Freakonomics Radio - 311. Why Is the Live-Event Ticket Market So Screwed Up?
Episode Date: December 7, 2017The public has almost no chance to buy good tickets to the best events. Ticket brokers, meanwhile, make huge profits on the secondary markets. Here's the story of how this market got so dysfunctional,... how it can be fixed – and why it probably won't be.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Let me ask you a question.
When you buy tickets to a big concert or a professional sports event or a hot Broadway play, on a scale of 1 to 10, how would you rate the ticket buying experience?
Think about everything from the price to the availability of tickets to the transparency of the whole transaction.
Okay? Now, say your number. Ooh, it's even worse than I thought you'd say. All right, now,
rate the experience of the last non-ticket purchase you made. Clothing or groceries,
maybe a piece of furniture. Now, how would you rate that experience?
Yeah, that sounds about right. Most markets these days are pretty transparent and predictable and sensible. But the ticket market?
This is a market that's been screwed up for a long time.
That's Eric Budish, an economist who's written a paper on the ticket market.
And when he says it's screwed up, well, you already knew that,
didn't you? You already knew that the hotter the event is, the more likely it'll somehow be sold
out the minute tickets go on sale. You also know that scalpers somehow always get plenty of tickets
and they charge prices that could send a kid to college. You know all about those service fees,
too. Our investigation found that the venues and ticket vendors
like Ticketmaster and Tickets.com
can add on significant fees that as much as double the price of the ticket.
That's Eric Schneiderman, New York State's Attorney General,
talking about his investigation into various consumer abuses
in the ticketing industry.
One big focus, the software bots that scalpers use
to scoop up the best tickets before anybody else can get them.
The majority of tickets for the most popular concerts,
the report read, are not reserved for the general public.
None of Schneiderman's findings were particularly surprising to anyone.
Remember, this is the ticket market we're talking
about. This is a market that's been screwed up for a long time. It's been so screwed up for so
long that occasionally someone tries to do something about it. Recently, that someone was
Bruce Springsteen. It's hard to think of a performer with a more loyal fan base than Springsteen.
So when he announced that he was bringing a new intimate
show to a Broadway theater with a capacity of under a thousand seats, he wanted to make sure
his fans and not scalpers got the tickets, some of which would be priced as low as $75.
Springsteen also has more leverage than the typical performer. So he partnered with Ticketmaster to
use a new program called Verified Fan.
Ticketmaster calls Verified Fan, quote,
a really big robot to protect fans from the thousands of little scalper bots trying to scoop up tickets.
One night, we went up to the Walter Kerr Theater on Broadway, where Springsteen was playing,
to see if the people who wound up with tickets were indeed hardcore fans.
I got an early start when he first started,
like way back in the days when he was playing two no crowds.
So way back when.
I've seen him probably, I don't know, 10 or so times since,
and I've turned my kids on to be Bruce fans.
Time to go in. Love Springsteen. Been seeing him for 42 years now.
You know, when we got married, I knew it was God, Bruce, and then me.
That was the order in line.
So, problem solved?
Maybe.
But remember,
This is a market that's been screwed up for a long time.
What you don't know about the screwy ticket market could fill an entire episode of Freakonomics Radio.
And today, it will.
We'll hear from the ticket sellers.
We are the recipient of the fans' ire.
And, yeah, it's a tough spot to be in.
We'll hear from Broadway producers.
I mean, if steam is coming out of my ears now when you ask, why do I feel that?
We'll hear from ticket scalpers.
The bots are really a red herring because we could only get the amount of seats that they would sell.
And we'll hear from you, the fans.
I can't accept it. It's not, it hurts me, really. From WNYC Studios, this is Freakonomics Radio, the podcast that explores the hidden side of everything.
Here's your host, Stephen Dubner.
Okay, let's start with the economists. My name is Alan Kruger. I'm an economics professor at Princeton University. Kruger has also held big jobs in government,
in Treasury, Department of Labor. And then from 2011 to 2013, I served as chairman of President
Obama's Council of Economic Advisors.
So what's Kruger have to do with the ticket market?
Well, at the moment, I have many endeavors related to rock and roll.
Research endeavors, we should say.
And I'm in the process of writing a book on economics and music.
And then there's Eric Budish, whom we met earlier.
Sure. So I'm a professor of economics at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, and I
do research on market design.
Excellent.
Market design.
So let's start with that.
What's your view on kind of the markets that do work well, and what are the characteristics
of a market that needs a bit more tending to than others?
That's a hard question.
I don't know if I have a quick and articulate
answer to that. Markets and societies need rules. So I think of market design research as trying to
get the rules of the game right so that then competition can work its magic. You've argued
as an academic that at least one segment of the financial markets, at least one,
high-frequency trading is badly in need of a market redesign.
Yes? Could you explain?
Yeah. So I remember at the time being genuinely puzzled how it could be worth so much money to be three thousandths of a second faster than the competition.
And where my research ultimately led was this observation or this understanding that current financial exchanges have a design glitch.
One way to think about it is when stock markets transitioned from being run by humans screaming in pits to being run electronically,
we forgot to tell the computer to put time into a unit like a second or even a millisecond.
And because of this failure to put time into units, the design encouraged competition on speed. It became economically meaningful to be even a billionth of a second faster than the competition.
So stock exchanges sell what's called co-location, the right to put your computers next to their computers.
They sell that for a lot of money. They make more money from that than they do from trading fees,
from trading shares of stock. And the market design reform I've proposed in my research
is to put time into units, and then you can run what are called frequent batch auctions,
auctions conducted extremely quickly by human standards, but at a time interval that's
slow enough for a computer to transform the nature of competition from competition on speed into
competition on price. And has that solution been put into play even on an experimental basis?
So no, there are kind of practical reasons why not, and then there's Chicago lunch table reasons why not.
The practical reasons why not are market design reforms take time, and this is a particularly high-stakes market.
There's also the Chicago lunch table reason, which is that there are a lot of incumbents who make a lot of money from the status quo. At first glance, you might think high-frequency trading
has nothing in common with the live event ticket market.
But as we'll learn today, there are at least a couple important overlaps,
especially the speed-based competition and the power of the status quo.
Okay, let's start to unpack this. First of all, let's think about the nature of the status quo. Okay, let's start to unpack this.
First of all, let's think about the nature of the ticket market.
Here again are Eric Budish and Alan Kruger.
Well, I think it's different than most markets.
It's an experienced good.
The emotional connection is the product.
That's what separates it from buying canned peas.
Event tickets were underpriced from the 19th century.
Event tickets remain mispriced to this day.
I love that you go right to tickets being underpriced,
because I bet a lot of people hearing this think,
oh, man, no, no, no.
Events, musical events, concerts, sports events,
they're way overpriced.
But you, the economist, go straight to underpriced.
Can you explain that?
Sure.
So you caught me being an economist. Thank you for
that. So artists often want to sell their tickets to an economist an artificially low price. And
what I mean by that is a price at which demand dramatically exceeds supply. For example,
Bruce Springsteen cares deeply about his fans,
and he wants them to care deeply about him,
and he doesn't want to develop the reputation as gouging his fans.
That's less the case when you go to the grocery store.
So what does this lead to?
This leads to high school kids waiting in line for long amounts of time
to try to get these underpriced tickets.
It leads to ticket brokers waiting in line or finding other more nefarious ways
to get underpriced tickets to then resell them at a more market-clearing price.
I've heard artist managers say, and multiple artist managers say,
they would like to have their clients charge a higher price,
but the artists are reluctant.
They're sensitive to what's written about them on social media.
So economists are puzzled by the fact that ticket prices are often too low.
If a ticket price is too low, that means the artist or the underpriced tickets, instead of going to fans, go to ticket brokers or go to StubHub or go to other secondary market venues.
And we should say that ticket brokers, StubHub, secondary market venues, all of them are basically, is that what you would call as an economist, rent-seeking?
Yeah, so a lot of that activity is what I would call rent-seeking.
And the basic economic point is that if an artist sells a ticket for 50 bucks,
but the price at which that ticket clears the market is more like 500 bucks,
there's $450 of profit that's going somewhere.
And a lot of that activity isn't socially useful,
so it's profit-seeking without
social value. Global primary market ticket sales are estimated at around $30 billion a year.
Secondary market sales on markets like StubHub are estimated at another $10 billion. So that's
a lot of rent-seeking. We should point out, however, that a resale market like StubHub serves another purpose.
StubHub acts as an insurance policy.
That's Sandeep Baliga, an economist at Northwestern.
If you're sick, you know, or if you can't go to a game and so on and so forth,
that aspect of StubHub actually helps the originator of the ticket.
Because now the originator of the ticket can say,
look, before I was pricing it lower because you had no resale opportunities.
But now you can resell the ticket on StubHub.
And so because of that insurance, I'm going to actually charge you more
because I know that you have a safety net should you need one.
Talk about scooping up tickets in the primary market with the use of either just good strategy
or bots or any other technological kind of workaround.
That's competition on a, to an economist, a strange dimension.
Competition on speed rather than price.
That's the connection to my stuff on high-frequency trading.
It's competition, but it's not a productive form of competition.
Modern ticket selling strikes me as so old-fashioned and suboptimal in that, you know, all the tickets are released at once at a price
with only a kind of haphazard guess as to what the actual demand is
or what the price elasticity may be.
It reminds me of the bread drops in the old Soviet Union
where you'd hear that on Thursday morning, this market will have bread, and then you have long lines and an immediate
sellout, and then the bread gets resold on the black market. So with the tickets,
they're not using price theory at all the way economists would like to use price theory, right?
Well, I think you're absolutely right. Theickets are sold at a price, at a moment
in time. It is useful for venues to be able to plan in advance. So one reason why tickets are
sold all at once is while a concert is sold out, an artist might add another date. There's a quote
in your paper that I was very intrigued by. It's from a former chairman of Ticketmaster, Terry Barnes,
quoted in the Wall Street Journal in 2006, saying,
we're in an industry that prices its product worse than anybody else. So that's kind of
discouraging since Ticketmaster is the behemoth of ticket selling. You would think the one thing
they would know is how to price tickets. So Ticketmaster is, they're the largest primary market distributor of tickets in the world.
And when they say they price their products worse than anybody else, they're working on
behalf of clients, whether it's Beyonce or the New York Knicks. And the industry historically
has been really bad at it.
Yeah. So the ticketing value chain is opaque to most people.
It's David Marcus. I am the headeting value chain is opaque to most people. It's David
Marcus. I am the head of music at Ticketmaster North America. And because the ticketing chain
is so opaque, I'm going to walk backwards through the chain so you understand how everybody's
connected. Ticketmaster contracts with concert venues, sports venues, theaters, to be a vendor, and they are our client.
Can you just talk about the different players, you know, from the artist, promoter, venue operator,
et cetera, et cetera, and how their incentives may differ from one another and how those incentives
ultimately affect the price? Well, I don't think there is a standard model, but a typical type of model would be an artist who has a manager.
Manager might take 15% of the artist's gross take from a concert, and the manager will negotiate with the promoter.
The promoter has taken risk, has basically gone to an artist and said, I'm willing to guarantee you a certain amount of money for the
right to present your performance in this given venue. The contracts are to some extent like a
book contract where the artist will get in advance. The promoter goes and negotiates with the venue
to hold the concert at the venue. And the promoter does a little bit of math, figures out how many seats they have available,
what the production costs are, what the guarantee they might have offered the artist is, and
arrives at pricing for the show, arrives at a total gross they need to achieve for the
show.
The promoter will hire a company typically to distribute the tickets.
And the venue is responsible for effectively telling us
for every single event what are the ticket prices
that we need to charge
and what are the associated fees that go with that.
Ticketmaster is the major player in that market.
And then we take their direction
and make those tickets available to the fans
through our website, Ticketmaster.com,
and our affiliated partners.
The revenue breakdown among the different parties will vary depending on a given deal,
but typically between 30 and 50 percent of the ticket price goes to cover costs,
with roughly 85 percent of the remainder going to the performers and 15 percent to the promoter.
And then there are those much-unloved service fees
that vendors like Ticketmaster add.
In New York, they average 21% of the ticket price,
but as we heard earlier, they can reach 100% of face value.
Something that's not widely understood is that these service fees,
often part of them goes back to the venue.
In a percentage that varies widely, frankly,
depending on the venue and the relationship percentage that varies widely, frankly, depending on the
venue and the relationship they have to Ticketmaster. So Ticketmaster takes all the PR hit for these
egregious service fees, but actually a lot of that money spreads its way around the rest of the food
chain. It's actually historically kind of part of Ticketmaster's business model to take on the
burden of that negative sentiment.
In 2009, then Ticketmaster CEO Irving Azoff appeared before a Senate Judiciary subcommittee which was concerned that Ticketmaster's upcoming merger with Live Nation Entertainment would hurt
consumers. You know, Ticketmaster was set up as a system where they took the heat for everybody.
Ticketmaster gets a minority percentage of that service charge. In that service charge are the credit card fees, the rebates to the buildings,
rebates sometimes to artists, sometimes rebates to promoters.
We would say it in the hallways. Yeah, you know, the reason that we're
as successful as we are is because we take those bullets on behalf of
the venue, the artist, the promoter.
Of course, if you worked for Ticketmaster, like David Marcus does, you'd probably say
that too.
But all the evidence we've been hearing today, from economists who've researched the
ticket industry and governments who've investigated it, it seems to back up the argument that
Ticketmaster does the bidding of other parties.
The evidence also points to a fairly bizarre ecosystem where certain parties
want to keep prices low for appearances sake, but also want to make as much money as they can.
And they've built in a series of opaque transactions to make that happen.
I said to a manager recently, is the concern about selling out. And he said there are two
concerns about selling out. One is that they don't sell out the house, which is what I meant. But the other is
that they're being viewed as having sold out to the capitalists and that they're gouging their fans.
Artists value the ability to say, we're sold out. And we sold out in a minute or two minutes. And that is historically a banner to wave that reflects your, you know,
stardom. But from an economic perspective, that's a disaster. If you sold out in a minute,
you underpriced dramatically, right? A lot of artists have their cake and eat it too. They'll
set prices at what looks like an artificially low level,
but then in excess of 20% of tickets will never get sold to fans and get kept by
the producers, the promoters, the venue, house seats of some sort. And then those seats have
a way of finding their way onto the secondary market. Yeah, there's two different greed lines.
That is Ken Losen. Okay, so I invented TicketBots about, oh, 18 or 19 years ago.
That might be a bit of an overreach.
Others were working on TicketBots too.
But still, we've been hearing about the supply side of ticket selling,
how the allocation happens, how prices are set, and so on.
Ken Losen, as a ticket broker, or, if you will, a scalper,
sat at the intersection of supply and demand.
Okay, and what about those greed lines?
You want the fan to get mad at a misdirected person than at the artist
because they lose their fans that way.
Like, they can price their ticket at $150 before their fans puke,
but, you know, a scalper can sell the same fan a seat for $2,000,
and they're not mad at the artist, they're mad at the scalper.
But they still pay it.
Coming up on Freakonomics Radio,
how people like Losen got hold of the tickets that you can't.
I got really lucky with a super genius out of Bulgaria.
We talk about possible fixes to the screwed-up ticket
market. It's blown away our expectations. But why even the best fixes might not be good enough.
Everybody's making money on scalping. Everybody from top to bottom.
As we've been hearing, there are a number of ways in which the live event ticket market is not a typical market.
You're buying an experience versus a product or a service.
It happens at a specific time and place.
Also, the people who create and produce live events, Broadway shows, for instance, They have a relationship to their product that runs
particularly deep. When I was a kid, the reason I got hooked on theater was my parents took me a lot
because theater was, you know, affordable. That's the Broadway producer Hal Luftig.
Among his many shows is Kinky Boots. Tickets were $3.50. It didn't break the bank.
If I were a rich man.
We were all up on the balcony.
I saw Fiddler on the Roof from the second to last row.
And it still worked.
And it still worked.
Broadway prices today are quite a bit higher, especially for the hottest shows like Hamilton.
Good afternoon. This is Jeffrey Seller speaking. I am the role of a theatrical producer, in as much as most people ever do think about that role, which may not be so much, no offense, what probably comes to mind is Max Bialystock, the producer.
Step one, we find the worst play ever written. Step two, we hire the worst director.
So can you talk about what you actually do as a producer and how that may or may not resemble what Max Bialystock did.
Well, first of all, I don't own a cardboard belt.
So there's a difference right there.
And I don't have Ula working for me in my office.
I'm a lot skinnier than Max Bialy's stock. And I would never take advantage of an old lady
to get a few dollars out of her pocketbook
to put into my show.
Hello, gorgeous.
Did you bring the checky?
Bialy can't produce plays without checky.
I kind of say what a producer does is
serves as that owner or CEO
that kind of oversees everything.
I am responsible for finding the funding for the production.
A producer also has his hand in the actual management of a day-to-day.
Right.
Well, one of the principal jobs that the producer has to fulfill is setting the prices.
And the first thing we have to look at
is how much money does it cost to run the show every week?
Very early on in a production's life,
money needs to be spent on, if nothing else,
just hiring the author, the director.
They all get a little bit of a fee to start.
And there are things like getting the rights
and getting the creative team.
And you'd be amazed how expensive it is.
Well, a Broadway musical these days can cost anywhere from $10 million to $20 million.
And it is certainly common for me to invest up to 5% of the budget personally. And just to put it in perspective of what that financial risk is,
80% of shows do not pay back their original capitalization. Of the 20 that return the
capital, probably half of them make a very modest profit, like maybe a 4% or 5% return on capital. And then you have your blockbusters
that come around every now and then that become enormous windfalls in which investors
can multiply their original investment sometimes by 10 to 20 times.
You have Lion King, you have Phantom of the Opera, you have Chicago, you know, Kinky Boots.
Bruce Springsteen, right? Oh, wait, has he recouped?
Did you name Hamilton? Did you include Hamilton? Oh, no, I haven't named, I mean, I haven't,
yeah, Hamilton. That's a fairly popular one, I understand. You think? I don't know.
That's iffy. Hamilton is doing great, and its investors call me and thank me on a regular basis.
Talk about the breakdown of that profit distribution.
The first thing that happens with the weekly income is you have to pay your bills.
You know, you pay the theater, you pay the theater rent, you pay the theater percentage, you know, all the crew, the cast, the orchestra, your advertising bills, all of that gets paid.
After the show pays all of their expenses, then the profits go to the investors and the
producers and they share the profits.
The way you've described the distribution, basically the producer more than anyone else,
by far, if it's a home run, you do really well.
And if it's not, run, you do really well.
And if it's not, then you really don't.
You really don't.
And here's the thing that people don't realize about producers.
You know, in other industries, people who are working on something get paid while they're working on it.
Not producers.
I can work on something for four or five years. I'm not drawing a salary or
I'm not getting any income. The only way that a producer really starts making money is when the
show becomes a hit. Hamilton had the experience of having a show go on sale on a given day with
a block of tickets and watching the entire block of tickets sold
within minutes. At first, we're happy. Wow, we sold all our tickets in a matter of minutes or
an hour. But then what we learn is that a lot of consumers are frustrated that they could not buy tickets. And then we learn that those very tickets are being sold for three,
four, five, eight, ten times their face value.
Jeffrey Seller wouldn't talk to us about actual Hamilton profits, but here's what we do know.
So far this year, the Broadway version has taken in more than $140 million in ticket revenues. A 2016 New York Times estimate put annual operating costs at about $34 million. So that's a lot of profit spread around to producers and investors, to Lin-Manuel Miranda, who wrote the show and originated the lead role, to the rest of the creative team, and so on.
That said, the $140 million revenue figure is from the primary ticket market,
not the secondary market run by brokers and scalpers.
Millions has been lost.
There was a point where we knew that up to 70% of our tickets
were being purchased through automated bots.
I, for one, went down's also not good for stakeholders,
like the artists who write the show, create the show, work on the show,
and for the producers who take the risk and the investors who take the risk.
If there are going to be windfall profits,
they need to go to the people who supported the show and the people who created the show.
Hal Luftig has a similar view of bots and scalpers.
Steam is coming out of my ears now.
When you asked, how do I feel about Steam?
It was a cartoon.
Steam is coming out of my ears.
Because I think there's nothing positive about the secondary market.
They haven't done a thing to help create this show.
But the fact is that a lot of people are willing to pay a lot more than face value to see a show like Hamilton.
Now, to be fair, the show has raised its prices quite a bit.
The average amount paid for a ticket to Hamilton on Broadway in 2017
was $274, nearly double the average amount paid in its first year, 2015.
But they also distribute thousands of $10 tickets each year to students
and another 46 tickets every night priced at just $10 via a lottery.
So what we use is a Robin Hood strategy of soaking the rich to help the poor.
Okay, but since scalpers make so much money by selling tickets so far above their face
value, why don't producers just raise their prices more to capture the money they see as rightfully
theirs? I want families to come. I want people to come again. I want, you know, tourists to be able
to come and not have to break the bank. You know, this notion of fairness is so important to us.
And so I may not be maximizing at the moment my dollars,
but hopefully I'm creating a culture of people who will keep going to shows.
So that's another way in which the ticket market, at least for Broadway tickets,
isn't a typical market. The people in charge, at least the ones we interviewed,
don't really want to
engage in what economists call profit maximizing. They want to make their shows accessible to
a broad audience and they want to not exploit that audience. But by doing so, they end up
underpricing their tickets, which creates an opportunity for other people to profit
maximize.
Correct. And we called ourselves, you know, we specialized in
ticket pulling is what they call it. That again is Ken Losen. And that's something that goes back
before the internet. You would go get in line, a physical line at 10 a.m. And David Marcus from
Ticketmaster. Back then, concert tickets were often sold in record stores. First come, first served.
The clerk would open the door to the record store, and the line would filter in.
The guys would, you know, go pay off the record store manager,
and then they'd sit in the back, pull out all the good ones, and they'd let the first person in.
And scalpers would get somebody in line.
They would hire homeless people to stand in line for them.
Eventually, sales shifted to the phone and Ticketmaster.
And the same paradigm was implied.
At 10 a.m., when the record stores unlock their doors, we'll open the phone lines.
And we'll be able to process more orders faster.
We were really, really good at flirting with the Ticketmaster operators.
And then, you know, making them hit the keys quicker for us.
And we had our boiler room kind of set up.
And 40 people buying tickets.
And then the internet came around.
And in the late 90s, we sold our first ticket via the internet.
And the same paradigm was put into play.
At 10 a.m., when the doors open to the record stores,
and when the phones light up, we'll open the ability to buy tickets on the internet.
And you had just this massive surface area of the ability to buy tickets on the internet. And you had just this massive surface
area of the ability to transact was created. And Ticketmaster became really unmatched in terms of
being able to sell huge volumes of tickets quickly. Well, the bots came along and we saw that volume
jump. Now you could buy hundreds of times more seats. Losen's company was called Wiseguy Tickets.
During the internet era, it became one of the most notorious and successful ticket scalping operations.
He makes it clear he had a lot of programming help.
I got really lucky with a super genius out of Bulgaria.
And we were just better at it than anybody else in the game.
And, you know, we were shaving milliseconds.
But what about anti-fraud software,
like the Captcha field that supposedly needs a human to fill it out?
They were only using 30,000 images static.
So anybody who knows Captcha knows you have to use millions,
if not hundreds of millions of images,
and you've got to rotate them if you want to stop automators.
You don't just put in the same 30,000 images
and leave them there for two years.
It wasn't even like a thing to beat.
By the mid-2000s, Wiseguy was getting the best tickets
to the biggest concerts and sporting events and Broadway shows.
We'd go in there and be out in a minute and have all the seats, you know.
For example, the Rose Bowl sold 1,000 tickets to the public,
and I got like, I don't know, 870 or 900 or something.
Wiseguy was a middleman.
Brokers would feed them credit card numbers on behalf of clients, and Wiseguy would use those cards to buy batches of tickets.
We had like, I don't know, 200 Amex cards.
So if there was an Amex sale, we would really take them all.
Okay, so let's back up a bit here.
The real scalping is going on between who and whom.
Well, promoters and teams sell directly to brokers,
and then those brokers then list them on the marketplace.
For a team owner, it's their ticket,
and for a promoter, it's their ticket.
It's not the artist's ticket.
I don't know another industry that intentionally advertises
one price to intentionally hold it and resell it secretly.
But the story that we keep hearing is that the parties who make out financially worst are the artists themselves because they want to keep the price low because they want to serve their fans and they want to be sold out, right?
Well, they want to sell their product for as much as they can, like any other business. Yeah. But what we're told is that artists are typically not getting any of that
additional markup. Are you saying that's not the case that they are getting some of that markup?
Well, I mean, I mean, maybe it's something like that, but their managers are, you know,
hired to make them the most money. And in the end, you know, if you're taking a guaranteed
amount that's higher than the revenue from the tickets, you know, if you're taking a guaranteed amount
that's higher than the revenue from the tickets, it's like a pre-scalp.
I just want to make sure I understand it.
So it's not that the artists are per se getting a cut.
Let's say a ticket sells for $100 on the primary and gets marked up to $500, right?
It's not like the artist is getting any of that additional $400.
It's that the guarantee that their manager negotiates for them
is based on a ticket sale
priced somewhere in between the $100 and $500.
Is that what you're saying?
Well, they're negotiating with, you know, a promoter for a flat amount, you know, per
show.
There's 50 shows on the tour.
We want $50 million.
A flat fee or fixed guarantee is one model of artist payment, but hardly the only one.
There's also a fee based on a percentage of ticket sales and all kinds of potential hybrid models.
You know, and if that adds up to less than the ticket, the box office price,
then of course the promoter can only make it up in the scalping market.
Everybody's making money on scalping. Everybody from top to bottom.
Everybody, including Ken Losen and Wiseguy.
But in 2010, it came to an end when the FBI shut down his operation.
One count of conspiracy to commit wire fraud, which was based on a Russian programmer asking for Amazon dollars.
Losen doesn't seem to have moral qualms about what he did.
You might hate me for the price, but I'm delivering exactly what I promised you.
That said, he recently started up a new firm
that's trying to make primary ticket markets better
for artists, teams, and fans.
It's called TixFan.
Lohsen is hopeful he can change the ticket-buying paradigm,
but he admits that most of his old allies
seem to favor the existing paradigm.
I went to four primaries and four rock stars and three teams and promoters and managers
and offered basically to do anti-bot and anti-scalping for free if they wanted to, to do a proof
of concept. And nobody wanted to do it.
Milton Friedman talked about the tyranny of the status quo.
That, again, is the University of Chicago economist Eric Budish.
And the Chicago lunch table sees a market that's screwed up and says,
huh, who's making money from the fact that this market runs inefficiently?
Let's try to understand the forces preserving the status quo. So if you, Eric Budish, were given the ability and authority to redesign from scratch the optimal ticket sales market for things like concerts, sporting events, and so on, including primary and perhaps secondary sales that is both profit maximizing to the, quote, right people and fair to consumers.
What's that market look like?
I think you have to let artists and sports teams and so forth ban resale or restrict resale if they want to.
So you have to make it possible for Bruce Springsteen to set a $75 price for his tickets
and have that ticket be something that you literally cannot resell to
another human. And as an analogy, if I buy a plane ticket, I can't resell my plane ticket to you,
Steve. And it's got my name on it. I got to show my driver's license when I get to the airport.
I mean, we're used to resale bans in other contexts. So I think you have to enable artists
to ban resale. Are you sure you're an economist, though?
I'm giving the artist the choice.
I'm not mandating that Bruce Springsteen sell this form of contract.
But I think it recognizes that there is this nonstandard element to entertainment events where artists or sports teams want to set a below market price.
I think you have to allow them to also ban resale. You have to then, in concert with that, enable fans who buy
a ticket that they genuinely no longer can use to, in some way, get their money back.
There's another idea, also appealing to economists, that would improve the ticket market.
Absolutely. What's beautiful about an auction is that auctions find the exact price at which
demand meets supply.
If you think that's the problem, which I think a lot of artists don't, there's a complicated industry,
but if you think the problem is how do we find exactly the right price that maximizes revenue and doesn't leave seats empty,
auctions are the economic solution to that problem.
And Budish discovered that back in the early 2000s, Ticketmaster actually used auctions
to sell some premium concert tickets.
You know, we were selling 100 tickets per auction.
David Marcus again from Ticketmaster.
These are for typically really high-demand artists who are playing arenas.
Artists including Beyonce, Miley Cyrus, and the police.
And they were developed fundamentally to solve this problem of trying to find a mechanism that would allow us to set market prices for premium tickets.
Because, you know, scalping was increasingly an issue,
and the artist community was aware of it, and we were all looking for solutions.
Eric Budish and another economist, Aditya Bhave,
wanted to know how well those auctions worked in helping demand meet supply.
They collected sales data from Ticketmaster, the primary market, and from eBay, a secondary market.
Today, by the way, eBay owns StubHub.
So in the data, they could see a given ticket migrate from one market to the other.
You can think of the empirical exercises as like tag the whale.
So you see a ticket sold in the primary market auction
and then trace that same ticket to its secondary market resale value.
For each ticket that made the journey, they compared three prices.
Its auction price, its resale price, and the face value price it would have sold at had there not been an auction.
And the main finding of the paper, it's a pretty simple paper,
is that the auctions worked in the sense of, on average, discovering the secondary market resale value.
In other words, the auctions discovered the right price at which the event's creators and producers could profit maximize.
The difference between the auction price and the average secondary market resale value was 2%
versus about a 100% difference between the face value and the resale value.
So the auctions kind of worked, as an economist might expect the auction to work.
So Ticketmaster, in conjunction with some big-time touring artists, decides,
hey, we're giving away way too much money to people who aren't contributing anything here,
so why don't we capture that money?
They do it. It works.
More money goes to the people who, quote, deserve it.
That sounds like a success and a no-brainer to continue it into the future.
Is that exactly what happened then?
No, the auctions are actually no longer in use and haven't been for several years.
The problem we ran into was consumers didn't really like it very much. We couldn't get enough people to participate
for four or five or six days of bidding. And it wasn't scalable.
An auction can be intimidating. The high fixed price might be too high a price, but it's not
intellectually complicated. It wasn't a terrible experience,
but it required that a fan be really committed. And it didn't have a lot of instant gratification.
In fact, it had no instant gratification. And it just couldn't hold consumer attention.
So the auction model, which appeals to economists, didn't fly because it doesn't appeal to the real fans who actually buy tickets. Another model that might appeal to economists,
using blockchain technology to register and track ownership of individual ticket sales.
That's what a Dutch startup called Guts is trying.
And Ticketmaster, as we noted at the top of this episode,
recently tried another idea, the verified fan program.
When there's really high demand for an event,
Bruce Springsteen's Broadway run, for instance,
this ticket-buying model doesn't prioritize speed or even price,
but degree of fandom.
We can really not make it about when, but about who.
Who are you?
Are you someone who's likely to use the ticket we sell you?
Or are you someone who's likely to resell the ticket we sell you? Are you someone who's likely to use the ticket we sell you? Or are you someone who's likely to resell the ticket we sell you?
Ticketmaster registers fans and collects their email addresses and ticket purchasing history.
And we run a series of sophisticated algorithms to try to forecast what that fan's behavior will be if they are successful buying a ticket.
The algorithms factor in a variety of true fan behaviors.
If, for instance, you want to buy Taylor Swift tickets, there are boost activities that will help.
Sharing social media links, buying merchandise, watching music videos. Or if you really want to ingratiate yourself, you could take a selfie with a UPS truck, UPS being a major Taylor Swift sponsor.
The public responses to this extended commercialism have been, not surprisingly, mixed.
But David Marcus from Ticketmaster considers Verified Fan a huge success.
It's blown away our expectations.
When we look across the 60-plus tours that we've applied Verified Fan to,
we see that fewer than 5% of the tickets that we distribute via the Verified Fan program
get listed on the secondary market,
which suggests that we're doing a really good job predicting that post-transaction behavior.
A cynic might point out that Ticketmaster wants to steal market share from the secondary
market because that market is dominated by a rival, StubHub.
Ticketmaster itself does resell tickets through its TM Plus resale site, but those sales are
dwarfed by StubHub's. A cynic might also point out that
when the stakes are high enough for a given event, the verified fan concept can look impotent,
as in the case of Bruce Springsteen on Broadway. The intimate show with the affordable ticket
prices meant for true fans has somehow become a scalper's holiday.
Tickets originally sold for $75 are routinely offered on StubHub for $2,000, $5,000, $10,000.
Springsteen has added dates to the engagement, which prompted one cynical headline, quote,
Springsteen to extend Broadway run, giving you more chances to miss out on tickets.
Here's some more audio from our visit to the Walter Kerr Theater before one of Springsteen's shows.
I'm so sorry. However, you guys can join the online lottery. So I suggest doing that, okay?
For what?
Oh, it's dead time.
Future time, okay? But take one of these for now, okay?
Thank you.
Try next time.
Try next time.
So, yes, we found plenty of diehard Bruce fans outside the theater
who got their tickets through primary channels,
but we also found people like this woman
who'd come from Belgium to see Bruce.
I never stood a chance, and I can't accept it.
I feel like this is a once-in-a-lifetime experience and I will not be
able to join and it's very frustrating. It's not, it hurts me really. She tried the normal channels.
When the tickets were on sale I tried for days and days and days in a row to get in.
At one point I managed to register only to get a message later that I was being put on hold.
And actually today, I saw a ticket for sale for $800, and I pushed the pay button,
and then I saw that there was another $200 service fee, and then I dropped it,
because I thought, I cannot rationalize this for myself.
I mean, this is too much money.
We asked if she was going to try for another night or enter the ticket lottery.
I don't know.
I think I'm just going to go for a drink or something.
Freakonomics Radio is produced by WNYC Studios and Dubner Productions.
This episode was produced by Stephanie Tam.
Our staff also includes Allison Hockenberry, Merritt Jacob, Greg Rosalski, Harry Huggins, and Brian Gutierrez.
We had help this week from Dan DeZula and research help from Zach Lipinski and Eamon Monaghan.
The music you hear throughout the episode was composed by Luis Guerra.
You can subscribe to Freakonomics Radio on Apple Podcasts or wherever you get your podcasts.
You should also check out our archive at Freakonomics.com. You can stream or download
every episode we've ever made. You can also read the transcripts and find links to the
underlying research. We can also be found on Twitter, Facebook, or via email
at radio at Freakonomics.com. Thanks for listening.