Freakonomics Radio - 425. Remembrance of Economic Crises Past
Episode Date: July 9, 2020Christina Romer was a top White House economist during the Great Recession. As a researcher, she specializes in the Great Depression. She tells us what those disasters can (and can’t) teach us about... the Covid crash.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
So what's it feel like as an economic historian to be living through a moment that's plainly
historic from an economic perspective?
It is sort of mind-blowing.
I remember back from the 2008 recession, I said to myself, well, I never thought in my
life I'd live through a bank run.
And here were people lining up outside banks.
Now I'm living through a pandemic.
It is just really hard to fathom.
That is Christina Romer.
I'm a professor at the University of California, Berkeley.
She is a scholar of economic catastrophe, the Great Depression in particular.
She was also chair of President Obama's Council of Economic Advisors at the start of his first term during the darkest days of the global financial crisis.
She had been surprised to get that job.
And several months later, I was talking to Rahm Emanuel, the president's chief of staff.
And I said, by the way, just tell me why I got this job.
And he said, you were an expert on the Great Depression, and we thought we might need one.
It did take several years, but the U.S. and global economies recovered from that catastrophe,
recovered pretty well, at least. But now the COVID-19 pandemic has produced an economic threat that borders on the existential.
In the first quarter this year, the GDP shrank by 4.8 percent.
Nearly 46 million jobless claims have been filed in the last three months.
Some advisors to the president are warning of unemployment numbers straight out of the Great Depression.
The Great Depression.
This is way worse than anything we saw in the Great Depression. And so, with everything going on right now, we thought it'd be good for us to consult a Great Depression expert, if only to help us make sense of it all.
Today on Freakonomics Radio, Christina Romer tells us the valuable lessons we can draw from the past.
I still feel we should have done even more.
She lists the current priorities.
It is the single biggest thing that needs to be done even more. She lists the current priorities. It is the single biggest thing
that needs to be done very quickly.
And whether we'll make it out okay on the other side.
I mean, the history of this country
is rising to challenges. From Stitcher and Dubner Productions, this is Freakonomics Radio,
the podcast that explores the hidden side of everything went into recession all the way back in February.
Christina Romer sits on the committee that makes such declarations.
For the past few decades, she has studied the causes and consequences of economic downturns.
Why did she choose such a cheerful topic?
For an economist, there's almost nothing that matters as much in people's lives as whether
they have a job, whether they can support their families. I think it probably doesn't hurt that I
came of age. I was in graduate school during the Volcker recession of the early 1980s,
and I think that was a searing experience for me and really made it stand out in my life.
Romer's parents were children during the Great Depression,
and she saw the market made on them as they got older.
My mother was the most frugal person you could imagine. I can remember when my father, they were buying a house that was a little bit of a stretch.
And I can remember finding my father sitting up one night just in a sweat over whether he should take on this mortgage.
If we were having this conversation at the start of 2020 with record low unemployment, record high stock markets, a generally robust
economy.
If we were having this conversation back then and I said, Professor Romer, I believe that
real GDP in the U.S. will fall something on the order of 5% to 6% in 2020, you would have
said what to me?
You're out of your mind.
I can even remember having been on a phone call with one
of the advisory boards that I'm on after the pandemic had started, but it was really early.
And someone said, I think the unemployment rate's going to go to 11%. And even then I said, oh,
for heaven's sakes, this is not the Great Recession. It's going to be a dislocation.
It's going to cause problems. But how do you get
to 11 percent? The unemployment rate actually blew past 11 percent. It is worth noting that
an economist as experienced as Romer, as experienced in economic catastrophes, didn't
see that coming. It's also worth noting that the magnitude and volatility of this labor
implosion make it even harder than usual to measure the true unemployment rate.
I mean, it always has, you know, some problems with it. There's some particular problems because
we're asking questions that we don't normally have to ask, like, are you employed but staying
home because you've been exposed to the coronavirus?
Right? That's not a question that was ever on the survey before. And so there are certainly
some problems just with how do we code those things. How does this compare to her time in
the White House during the Great Recession? You know, I thought in late November of 2008, while we're headed for a terrible downturn, maybe
the unemployment rate will go up three or four percentage points.
And then the numbers start to come in and it's hitting you just, my heavens, how horrible
this thing is.
Both the private forecasters, those of us in government, everybody was having to readjust and say,
wow, this is really bad. Oh my goodness, it's worse than really bad. And I'm sure that the
people in the Treasury and the Council of Economic Advisers today are having those
same kinds of moments of, holy hell, I didn't know it could get this bad.
So I guess the big question really is how worried are you right now about the
near and long-term future of the U.S. economy?
That's the million-dollar question. I'm, of course, deeply worried about the near-term outlook. What we're living through right now is truly wretched, and there aren't bad enough words to describe just how much many people are suffering.
We've had a cataclysmic decline in output, a cataclysmic fall in employment. I think what worries me a lot is,
I think some people think, oh, we're starting to end the lockdowns, we'll snap right back.
And that, unfortunately, is not going to happen. And I think people maybe aren't prepared for the
fact that this is going to be a long, hard slog. And so the pain we may have for
not just a few more months, but a few more years is something that concerns me greatly.
There is growing evidence that this slog will indeed be long and hard.
COVID-19 diagnoses are rising fast in many places. Many states, including Texas and Florida
and California, have paused or reversed their plans to reopen the economy.
This may cause a much more permanent change in how we live and how we do things. And so
we have to shut down some industries and there's going to be some new industries that grow up.
And then even for some of the same industries that we still want, the restaurants, the services,
if those businesses have gone out of business, then somebody else has to come in, figure out
how to do it, hire the workers, build the customer base, and that's going to take time.
So how does Romer compare the current U.S. economic damage to the Great Depression?
So we don't have quarterly data for the Great Depression, but the numbers for the first few years of the 1930s was real GDP fell at about 10% a year. And from the peak to the trough of the Great Depression, real GDP declined by about 30%.
So we lost a third of our output. And when the numbers come out for the second quarter of this
year, we're likely to learn that it's fallen by about 40% at an annual rate. So when we talk about
a 40% annual rate, it means if we had the same behavior in the
second quarter and in the next three quarters, GDP would be down 40%. And nobody expects that
to happen. I was just looking at some numbers from the Congressional Budget Office, and they think
when the dust is all settled, we'll probably say that GDP fell about 5% or 6% over all of 2020.
So again, that's horrible.
But when you compare it back to the Great Depression, where it was 10% a year, and where
it didn't happen just one year, but three years, it does at least help you to realize what our grandparents lived through back in the 1930s dwarfs even
what is truly a horrible time now.
As for the Great Recession, where Romer had a front row seat, real GDP fell then by about
6.3% in the fourth quarter of 2008.
But apart from being a useful comparison, past recessions and depressions
may also offer lessons on how to escape from this one. I asked Romer to describe what she
considers the most effective parts of the Obama administration's Recovery Act.
The first thing to say is we still had a quite severe recession. And so at that sense, nobody should take a victory lap
because it was really painful for lots of people. I think the one piece of the Recovery Act that has
been now studied in hindsight is the aid to state and local governments. For an economist,
it's a great example because some of the state and local fiscal
relief in the Recovery Act was actually given more based just kind of on historical accident.
Meaning the relief was almost randomized, as if in an experiment.
And so it gave us a nice natural experiment. We can see if states that got more fiscal relief for relatively
exogenous reasons did better. And the answer was they did. You know, it was only about $130,
$140 billion. I know, only. But it seemed to have been very effective.
For instance, one analysis of Recovery Act aid found that increasing a state's Medicaid funding helped increase long-term employment.
On the flip side, states and municipalities that had drastic cuts were slower to recover, often by years.
In Romer's own analysis of the Great Depression, she found that federal aid to states and municipalities was very effective. Absolutely. Before Roosevelt came in,
the states were the main ones doing relief. And then as soon as Roosevelt started to have some of
his public works and things like that, one of the things we see is states saying, oh, thank heavens,
now we can get our fiscal house in order. So as we were designing the Recovery Act,
I was one of the big proponents of, we got to make sure that state and local governments
don't start laying off public workers and cutting a lot of the crucial services because
that's just going to make this so much worse.
Romer thinks the same formula is important in the current crisis.
State and local governments are experiencing huge drops in revenue
and huge increases in spending for public services like health care and unemployment.
State governments are something like $750 billion in the red.
And unlike the federal government, states can't just keep borrowing and run at a deficit.
They have laws requiring at least the proposal of a balanced budget. And because they're not allowed
to run budget deficits, they're going to have to start cutting spending, cutting social programs,
cutting infrastructure. And that's going to be the real test of bipartisanship, because Democrats tend to
be proponents of giving money to state and local governments, and Republicans often are not. And
that will be the real test if we can get that through, because it is the single biggest thing
that needs to be done very quickly. So if you are running one of these states that's taking on massive debt now
dealing with COVID, would you try to undo this balanced budget requirement and run in a deficit?
That's a great question. I mean, I think the much better thing is probably for states to
stay the way they are and for the federal government to use its power to borrow to help the states,
simply because, right, we are one country. And especially something like COVID doesn't affect
every place the same, but it seems like the natural thing that we all share in those burdens.
You don't say, oh, well, you're a state that happened to get unlucky, so you're just going to have to pay for it.
A benefit of being in a large country is that we have insurance.
We take care of one another.
When there's a hurricane in Florida, the rest of the country helps them.
When there is a terrible COVID outbreak in New York City, I think the rest of the country should help them.
Right. But the fact is that a lot of these states that are in real trouble,
they claim that they're not getting anywhere near the federal money that they need.
So relying on the old model may be catastrophic. So what do you think will happen there? Let me include the question that's a matter of some discussion and controversy about bankruptcy
for states and whether it should perhaps be permitted.
Just as I think it's a terrible thing for anyone to talk about the federal government
defaulting on its debt, I think we're a country where we pay our debts.
So I think letting states go bankrupt, that's just not a sensible strategy.
We ought to actually deal with the problems that we have.
We're a rich country.
We can do this.
And we don't have to act like a country that doesn't have effective government.
What should be happening to a state that is in real trouble. I think it would certainly
be much better for them to find a way to borrow than to not serve their people, to not deal with
the public health crisis. So I hope it doesn't come to that. I hope that we can have sensible
federal fiscal policy to help the states that are in real trouble.
But barring that, finding a way to allow them to borrow, I think would be a much better strategy.
Keep in mind, Romer was among the most enthusiastic proponents of federal aid to states during the recovery from the Great Recession.
While putting together the 2009 Recovery Act, one of the major debates was over the size of the federal stimulus package.
I still feel we should have done even more, but I do feel good that I bargained people up by,
you know, several hundred billion.
Yeah, so talk about that for a minute. We've read about your participation as a member of
this team, which included, among others,
Larry Summers, who's, I think, sometimes misunderstood in whether his aggression is intellectual or personal or whatnot. But you wanted the aid to be how much bigger than it
ended up being, and how much more did you get than was originally proposed?
The main thing that I remember actually was a meeting where Larry turned out to be a
crucial second vote for my opinion. So, you know, I think the proposals had been for numbers closer
to doing a fiscal stimulus of about $600 billion. And I remember having run lots of numbers. I
came in and I said, this is much too small. I think it needs to be,
at least 800 billion and probably bigger. And I almost fell off my seat when Larry said,
I agree with Christy. Why were you so surprised he agreed?
Well, because Larry doesn't agree with anyone. But so it was really important for, as I said,
it's not nearly as big as it needed to be, but it was a lot bigger than anyone had been thinking.
Now, was your desire to have the fiscal stimulus be larger then?
Was that a result of your understanding of the Great Depression and the way that fiscal aid was used back then and that it essentially was not large enough?
Absolutely.
There's two things that I think I learned from the Depression. One was,
relative to the size of the unemployment problem in the early 1930s, what Roosevelt did was much too small. It was big relative to anything that had been done in the past, but it was not nearly
enough to deal with the problem. The other thing is actually
monetary policy can be very effective, even when interest rates are quite low. And so, you know,
though what the Federal Reserve was doing wasn't the bailiwick of the administration,
one of the things that several of us tried to convey to the president is,
you know, what the Fed is doing is a great thing. You want to be supporting Ben Bernanke.
What specifically was Bernanke doing that you thought was positive that needed encouragement?
Things like when interest rates get to zero, one of the tools that you still have is to try to affect people's expectations of inflation because that affects what the real cost of borrowing is.
And so I think Bernanke was taking a number of steps. For example, at this time, they started giving out something that's close to a target for what they
were aiming for, for the inflation rate. And I remember trying to explain that that was probably
a good thing, because we were in a world where with unemployment at 10%, people might be starting
to expect inflation to come down. And if the Fed is signaling, no, we're going to keep it at least at 2%, that can actually be very positive.
So the political costs of the recession and the Obama White House's response to it were pretty extreme, whether it was the recovery plan itself or just the depth of the recession.
Dems got crushed in those midterms two years after Obama's election.
Surely, the Trump administration is looking back at that to judge how they want their responses to affect the next election.
How do you think that will influence what they ultimately decide?
I mean, I pray it doesn't affect what they decide.
What everybody should be doing is what's right for the country. And so
this is a case where you would think that both their political interest and what the country
needs would be, you know, let's deal with the public health crisis. Let's make sure there's
enough support for workers, that there's support for state and local government. So I'm hoping that this is a time when there's no conflict between the politics and what would be
right to do. We'll have to see. Coming up after the break, the mistakes learned from previous
economic recoveries and how even in a crisis, Romer keeps her chin up. You haven't yet taken the optimism out of me.
Also, don't forget to check out our new spinoff podcast,
No Stupid Questions,
which is sort of Freakonomics for Psychology.
You can get it wherever you get your podcasts.
Christina Romer, a former top White House economist,
has spent her career analyzing the causes and consequences of recessions and depressions.
In light of the fact that the economy has become much more globalized in recent decades,
I asked Romer to describe how the U.S. economy is unique
and how that will affect our recovery from the COVID crash.
Traditionally, the American economy has been, what do I want to say, more vibrant, more dynamic. So
if you want to compare us to Europe, we have more flexible labor markets. It's easier to start a
business here. It's easier to close down a business here. And that has often served us very well because capitalism is good at some things and especially at figuring out what consumers want. But it does mean that it makes an economy much harder on workers. It's a lot easier to lay people off. You don't have the same employment
protections. It certainly has been very hard on workers in this downturn compared, say, to a lot
of European countries where the governments have just been paying employers to keep people on the
books. So one thing I could imagine is we've discussed that some industries may never come back.
Brick and mortar retail, it may come back some, but it'll never be like it was.
And I think the positive would be that the U.S. economy may be better at adjusting to such changes, that we are a dynamic economy. And so when there's an
opportunity, American firms are pretty quick to step in. But if you're going to be a dynamic
economy, you also need to think about how do you protect the people that may be harmed by all of that dynamism and don't move as easily from one industry to
another. And we have to have a way to protect them and make sure that they're able to keep
body and soul together and retrain for whatever new jobs are coming down the line.
I asked Romer to think back to the Great Recession and identify the mistakes that
she and her fellow Obama economic advisors made, or at least the ideas that didn't work out so well.
There are a couple. We had the making work pay tax credit. We thought rather than write people
checks and have them arrive in their mailbox or in their account. We would just slip it in. So it's just
going to show up in lower withholding. And we thought people would just notice they had more
money in their bank account. And maybe that would have a good effect on spending. As it turned out,
most people didn't seem to even know they got it. Or worse yet, they thought the Obama administration had raised their taxes, which they hadn't. We'd cut them by a lot. So that was one
that just didn't work as we'd anticipated. And was that a communication failure,
a perception failure? How did that happen? I think some of it was a communication failure. I think some of it, it turns out,
economic theory doesn't give us good insight. It's really, in some sense, a behavioral question.
Do people respond more if they see the check in their hands, or do they respond more if it
just shows up in their paycheck a little bit every month. And I think it was partly we were just learning.
There was another idea that looked good, but never gained traction.
We were trying a lot, especially in 2010, to think of another fiscal stimulus that maybe
would not be terribly expensive, but could have a big bang for the buck. So we were very interested in
a new hiring tax credit, a way to convince businesses to hire workers. And, you know,
we really did due diligence on this one. We ran surveys and we spun the CPS tapes.
CPS stands for Current Population Survey.
Just all the research we could think of,
we were just desperate to get them over the hump and ready to hire again. We ended up getting a
small kind of pilot program through Congress, but nothing on a big scale. So I'm not sure that we
ever learned whether this wouldn't work, but that was a policy that I was very excited about. So
maybe that's still something we could have in our
arsenal and try at some point. Romer also thought that more could be done around public employment,
which she thinks played a big part in the U.S. recovery from the Great Depression.
Because, you know, what Roosevelt was able to do of putting just millions of people directly on the government payroll, I think was
incredibly valuable. This is the WPA. WPA, the Civilian Conservation Corps. But in a modern
world, trying to figure out how to hire millions of people quickly is something that seems really hard. And I think it's something President Obama would have
liked to do. And we thought about it. We tried. I remember having a conversation with some other
cabinet secretaries. I'd say, if money was no object, how many people could you hire? And they'd
say, oh, lots, you know, 20, 30,000. Like, that's not going to do much when we've got millions and
millions of people unemployed. Why is it so hard? I mean, I realize you're talking about the federal
government hiring people versus private firms, but you have been extolling the virtues of our
nimble and robust capitalism, which can, you know, move fast, break things, hire and fire
lots and lots of people.
Why is it so hard for the federal government to do that?
I think partly we have different standards for the federal government.
So I think we try to do things probably more carefully.
Think about the Civilian Conservation Corps.
So that's the hiring program from the Depression that built a lot of
the buildings in our national parks and things like that. It hired mainly young men. It took
them out into the woods to build roads and log cabins. And it sent three quarters of their
paychecks home to their mothers. And it was, by all accounts, incredibly successful. And,
you know, I've met with some of these people that were on CCC projects.
They're now in their 80s and 90s.
And it was life transforming.
But can you imagine proposing that today of let's, you know, hire young men, send them
out to the woods and send their checks home to their parents?
That just, I think, is not in the modern American
way of doing things.
Right. But there are certainly modern equivalents. For instance,
one problem with dispersing aid money has been that it needs a lot of manpower.
One problem with contact tracing is it needs a lot of manpower. So is it really
so hard to imagine a kind of massive shift from private to
public hiring over the next couple of years? Because this is not going to go away. Unemployment
is not going, I assume, back to three, four, five percent anytime at all soon, right?
No, I agree. And so contact tracing is a great example. That is something that we ought to be able to use lots of people and put
them to use very, very fruitfully. I think even if you were to think about reasonable numbers,
I suspect that you're not going to be able to deal with the millions and millions of people
that are currently unemployed. I'll give you another example of one of the ideas I was thinking about back in 2009 was, you know, how about just a
massive program of hiring people to be teacher's aides. And I was really very taken with this
because so many of our public works jobs tend to be for, you know, construction workers, male often oriented jobs.
And I thought this was a great way to make sure that we were getting some balance and
something that might be particularly good for female employment in a tough time.
And we ran into a certain amount of opposition from, you know, think about local school districts
that are laying off teachers,
and you say, but I have this great program, I'm going to give you all these teachers' aides,
you know, they tended to say, what we really need is the money so we can keep our teachers employed.
So it is hard to figure out what's the right way to do this. And I came away thinking,
well, let's give more money to state and local government so
they're not laying off teachers and maybe they could hire the teacher's aides.
Okay. So if you are running some kind of economic SWAT team right now, let's imagine you were
running CEA now or National Economic Council or something to the equivalent, and you are trying to game plan the current recession or economic
doldrums. Do you look more to the Great Recession as the model, whether because it's more equivalent
in some ways and or just because it's more recent, or do you look more toward the Great Depression?
Where are you trying to draw your best inspiration from, both in terms of positive
moves and mistakes to be avoided?
I almost think we need to not look at either of them. In both those episodes or basically any other recession, the only problem is a lack of demand. And so just any policy you take
gets demand up. This is so different because it's a public health crisis and you're not going to get
demand up until you solve the public health crisis, nor do you want to because you don't
want every business producing at full capacity because then you have more workers than you
can actually keep safe.
So I think we really need to throw away some of our previous experience and focus more on what's unique about a pandemic and how do we actually deal with the public health problem.
So I think I would go much less, let's just get demand up.
Let's just give people tax cuts and much more.
Let's spend so that we solve
the public health crisis. I'd maybe take inspiration from other countries today that
have made more progress than we have, rather than looking back at previous US recessions.
We talked earlier about there's a dynamism to capitalism and
especially a dynamism to the way Americans do things. But there is a cost, which is because
we're laying off a lot of workers, the firm-employee link is being broken. And they're hard to get back. And it is hard to hire workers and get those right matches again. And so that's going to be costly. And that may tend to slow us down in the recovery process. firms that even if they survived COVID pretty well or are now returning to business, that
they are having a really hard time rehiring their own former employees because the unemployment
insurance and the other aid that people have been getting is really great.
And they can literally earn as much, if not more, by not going to work.
I know this was an early concern when the CARES
Act was being put together. It was largely dismissed as saying, hey, it's much better to
support individuals. If this is the downside, we'll live with it. But now,
there are employers who are living with it. What are your thoughts on that?
I think absolutely, in the initial stages, it was great to get more money into the hands of people who were struggling. And we do as a country have a terrible inequality problem. So giving 600 more dollars a week in benefits to a low wage worker, that really was a great thing to do. I think as the economy recovers, and you want
people to go back to work, you don't want them to just lose those funds, you know, to be worse off
if they go back to work. So can you give us some benefits, people have been talking about, you know,
reemployment bonuses, or things like that. I think it also comes back to, you know,
we've got a long run inequality problem, we should be dealing with that. At some point,
you don't want to be doing it through your unemployment system, you want to be doing it
in a more sensible way through your tax system or the earned income tax credit or, you know, better benefits in the form of
universal health insurance, things like that.
So one early and much cited paper of yours was about fiscal policy. And you argued that fiscal
policy during the depression didn't help the recovery all that much. And that finding of yours has been
interpreted over the years as an argument against fiscal intervention, which, as I read your work,
was not at all what you intended. So can you quickly summarize your actual finding and then
describe the misinterpretation, then we'll take it from there.
So the actual finding is if you look at what it was that helped the economy to recover from the Great Depression, the monetary actions that Roosevelt took when he came in were much more important.
That didn't have anything to do with whether fiscal policy could have been valuable.
It was just the fact that we didn't do all that much fiscal stimulus in the mid-1930s. And so it was
not the main driver of the recovery. Much of my subsequent work, and all of it joint with my
favorite co-author and also husband, David Romer, has actually been pointing out that fiscal policy
is very effective. So we have a paper looking at
the effects of tax changes. And if you cut people's taxes, it does help to stimulate the economy
in the short run. It helps you to increase demand and get an increase in output. We've looked at
the effect of transfer payments, and that too has a substantial positive effect on consumption.
So I think we've done some very important work saying that fiscal policy is really valuable. It
just turned out it was not used in a nearly aggressive enough way in the Depression to have
been a big factor accounting for that recovery. Although Roosevelt must have felt that he was
using a lot of fiscal stimulus, yes? It seemed like a lot at the time relative to what had been
done in the past. Oh, of course, right. And it was even a lot in an absolute amount in the sense that
the actions taken by the federal government were pretty substantial. But if you look at the total
fiscal situation for the U.S., because state and local governments were going in the opposite
direction of hunkering down, of actually raising taxes, cutting spending, the net fiscal stimulus
was pretty small because the states counteracted anything Roosevelt was doing on
the positive side. We should also say, this is tangential, but I can't let it pass without
saying that among your husband's most noteworthy research has to do not with depressions,
recessions, but with fourth down decisions in football.
True. He calls that one his midlife crisis paper. Even he would tell you
his most important work is on monetary and fiscal policy and financial crises. But I gather that
Bill Belichick read the paper and integrated it into his philosophy, yes? I believe he did read
the paper, but you'd have to talk to David about whether he listened to it enough.
Obviously, it is tangential to our conversation. And yeah, in some way, it's not, which is that
it was an empirical finding which argued that using the tools of economic analysis, you can
determine that almost all football coaches are playing fourth down wrong and that they should
punt much, much, much, much less than they do.
And yet it's been mostly ignored by all but maybe a handful of coaches.
Do you see equivalent empirical research done in the realm of fiscal or monetary policy that is demonstrably correct or at least worth considering among the tribe of economists
but is largely ignored by practitioners? One of the things that's been nice is that in a lot of macro research,
it actually has been the opposite of ignored, that policymakers have listened.
So I think especially central bankers have been very interested in academic research on the effectiveness of quantitative easing or the
impact of monetary policy or credit, things like that. So I think on the monetary side,
there is a lot of interest in research and learning from the research. On the fiscal side,
it's been a mixed bag. I feel there's a lot of professional research that fiscal policy can be very effective. When I was in the Obama administration, and certainly later in the Obama administration, when we desperately needed more fiscal stimulus, that was the moment when policymakers, especially Republican policymakers, decided that no, fiscal policy didn't do anything. But then part of what's happened over the last 10
years is there's just been paper after paper looking at what was done in the Recovery Act,
looking at what was done across countries in terms of their fiscal response to the Great Recession.
And those, again, almost uniformly find that fiscal policy is very effective. So I've taken a little bit of relief that facing this crisis, Congress said,
yeah, I guess we'll do it again. In fact, we'll do even more. So maybe policymakers are in fact
listening and realize that these things do help. I have to say, when I first started paying
attention to economics years ago, it was one of the things that most dispirited me because
I found that the greatest economists of the era were still debating the degree to which
fiscal policy during the depression either helped end the depression or, on the other hand,
exacerbated it. And I thought, well, wait, if these people can't tell us the answer to that
question, perhaps you're not very useful to us. I don't
mean to indict your whole tribe, but you're saying that you feel there has been more consensus,
at least on that kind of macro policy intervention in the last 10 or so years.
I do. I think if you look, say, at the University of Chicago's, their panel of experts, if you say, what did the Recovery Act do? Some very large fraction will say it absolutely was helpful.
We should say that's a survey that the UFC runs. It's not all University range of economists. So I think everyone wants to say, oh, economists all disagree.
I think you can always find somebody to take the other side. But it's often the case that
90% of economists believe one thing and 10% believe the other. And so the vast majority
would say monetary policy is very important. A vast majority would say if you cut people's
taxes, that will indeed stimulate the economy
in the short run.
Okay, so let's, in our remaining time, look at the future as best we can.
It's obviously unpredictable.
I'm curious, when you look at the policy that you see being considered and being made now,
fiscal and monetary
policy, and if you try to play it out in your mind, not just a few months from now, but a few
years, maybe many years from now, I'm especially curious if you think there are any lessons from
the depression in particular that we should be taking, especially when the cure turns out to be you know as dangerous as the ailment itself so one example
i think about this is not a perfect parallel but after the war when there were wage controls and
health insurance began to be offered as a fringe benefit and bundled with employment which is
something that most health economists say is one of the really difficult things about our healthcare system now. When you look at the policies being considered or made now,
what do you think we should watch out for? What might be some sad or difficult downstream effects?
The one that worries me is the budget deficit. So not in the immediate term, but if you think about how much money we're
spending, it's completely appropriate. We need to be doing it, but we are better at running budget
deficits than we are at dealing with them when the crisis has passed. And so if we keep dealing
with crises, but then not getting our fiscal house in order
afterwards, at some point, we're not even going to be able to deal with the crises because we will
have run our debt to GDP ratio up so high. We should have a plan to raise taxes eventually
to get back in a more sustainable system. I think the pandemic may well exacerbate
inequality, and that was already a terrible problem. So I think we need to be
getting through this, but also thinking about what do we do when we're through all this to make sure that we're sharing the benefits of this
amazing economy much more broadly, much more fairly.
I do feel compelled to point out that it's a little disorienting to speak to you, a Democratic
or Democratic-associated, at least, economist who is urging against a certain level of deficit spending, because we're used to
Republicans saying that, especially recently, Fed Chair Jerome Powell, he pledged to use what he
called the Fed's full range of tools to support the economy. And he also urged policymakers to
not worry so much about raising debt and instead to use what he called the great fiscal power of
the United States to get through
this with as little damage to the longer run productive capacity of the economy as possible.
So is this just a matter of the Republicans are in office now and you respond to the crisis in
front of you? Or has there been some kind of switching of direction for Democrats and
Republicans or economists who support them
when it comes to deficit spending? I want to be clear, I am wildly in favor of doing
the deficit spending that we're doing now. We need to do this. I agree completely with
Chair Powell that we should be doing anything we need to do to get the economy through this crisis.
But that doesn't mean that you don't think about the deficit. Even in 2010, we're not about to try
to deal with the deficit right then, but we were talking about it because you need a plan for three years, five years from now,
how do we deal with this? And perhaps because I believe so firmly that fiscal stimulus
is a crucially valuable tool, I want to make sure it's there the next time we face something like this. And so I think I've been very aware of
the need to, when you make it through a hard time and you're back in the good times,
that's when you repair the roof on your house. Right. So are we all going to come out of this
okay, do you think? I hope so. I mean, there are going to be some workers whose jobs disappear forever. We're not
just going to go back to the way we were. So I think we could all come out of this okay,
provided we take the policy actions that we need, we invest in the training to make sure everybody's okay. I worry that we'll get
through the worst of it, and then we'll forget about some of the people that have been hurt and
that remain struggling. And let's say that some of the changes that have happened thus far to
travel, to live entertainment, to restaurants, basically all of them wiped down
close to zero. Let's say that for a variety of reasons, they sort of stick and that people don't
return to them in large numbers, at least. Do you feel that the U.S. economy and our brand of
capitalism is still set up to be as vibrant and nimble to adjust and for people to job reallocate?
Or do you worry that a lot of
people in those industries, which employ millions and millions and millions of people, that they
will essentially be adrift, perhaps for a long time, unable to reallocate into commensurate jobs?
I think many of them will be able to reallocate. Again, I have a lot of faith in workers and in their ability to develop new skills and
find jobs when they're available.
I think they'll need a helping hand.
They'll need support in the period in which they are trying to learn a new skill. It also is going to be a lot easier for
25 or a 30-year-old worker than it's going to be for a 55 or a 60-year-old worker.
I sometimes think that this moment is, you know, that if you were looking at this from the future,
like an archaeologist looking at sediment, like the meteor that wiped out the dinosaurs ultimately,
that this is going to have a huge scarring effect on the world. And maybe I'm totally wrong,
but my sense is that this disruption has already led just about everybody to question
the way they live their life, the way they earn their living, the way they interact with
their families, the rest of society, community, and so on. When you look down the road, do you
think the world is fundamentally different? And if so, on what levels? Or do you think I'm maybe
being way melodramatic here? I'm perhaps not quite as dramatic as you, but I agree that this may set off a sea change.
I think you're right that we will probably trade less, travel less, work differently.
Whether it is a giant shift or just a moderate shift, I'm less sure.
But I think it is going to change things.
And I think the real question is how well we manage this. Do we manage it so that it changes
things, but we're all still okay? Or did it change things and make some of our underlying problems even worse?
But I guess, you know, you haven't yet taken the optimism out of me.
I still am hopeful that we can recover.
I mean, the history of this country is rising to challenges,
and I desperately hope that we do it again.
Coming up next time, a topic that didn't come up in today's conversation with Christina Romer,
but maybe should have, one of the most persistent economic problems in American history.
The racial wealth gap is such that the typical black family has about 10 cents on the dollar as a typical white family.
So are reparations the answer?
Will hear the arguments in favor?
The material redress would, in a retrospective way, bring about justice by affecting the racial wealth gap that we see today.
And the arguments against?
I think you're playing with words and avoiding the hard work of trying to
discover complex historical causal chains.
Also, several other ideas to address black-white wealth inequality.
That's next time on Freakonomics Radio.
Freakonomics Radio is produced by Stitcher and Dubner Productions. This episode was produced by Daphne Chen. Our staff also includes Allison
Craiglow, Greg Rippin, Matt Hickey, Zach Lipinski, Mary Duduk, and Corinne Wallace. Our intern is
Emma Terrell. We had help this week from James Foster. Our theme song is Mr. Fortune by the
Hitchhikers. All the other music was composed by Luis Guerra. You can get Freakonomics Radio on
any podcast app. If you want the entire back catalog, use the Stitcher app or go to
Freakonomics.com where we also publish transcripts and show notes. As always, thanks for listening.
Yeah. So the political costs, is that your dog or mine?
I think it's yours.
Do you have a dog?
I do not have a dog.
Okay, sorry.