as its president,
quit before he could be fired.
But he's back at Harvard now as a professor.
How does he spend his days?
You know, I teach classes.
I advise students on research on their future.
I write a blog on various aspects of public policy.
I write economics research papers on topics ranging from global health
to the future of the banking system and the prospects of financial stability. I speak with government officials around the world.
I advise a number of companies. And he's been publishing in the Washington Post and the
Financial Times some of the most incendiary anti-Trump rhetoric around. But here's the thing.
He's also been carrying on a multi-year campaign about the dangers of what economists call secular stagnation, a long-term period of slow growth. Summers calls it the defining macroeconomic challenge of our times. where he's a board member or fellow or advisor. The Center for American Progress, for instance, which is essentially an offshoot of the Clinton wing of the Democratic Party,
but also the much less doctrinaire Peterson Institute for International Economics,
where he dispenses macroeconomic insights that are considered without peer.
Today on Freakonomics Radio,
Summers tells us what the White House felt like during the first days of
the Great Recession. It was a very tense time, and there were many who thought we might be seeing a
precursor to the Depression. He talks about his policy successes and failures. Perhaps,
given what happened, you can say it was a mistake. He lists his current economic priorities. I think we've completely mismanaged
infrastructure investment in the United States.
He talks about policy decisions
he would have made differently.
Only an idiot would put a sign on the library door
saying no amnesty now, thinking about one next month.
And why he's not a big fan of the current White House. It's the disregard
for ascertainable fact and disregard for that explores the hidden side of everything.
Here's your host, Stephen Dubner. Let's say the year is 1954 and you are running some kind of experimental breeding lab for
supernaturally talented economists. The most prized product of your lab surely would have been
young Lawrence Summers. You come from a most distinguished economics lineage. Your father and mother were both
economists, as were two uncles who each won a Nobel Prize, Paul Samuelson and Kenneth Arrow.
When you grow up with economics in your blood and in the air, how does that inform your worldview?
I suppose I learned about supply and demand a little earlier than the average child did.
And certainly one of the first lessons I learned as a child was that the most important things in life had nothing to do with money.
And so I was always someone who took the statement that an economist is someone who knows the price of everything and the value of nothing, not as a definition
or description, but as a cautionary warning.
So you've served many roles in government and institutions, but you've also spent a
lot of your career in academia.
Talk briefly, first of all, just about the central difference between academia and government,
especially when it comes to the relationship between empirical evidence
and policy decisions? Well, you know, I always joked that when I moved from Harvard to work in
the U.S. Treasury, that the worst thing you could do as a Harvard professor was to sign your name
to something you had not written yourself. On the other hand, as an undersecretary of the Treasury,
it was a mark of effectiveness to do so as frequently as possible.
It's an interesting joke for Summers to tell.
In 1991, as chief economist at the World Bank,
he did sign off on an internal memo that he reportedly didn't write.
It was about pollution in poor countries.
Just between you and me, the memo read,
shouldn't the World Bank be encouraging more migration
of the dirty industries to the LDCs or less developed countries?
I think the economic logic behind dumping a load of toxic waste
in the lowest wage countries is impeccable.
Underpopulated countries in Africa are vastly underpolluted.
The memo was leaked, after which Brazil's Secretary of the Environment wrote this to
Summers. Your reasoning is perfectly logical, but totally insane. And he called it a concrete
example of the unbelievable alienation, reductionist thinking, social ruthlessness, and the arrogant
ignorance of many conventional economists concerning the nature of the world we live in.
Here's how Summers ultimately responded to the so-called toxic memo. He said,
I think the best that can be said is to quote LaGuardia and say, when I make a mistake,
it's a whopper. So that's one difference between academia and politics.
And of course, there was another difference, which is that as a scholar,
if you work on a problem and you work on a problem and it's just too hard and you can't
find a good solution, what you do is you move on to a different problem.
And as a policymaker, you don't have that luxury.
One huge difference between the needs of scholarship and the needs of policymaking is that in scholarship,
if you point up an important aspect of a problem that nobody's really thought much about before,
and you show that it's important and you explore it in its various aspects,
you've made a very valuable contribution. And so it's the essence of scholarship to abstract
from many things in order to highlight a particular point.
It's the essence of policymaking to be able to see all the aspects of a given situation.
And if you've neglected any important aspect, you're probably not doing your job very well because that can lead you to make a wrong decision.
In 1993, Summers won the John Bates Clark Medal given to the best American economist under 40.
He was still young, but he was also an old hand.
Harvard had awarded him a professorship back in 1983
when he was just 28.
He'd taken a leave to work at the World Bank,
then back to Harvard, but then it was back to D.C.
as Undersecretary of the Treasury for International Affairs.
He was at Treasury for six years before Bill Clinton named him secretary toward the end of Clinton's final term.
By the way, Summers' chief of staff at the time?
Sheryl Sandberg, now of Facebook and Lean In fame.
Summers' time as head of Treasury was marked by a push for
modernizing the financial and regulatory systems. Let me welcome you all here today
for the signing of this historic legislation. With this bill, the American financial system
takes a major step forward towards the 21st century. Along with the new Republican administration
under George W. Bush came a new
Treasury Secretary, Paul O'Neill. But within seven months, Larry Summers went from being the 71st
Secretary of the Treasury to the 27th President of Harvard. Tell me about this world's richest
university that you're taking the helm of. Harvard's a very special institution. And the challenge for the next decade
is to maintain Harvard's excellence.
His agenda for Harvard was ambitious.
A physical expansion of the campus,
a greater emphasis on science, more financial aid,
and making sure students, especially undergraduates,
had good access to faculty.
He made some progress, but along the way,
he also made enemies. Maybe it was his background in academic economics, where intellectual
firepower counts for a lot more than manners. In any case, Summers infuriated some people,
alienated even more. What turned out to be the final straw was a talk Summers gave at a small
economics conference in Cambridge.
The theme was diversifying the workforce in science and engineering. Summers made it clear
that he was speaking, quote, unofficially and not using this as an occasion to lay out the many
things we're doing at Harvard to promote the crucial objective of diversity. In other words,
he'd be speaking as an economist, not a bureaucrat. The question he
sought to address, why are women so underrepresented in tenured positions in science and engineering
at top universities and research institutions? He made clear this was hardly a unique case.
To take a set of diverse examples, his lecture read, the data will, I am confident, reveal that Catholics are substantially underrepresented in investment banking, which is an enormously high-paying profession in our society.
That white men are very substantially underrepresented in the National Basketball Association, and that Jews are very substantially underrepresented in farming and in agriculture.
When it came to the underrepresentation of women in science, Summers identified several possible factors.
Discrimination, gender differences in preferences and in socialization from an early age,
but also, as he put it, quote, there are issues of intrinsic aptitude. He went on to say,
quote, I would like nothing better than to be proved wrong because I would like nothing better
than for these problems to be addressable simply by everybody understanding what they are and
working very hard to address them. But once Summers' remarks became public, no amount of
nuance or wishful thinking could save him.
His goodwill account had run dangerously low,
and with the writing on the wall, he resigned.
As you can imagine, Summers is not fond of talking about the end of his Harvard reign.
I did want to ask him, however,
about some interesting new research concerning women in science.
No idea if you've seen it or know anything about it.
It's by David Card and Abigail Payne.
And it argues that for STEM students in college, it's not so much a case that women are underrepresented as that men are overrepresented, the reason being that many more women enroll in college now generally than men,
and that men are typically much worse than women in non-STEM fields.
So basically, the men who are good enough to go to college tend to be more appropriately suited to STEM.
I don't know if you know anything about this paper, but I'm really curious to know your thoughts on it,
since it obviously picks up on a topic that led to your demise as
president at Harvard. Well, I'm going to stay away from that aspect of my time at Harvard,
Stephen, and I'm afraid I haven't seen the card and pain paper. It is, I believe, a fact that
if you look at men who have extremely high test scores in mathematics and women who have
extremely high test scores in mathematics, that if you look at the test scores outside of mathematics,
the women will, on average, have higher scores. And that may have something to do with the respective choices precisely because the women have the greater intellectual strength in the verbal areas.
But I'm not going to say any more about this because, as I say, I have not had a chance to read the Cardin-Payne paper.
Summers' comments at that conference would continue to dog him.
When Barack Obama was elected in 2008 and installed Summers as head of the National Economic Council, there was a lot of pushback.
This is a man who only listens to what he wants to hear, said a female MIT scientist.
Does Obama care that someone says 50% of the population is genetically inferior to the other 50%?
During his first White House Correspondents Association dinner,
Obama tried to joke about Summers' reputation.
Not very successfully.
We've also begun to change the culture in Washington.
We've even made the White House a place where people can learn and can grow.
Just recently, Larry Summers asked if he could chair the White House Council on Women and Girls.
Coming up on Freakonomics Radio, Summers on the Great Recession, Summers on Trump, and Summers on Summers.
You think you'll serve in government again, Larry?
You never know what's going to happen.
That's coming up right after this. Here are a few headlines of the articles and blog posts Larry Summers has written lately.
Trump's CEOs resigned. His staff should do the same.
What history can tell us about Trump's budget fantasy.
Western civilization and presidential hypocrisy.
In his denunciations of Trump, he has begun to out Krugman, Paul Krugman,
as the economist most likely to start a bonfire.
But there's a difference.
No matter how indignant Summers gets, his analysis isn't received as mere ranting.
His bona fides in government seem to have earned him the right.
Now, why had Barack Obama been willing to install someone
with Summers' baggage
as head of the National Economic Council?
Because if you are a new, young president
who's just inherited the scariest recession
in generations,
you want experience
and you want brilliance. And that is what Larry
Summers had come to represent. And as one of the great economic minds of our time, Larry has earned
a global reputation for being able to cut to the heart of the most complex and novel policy
challenges. With respect to both our current financial crisis and other pressing economic
issues of our time, his thinking,
writing, and speaking have set the terms of the debate. I'm glad he will be by my side,
playing the critical role of coordinating my administration's economic policy in the White
House, and I will rely heavily on his advice as we navigate the uncharted waters of this economic crisis.
What was it like to be on the inside of the Obama administration during the financial meltdown,
especially those early weeks where really the future of the economy was in question?
It was a very tense time. We would meet with the president each morning and talk about what was happening
and what had happened in the markets the previous day, what we were hearing about,
the health of different financial institutions. But the president was very clear. He said, you know,
this is why I was elected to do the right thing, whatever the right thing is. And so don't tell me
about the political problems. Tell me what the right thing to do is. And that's what Tim Geithner and I tried to do. And while battlefield medicine's never perfect,
and the things you could look back on and ask questions about, I think you'd have to say that
the fact that we had such a dramatic turn in the economy, really in May, June of the president's
first year, means that at least on some of the big
broad picture aspects, that the approach we chose was effective. And certainly it wasn't a priori
clear that it would be as effective as it was. And there were many who thought we might be seeing a
precursor to the depression. So you were co-chair of the president's auto task force. One of the
biggest and most difficult decisions was whether to bail out GM and Chrysler. You argued in favor
of a bailout and you won the argument, though not without a fight. The other side represented by
Austin Goolsbee and others. Give us briefly your perspective on this chapter. And even though
you won the argument and even though from what I can tell, your argument turned out to be correct.
In retrospect, I'm wondering if there's anything you might have done differently. emergency lending, that on the one hand, the cost of keeping Chrysler alive was about the
same as the cost of providing for unemployment benefits for all the workers and pension benefits
for all those who the pension insurance company would be on the hook for if Chrysler went
belly up. So at one level,
you could say there really wasn't a net cost to keeping Chrysler going. The problem, of course,
was that if you didn't succeed in keeping Chrysler going, you'd pay twice, once for your failed
attempt to keep Chrysler going. And then again, when it failed, you'd end up not
having avoided the costs of failure. So one had to make a judgment, given the dynamics at that time,
about the prospects that, with support, Chrysler would be able to turn things around.
And you had to be able to make a judgment about how widespread the consequences would be
for the rest of the economy if Chrysler were to go down. And the judgment that I believed
was that there were no certainties, but I thought there was a substantial chance that given this support, Chrysler would be able to make it forward and GM would be able to make it forward and that you would avoid dealing with something traumatic at a moment when the economy was least in a position to deal with something traumatic. And I think that judgment has been borne out by subsequent events.
Could there have been slightly different conditions?
Could there have been a slightly different allocation between bondholders and workers
of the costs?
Could the shares that the government took have been put back on the market with
different timing? These are all questions where reasonable people can argue with the benefit of
hindsight, where there would be people who would have made different judgments than the ones we did
at the time we made our judgments. But I think the broad strategic judgment has been overwhelmingly borne out
by what's happened. Now, there are some people who would argue that the financial crisis itself
was a product in some part based on decisions that you and others had made in a previous
Democratic administration, the Clinton administration, specifically as part of the
Financial Services Modernization Act, the repeal of Glass-Steagall, which freed up banks to be more aggressive, and also that you argued quite heavily
against the regulation of derivatives, the financial instruments, which of course turned
out to be quite dangerous. So looking back at those as potential consequences for the meltdown,
again, same question, what do you think you might have done differently knowing now,
if you knew then what you knew now? Look, Stephen, with the benefit of hindsight,
and with, if you wave away all the political problems that would have existed at that time,
it surely would have been much better to have put in place all the kinds of safeguards that were contained
in the Dodd-Frank legislation that was passed in 2010, and to have anticipated all of those needs
and to have put them in place during the 1990s. I think that in assessing the actions that were taken in the 1990s, there are a number of things that are useful to keep in mind.
With respect to Glass-Steagall, there's nothing in the crisis that had to do with the combination of commercial banking and investment banking, which is what Glass-Steagall was all about. If you think about the main
institutions that were involved, Lehman Brothers had nothing to do with commercial banking. Bear
Stearns had nothing to do with commercial banking. Fannie and Freddie had nothing to do with either.
AIG was an insurance company, and I could go on with the list. And in fact, some of the key measures that resolved the crisis,
such as J.P. Morgan's taking over of Bear Stearns
or Bank of America's taking over of Merrill Lynch,
involved the combination of commercial banking and investment banking.
So I don't find it plausible that Glass-Steagall reform
had anything to do with causing the crisis.
And I think it's a mistake that economists should be able to move beyond to simply phrase
these questions as all regulation is good and all deregulation is bad.
I think the question of derivatives is a much more complicated story. Our desire was not
to keep derivatives deregulated. We ran into a problem, which was that statements that had been made by the CFTC called into question whether the
enforcement of all the huge trillions of dollars of derivatives contracts out there would be
possible.
And because of the way they'd made those statements, they seemed to be questioning the enforceability
of those contracts. of the way they'd made those statements, they seemed to be questioning the enforceability of
those contracts. And under those circumstances, there was huge pressure from Congress to provide
legal certainty. And it was a Republican, very much a free market Congress. And they insisted as part of providing legal certainty that there be some removal of certain regulatory issues with respect to derivatives.
Should we have gone along with that?
Perhaps, given what happened, you can say it was a mistake.
And certainly I worry that it may have been a mistake.
On the other hand, there were issues that seemed pressing to the experienced attorneys at the SEC,
the Treasury, and the Fed about legal certainty to which we were responding. And it's certainly true
that if we had preserved authority, I don't think very much would have happened.
Because while we did sign legislation that reduced regulatory authority, the Bush administration, which was the administration in power from 2000 until the crisis hit, it used only a small fraction of the regulatory authorities that it had.
And it, in fact, ran major photo ops where they showed all the regulatory officials
taking the kind of saws you use to cut wood to books of regulations. And so it's hard to believe that whatever authority had been preserved would
have been used by the officials who were staging book burnings of regulatory books. So I'm not
completely objective on it. And again, I would wish more than anything that we had had the foresight and
the political strength to put in place irrevocably the kind of protections that were put in place in
2010 with Dodd-Frank. But I think that the narrative is at least much, much more complicated than that of many who simply say, well, they were for deregulation and then we had a crisis, so it must have been a mistake.
No matter how complicated it was, whether Summers made mistakes or not, the fact is that he accumulated plenty of critics, even on the Democratic side.
In 2013, when the White House floated the idea of Summers as a possible replacement
for Ben Bernanke, the outgoing Federal Reserve chairman, a chorus rose against him.
Three Democrats on the Senate Banking Committee recently said they would not support Summers.
The prospect of his appointment had unified Washington against both sides,
both parties. People want a new page. Seems like the president was the only person in Larry
Summers' corner. I just didn't hear anybody in Washington or across the country come out in
support of him. The left flank of the Democratic Party had grown particularly frustrated with
Summers. He had become the face of a discredited brand of economic centrism that was considered too friendly to the big banks.
He did have his defenders, like former President Bill Clinton.
Well, he's a friend of mine, and I think that a lot of the criticism to which he's been subject
about what he did in my administration is not accurate. I think there's this kind of cartoon image
that's been developed
that somehow Larry Summers was a one-note Johnny
just trying to let big financial titans ravage the land,
and it's just ludicrous.
But it was clear which way the wind was blowing.
Summers wrote a letter to President Obama, withdrawing his name from consideration for
the Fed chair post.
Larry Summers may no longer be the political player he used to be, at least for now, but
in the age of Trump, he's more vocal than ever.
Give me a thumbnail assessment, if you can, of the two men who are serving in two roles that
you've served under different administrations. Gary Cohn, director of the NEC, National Economic
Council. Steve Mnuchin, Treasury Secretary. I think one of the crucial functions of the Treasury Department is to be a bulwark of financial integrity for the federal government.
And I've been disturbed by the number of things that Secretary Mnuchin has said that were not actually true. His claim that the Trump tax cuts would not provide any relief
to those with the highest incomes. Hisottesville. A variety of his statements
about the plausibility that the president's policies would stimulate economic growth
seem to me to have put his credibility in considerable doubt. And that's not a personal thing. We don't know when
there's going to be some kind of crisis or serious economic problem. And it will be necessary for the
Treasury Secretary to provide reassurance. And at the moment when it is necessary for him to provide
reassurance, his credibility is going to be a crucial asset. And if he has said that
Donald Trump didn't provide any aid and comfort to racism, if he has said that the tax cuts are
not for rich people, then his credibility will be less there when the moment comes when it is asked. In the same way, I have been surprised by the number of statements that Gary Cohn has made
that just are matters of fact and aren't right.
He asserted that Dodd-Frank had cost banks a few hundred billion dollars a year in compliance costs.
Well, Dodd-Frank, I happen to support Dodd-Frank regulations, but reasonable people can agree or
disagree as to whether they're a good idea. But given that the total payroll of all the banks in
the country is $400 billion, it seems unlikely that complying with Dodd-Frank
is costing a few hundred billion dollars in compliance costs. Gary Cohn asserted that he
was working on doing the first tax cuts in 31 years. Well, we had tax cuts in 1997, tax cuts in 1999, tax cuts in 2001, 2003, and a variety of other years.
There are a variety of misstatements that are made.
Now, you can say that everybody exaggerates in service of an argument, and you can say
that it's all politics and that it's not a seminar room. On the other hand, I think in the
economic and financial arena, it's very important for public officials to maintain their credibility.
And I would add that on the evidence so far, and of course, things may change. The president talked about a variety of things
in the economic area. He talked about what he regarded as the economic benefits of repealing
Obamacare. That didn't happen. He talked about the benefits of infrastructure investment.
Nine months in, there's not even a plan from the administration for infrastructure investment.
He talked about how he would bring about dramatic changes in our trade relations, but he didn't do what he said he was going to do with respect to China or with respect to NAFTA. So if you judge either by has the administration been successful in bringing into place the policies it campaigned on?
Or if you ask the question, has the administration been successful in bringing into place significant policies that have the prospect of spurring economic growth,
one would have to say the answer to both those questions so far is no.
Now, just pretend for a minute that you were on their team, that you're on the Republican team.
Presumably, you could make an argument that it's early days. Indeed, there is a tax reform plan
under discussion, at least, and that these things take time, right?
Well, if you look at some past presidencies, I didn't support them.
But President Reagan's signature policy, his tax cuts were passed in July or August of 1981. President Clinton's signature economic initiative,
the Budget Deficit Reduction Act of 1993, was passed in July of 1993. President Obama's
signature economic policy, the Economic Recovery Act from the recession, was passed in February
of 2009. And the economy had had its biggest turn from a negative quarter into a positive quarter
in the post Second World War period, between the second and third quarter of 2009. And I could go on with
examples like the legislation that LBJ achieved in the summer of the year after his re-election
in 1965 or in the summer after he took office in 1964 with the Civil Rights Act,
I think the experience is actually very compelling that large deeds by presidents in the economic area
tend to have been legislated by this phase in the presidency or at least tend to be very much in prospect. So I don't think it's unfair to apply
the standards that history has applied in judging other presidents. And, you know, I left out what's
obviously the most important example, which is FDR's 100 days, where we're now past 200 days.
Let's say a Democrat like Hillary Clinton had won,
and let's say Hillary Clinton brought Larry Summers back to D.C.
in some, you know, to-be-determined policy position.
If you're making your to-do list right now, 2017,
for the American economy and America as part of the global economy,
what are your top three items?
What do you most want to accomplish?
I think we've completely mismanaged infrastructure investment in the United States.
We have a way inadequate level of spending.
It's nuts that when interest rates are lower
than they've been any time in 50 years,
that we're also investing less net of depreciation
than at almost any time in the last 50 years.
It's nuts that we have a regulatory apparatus that means that it took far longer to repair a single exit of the Oakland Bay Bridge
than it did to build the entire Oakland Bay Bridge two generations ago.
There's a small bridge across the Charles River that I'm looking at outside my office.
It's about 300 feet long.
It was under repair with a lane of traffic closed for five years.
Julius Caesar built a bridge over a span of the Rhine that was nine times as long in nine days.
So both on the quantity of expenditure and on the efficiency of the expenditure and the streamlining of the effort, there's plenty of room for improvement. And that's not a partisan thing.
Democrats tend to be bigger on more spending.
Republicans tend to be bigger on the streamlining.
All right.
Infrastructure, number one.
Yep.
Second, I think the president's right on the principle, even if he's wrong on the specifics with respect to tax reform.
Look, we have two and a half trillion dollars sitting
abroad. Indulge me, if you will, Stephen, in an analogy. Suppose you ran a library,
and suppose you had a lot of overdue books from your library. You might decide to give a library
amnesty so people would bring the books home. You might decide to say that there would never be an amnesty
and people better bring the books back
because otherwise the fines are just going to mount.
But only an idiot would put a sign on the library door
saying no amnesty now, thinking about one next month.
And yet, what have we done as a country?
We've said to all the businesses with that $2.5 trillion abroad that if you bring it home right now, you'll have to pay 35% tax.
But we're talking about and thinking about and planning and maybe we'll have some kind of tax reform where that will go down. Getting to resolution one way or another on the corporate tax regime, I think,
is a very important issue. I'd like to see us tax global income more heavily than we do now,
even if it's not repatriated and brought back into the United States. And then I'd like to see some
more favorable rate if it is brought back into the United States so that we greatly narrow the gap that provides an incentive to keep capital outside the country right now.
And do you get rid of carried interest loophole or you keep it? I think that we have a variety of tax breaks for financial engineering, like
carried interest, like various breaks that let you engage in complicated loan transactions with
the wealthy, engage in complicated loan transactions with their children that facilitate the avoidance of tax. I think all of these things, if they were repaired,
would help us have a more dynamic and a more efficient economy.
And I think the third thing is adapting to the knowledge economy.
The truth is that value used to reside heavily in how heavy a thing was, and now it resides heavily in how knowledgeable it is.
And that means a whole set of things, starting with strengthening an education system. You know, in many ways, one of the triumphs in this country is that we have,
over the last generation, largely conquered price inflation, and inflation rates have been very low.
But we certainly haven't conquered grade inflation. And when the most common grade at our
leading universities is A, I don't think it can be very surprising when there's various kinds of misrepresentation and various kinds of exaggeration of shrink. And one of those reasons that I
found really interesting, you talked about how changes in structural pricing that disproportionately
affect government are huge. And you talk about the Consumer Price Index from 1983 versus today,
and the things that have gotten relatively cheaper, and the things that have gotten
relatively much more expensive. Can you talk about that for a moment? And I assume where that leads to is a conversation about what you economists call cost disease, yes?
Yeah.
Just as a point of fact, we use the so-called consumer price index
to measure what happens to the price of different goods.
And it's an index, so it's set at a certain level in a certain year. And the
Consumer Price Index for all products are set, just as a convention, to be 100 in 1983. Well,
if you look at the Consumer Price Index for television sets, it's now about six. If you look at the consumer price index for a day in a hospital room or a year in a
college, it's about 600. In other words, since 1983, the relative price of this measure of education
and health care, as opposed to this canonical product, the TV set, has changed by a factor of 100.
Well, that's got a number of consequences.
One is since government is much more involved in buying education and health care
than it is in buying TVs, there's going to be upwards pressure on the size of government
relative to the rest of the economy.
Another is that because there's been far greater productivity growth in the
production of television sets than in the production of government goods, a larger fraction
of the workforce is going to find itself working in the areas where there's less productivity growth,
like education and health care. And this is the phenomenon that was first noticed by the
late Princeton economist, William Baumel, that sometimes referred to Baumel's disease or
cause disease. And it refers to the fact that if workers become much more productive doing some things and their wage has to be the same in all
sectors, then there's going to be a tendency for the price of the areas in which labor is not
becoming productive to rise. And that's why it costs more to go to the theater relative to other
things than it did when I was a child. That's why tuition in colleges has risen.
That's why the cost of mental health counseling has risen.
All kinds of activities where it takes inherently a person one hour to provide a given kind of service
and where productivity growth is sort of defeating the point.
I mean, productivity growth in education,
after all, is a higher ratio of students to teachers, which is exactly the opposite of what
we all want for our kids, that those kinds of structural changes are going to define our economy.
You are known to admire and respect raw intelligence or perhaps even better cultivated
intelligence. How smart
do you think Donald Trump is? Oh, I'm not going to be in the position of evaluating that. I don't
think that raw intelligence in the IQ sense is a terribly important attribute in being president or in leadership. I think concern with understanding
the issues with which one's grappling and honesty and integrity about facts are much more important
values. And I've therefore been very troubled by the president's fairly constant statements of historical events that distort them substantially,
statements of matters of objective fact, like the size of crowds at his inaugural, that are inaccurate statements of intention, like the extent to which his tax
cuts will favor wealthy people that are inconsistent with the reality of those tax cuts.
So I think it's not issues of intelligence that have troubled me about the president and some of his officials.
It's disregard for ascertainable fact and disregard for analysis of the consequences of possible policy actions. And so when the president proposed a budget that included obvious double counting of what
were probably to start with vastly exaggerated claims for the revenue benefits that would
come from extra economic growth caused by tax cuts, but then to double count it because
of an elementary logical error. You don't necessarily expect a president to catch that
type of thing, but you do expect a president to surround himself with people who are sufficiently
competent that that type of thing won't happen. And you do expect the president to be alarmed
if things of that kind happen. Certainly, President Clinton or President Obama would
have been very disturbed if somehow the budgets they put forward had had the kind of blatant
logical errors that were contained in President Trump's budget.
Do you think you'll serve in government again, Larry?
You never know what's going to happen. But right now, and for the foreseeable future, that were contained in President Trump's budget. Do you think you'll serve in government again, Larry?
You never know what's going to happen.
But right now and for the foreseeable future,
my focus is very much on my teaching and research and writing.
Are there any potential Democratic candidates in 2020 or 2024,
whatever, that you'd get particularly excited about?
Oh, you know, I just try to focus on the issues,
not the personalities. Do you think President Trump will serve out at least one full term?
We'll have to see what happens. That proposition is certainly more in doubt than it's been with any president that we've had in September of his first year. Do you bet? Are you a gambler at all?
Even like a football? I'm not really a gambler. Stephen, I'm getting near the end of his first year. Do you bet? Are you a gambler at all? Even like a football?
I'm not really a gambler.
Stephen, I'm getting near the end of my time here.
All right, let's say goodbye.
I thank you very much for your time.
All right.
Thanks very much.
If you're a gambler,
and if a Democrat gets back to the White House anytime soon,
what do you think are the odds they'll invite Larry Summers back to D.C.?
Yeah, that's what I think, too.
Coming up next time on Freakonomics Radio, just about every public place you go these
days, you'll hear music being played or some kind of a soundscape.
So that's a lot of sound to deal with.
After all, we aren't born with ear lids.
But the one place where you really want some noise?
It's quiet as a tomb.
Oh, it's disgusting,
but honestly, I'd really try to
avoid restrooms where there are lots
of men doing fireworks,
you know?
Time to take back the toilet.
That's next time on Freakonomics Radio.
Freakonomics Radio is produced by WNYC Studios and Dubner Productions.
This episode was produced by Greg Rosalski with help from Kent McDonald. Our staff also includes Allison Hockenberry, Merritt Jacob, Stephanie Tam,
Eliza Lambert, Emma Morgenstern, Harry Huggins, and Brian Gutierrez. We had help this week from Sam Baer. The music you hear throughout our episodes was composed by Luis Guerra. You can
subscribe to Freakonomics Radio on Apple Podcasts or Stitcher or wherever you get your podcasts.
You should also check out our archive at Freakonomics.com,
where you can stream or download every episode we've ever made,
or read the transcripts and find links to the underlying research.
You can also find us on Twitter, Facebook, or via email at radio at Freakonomics.com.