Freakonomics Radio - 513. Should Public Transit Be Free?

Episode Date: August 25, 2022

It boosts economic opportunity and social mobility. It’s good for the environment. So why do we charge people to use it? The short answer: it’s complicated.  ...

Transcript
Discussion (0)
Starting point is 00:00:00 My name is Markus Fienbom, and I work as a traffic planner in Stockholm, Sweden. I understand that in a previous life, and maybe still in your current life, that you were a pretty devout, I don't know what's the best word for what you were, a transit protester, a transit anarchist? A public transit advocate, bringing more access to public transit for people. Can you just pronounce the name of the organization? Is it Planca? Planca. So it means fair dodge now. Talk about how you
Starting point is 00:00:35 dodge a fair. If it's a train, are there turnstiles that you have to jump, things like that? In the metro and the commuter trains, there were back then turnstiles. The turnstiles had a sensor. So if you just stretch your leg in, you would reach the sensor and it would open up and you would slide through. Marcus Fienbaum didn't just dodge fares himself and encourage others in Stockholm to do the same. He and his comrades at Plancka also had a scheme to mitigate the risk of fare dodging.
Starting point is 00:01:05 We mainly did this by organizing a solidarity fund. So if you got caught and you got a quite hefty fine, at the moment, I think it's somewhere in the vicinity of $150. The solidarity fund would pay this. So this is a group you join where you're not going to pay for the transit that you ride, but then you contribute to, it's kind of like an insurance fund, right? You contribute a little bit and if you get caught and get fined, the fund will pay it for you. Is that the way it works? You can say that. Yeah, for sure. Were you ever caught?
Starting point is 00:01:35 For sure. Yeah. How did it happen? The ticket controllers, they found it quite easy when someone were a member of Planka because we never got aggressive or tried to get away because like, OK, I got caught. Here's my ID. La la la. And they were like, oh, you're a member of Planca. OK, cool. Here's your ticket. It's a clever idea, this fair dodging insurance plan. But that wasn't Planca's only goal, or at least its primary one, they wanted to challenge the idea that anyone should pay for public transit. For Fienbaum, this gets at some bigger questions about the
Starting point is 00:02:11 relationship between transit and society. What kind of city do you want? Do you want one open and accessible for everyone? Or do you want one with barriers and borders that hinder some and makes life just more miserable for some. Marcus Feenbaum is not alone in asking such questions. There is a flourishing argument that public transit is good for the environment, good for economic opportunity and social mobility. Basically, good for everybody. Assuming that is all true, here's another question. Should public transit everywhere be free?
Starting point is 00:02:46 I cannot answer that without context. Today on Freakonomics Radio, one large that explores the hidden side of everything with your host, Stephen Dubner. If I were to ask you, let's say 10 years ago, which would you say was less likely? That the mayor of Boston would be Michelle Wu or that all public transit in Boston in, let's say, 2030 would be free? I'm not sure. Both would be completely impossible. So the first one we now know is not at all impossible. In your heart of hearts, what do you think about the second one? I think we can get to a free bus system. That would be transformational for our city's economy, climate, and opportunity.
Starting point is 00:04:01 That is Michelle Wu, and she is the mayor of Boston. She grew up in Chicago, came to Harvard for undergrad and law school, then served on Boston's city council for eight years before winning the mayoral election. As mayor, she wants to be aggressive. It's very easy to be just reactive in these roles. And we have to exercise every bit of planning and capacity and organizational muscle to be proactive. I keep a countdown clock, a little widget on my phone that shows me exactly how many days are left in the term because every single day should count. And we have to move at a pace that is closer to the urgency
Starting point is 00:04:46 in the communities as opposed to the usual pace of government. It's not just the pace of government Wu dislikes, it's how little risk they usually take on. If you maximize the chance that nothing will go wrong, then we won't get close to the scale of change and transformation that's needed. So in a 2019 Boston Globe op-ed, you were a city council member then, you wrote a piece titled Forget Fair Hikes, Make the T Free. The T being the Boston public transit system. It's the T in MBTA, which is the Massachusetts Bay Transportation Authority. Free public transportation, you argued, is the single biggest step we could take toward economic mobility, racial equity, and climate justice.
Starting point is 00:05:31 I read that now, even now, even knowing what you've been doing, and I say, wait, what the single biggest step? And I think before transportation, I, and look, I'm no mayor, I'm no city council person, but I would have thought the single biggest step might have been about early education or child care or health care or affordable housing. So why start there? Why start with free public transit? We know that the foundation for equitable access to opportunities is connectedness, the ability to get around. A 2015 longitudinal study of several hundred people that Harvard conducted showed that the factor most closely linked to a family's ability to rise out of poverty, in fact, wasn't the test scores of schools in the area. It wasn't the public safety statistics. In fact, it was the average commute time to work. So there's a relationship between transportation and particularly transportation infrastructure decisions and which communities have access to economic opportunity.
Starting point is 00:06:39 When I'm thinking it through, I'm thinking, well, even for low-income workers, transit fares just can't make up a very large share of income, especially compared to housing, child care, health care, and so on. So how much of the argument for free public transit is about actually helping people afford transportation versus all those other incentives, including lessening carbon emissions, lessening traffic, increasing mobility generally. Even if it feels like compared to your rent or the cost of food that the fare for the bus is smaller than that, it does add up. MIT helped lead a study here a number of years ago where a number of low-income families were given a 50% discounted fare card to the MBTA. And what we saw was that families
Starting point is 00:07:34 saw a significant increase in their MBTA usage, 30% more trips. And it turns out that people were using the transportation for basic life necessities to get to their medical appointments, to get to the grocery store, all things that they had previously been rationing because it was just one more cost that you had to undertake. New York City has means-tested transit discount, 50% off for people below a certain income, but Boston doesn't have that. So why not start there? Why go from zero all the way up to free transit for everybody? We are proud as a city to be home to the innovations that have shaped our society in many ways. We were the first to drop the prices for access to education, for example, or libraries or parks, and we're still home to the first public school in the country,
Starting point is 00:08:31 the first public library, the first public park at Boston Common. All ways in which we recognize that by investing in our shared destinies, our common wealth, that we are all better off. And so in line with that vision, public transportation is just as fundamental. To get there, it's not going to happen overnight. And there are different starting points. So I have been very forcefully supportive of a means-tested discount program as one step in the right direction. Free buses are the ideal place where we would capture so much of this value. It's a place where we see the widest inequities across our transit system in Boston,
Starting point is 00:09:12 64 hours more per year that black bus riders spend on city buses compared to white riders, because those routes tend to be longer, stuck in traffic more. This is also a place where the act of paying slows down the service because people are lining up, digging out their wallets, uncrinkling the bills. So that's the ideal place to start. If Boston were to eliminate transit fares, it would become the biggest American city to do so. Michelle Wu would therefore steal those bragging rights from this man. Robbie Mackinnon, I'm president and CEO of the Kansas City Area Transportation Authority. Actually, Mackinnon is now the former president and CEO. He left his job not long after we spoke
Starting point is 00:10:03 with him. But on his watch, Kansas City, Missouri became the first major city in the U.S. to make the move to free public transit. We didn't just flip a switch and say, hey, everything's free. We did a methodical, strategic process. We first made transit zero fare for our veterans. All you had to do was show your veterans card and come on board. Next, we went to the school districts, and we said if a child wanted to stay after school for a chess club or football or whatever, and they missed that one yellow bus at 530 to get home, well, then what was going to happen? Mom would have to come get them, or they'd have to walk.
Starting point is 00:10:40 So just giving them access to public transit was a big deal, and they enjoyed that. The third step was we went to our safety net providers, mental health agencies, domestic violence shelters. So by the time we got to where we were going to flip the switch to make zero fare throughout the region, we were already 60% there. Now, you may be asking yourself, when a transit agency stops charging its passengers, where does the money come from to run the system, to buy and maintain buses and trains, to pay drivers and other employees? We have a $100 million budget. Less than 10% of that we were getting from the fare box. Among transit people, this is called the farebox recovery ratio, and it varies a lot
Starting point is 00:11:26 from place to place. Here is Brian Taylor, a transportation scholar at UCLA. People often may not have an idea of how much the fare they pay goes for the cost of transit. Nationwide, fares cover about a third of the operating costs of a system, but they don't cover any of the capital costs. So the buses, the trains, the equipment, the stations are all paid for with federal grants. And the cost of operating the service, the operators, the drivers and the mechanics, fuel, tires, wear and tear, things like that, about a third of that is covered out of fares and about two-thirds by government subsidies. But as we said, the fare box recovery ratio can vary from place to place.
Starting point is 00:12:10 Consider the numbers for two big California transit systems, Los Angeles Metro and BART, or Bay Area Rapid Transit. L.A. Metro is down in the teens, where BART is closer to 50%. And remember what Robbie Mackinnon told us about the $100 million transit budget in Kansas City. Less than 10% of that we were getting from the fare box. Meaning the vast majority of the operating costs were coming from federal, state, and local funding. And if you're down that low from a fare box recovery standpoint,
Starting point is 00:12:43 you cannot tell me that I couldn't walk in there and find that 10%. You can't tell me there's not a way to help the folks that need it the most. Who need it the most financially, he means. The demographic makeup of public transit ridership also varies from place to place, depending on the geography, economics, even the history of a given city. In places like San Francisco and Boston and New York, traveling by car is time-consuming and expensive. Therefore, more middle and high-income people in those places use public transit. In Kansas City, meanwhile, where driving is easier and cheaper, there's a much larger share of low-income transit passengers. And to me, charging a fare is a regressive tax on the people who need it the most.
Starting point is 00:13:31 When we started down this road, everybody wants to go back to some study that was done in 19-whatever-the-hell, excuse my language. Everybody said, oh my gosh, you can't do it. Society's going to break down. You know, crime everywhere, cats living with dogs, mass hysteria. That's what's going to happen. Well, let, crime everywhere, cats living with dogs, mass hysteria. That's what's going to happen. Well, let me tell you, exactly the opposite happened here in Kansas City. And I'm going to tell you why. Over 75% of any incident we ever had on a vehicle was over a fare box dispute. Okay? Think about that. And since we took the fairway, we've had less than 20 incidents out of, you know, 10 to 13 million rides. That's fantastic.
Starting point is 00:14:10 And then the other part was they said, yeah, but now the houseless folks are just going to get on and stay on and live on your vehicles. Well, you know what? First of all, there but by the grace of God go I and you, right? These folks are people and they're just people that need help. So what we've done is invent a pilot program where some of the homeless providers are putting case management teams on our vehicles based upon heat maps of where we need the most help and they can help them get to the shelters and the services that they can actually use, rather than just putting more, you know, police with guns on a vehicle. Once Kansas City went fare free,
Starting point is 00:14:51 Mackinnon and his transit agency did have to make up a $9 million budget shortfall. They're getting $5 million from the municipal government and using federal COVID relief funds to cover the rest. But that money will run out soon. And with Mackinnon, the program's main champion, out of his job, the future of free transit in Kansas City is uncertain. The agency says it is pursuing other sources of revenue, but advocates of free transit like to point out that
Starting point is 00:15:20 eliminating fares can actually save money by saving time. Here again is Boston Mayor Michelle Wu. We've already seen significant operational savings from the cost efficiencies of making our routes run faster. Earlier this year, Wu helped start a pilot program that eliminated fares on three bus lines that serve lower income areas, routes 23, 28, and 29. And you save some of the costs of fare collection. So when you do a net accounting on the enforcement and fare collection costs versus free fares on those three lines, where do you come out?
Starting point is 00:16:00 In some ways, there's an elasticity question. How much are more people riding because the price has changed? The estimate across the entire bus system previously was that it would be about a $29 million cost savings in the fuel and all the efficiencies from speeding along bus service with all-door boarding. But is that at a steady state? Because theoretically, if you're inducing demand by making it free, right, so now you need more buses, more drivers, more depots for those buses and so on, yes? Yes. And that's part of what we're trying to measure with this pilot. The pilot so far has been just a number of months, but what we did see was that relative to other bus lines that did not have free fares,
Starting point is 00:16:53 the ridership of the 28 bus was about 92% of ridership pre-pandemic. That is compared to most bus lines at 50 percent, 30 percent. This is all starting to sound pretty convincing in favor of fare-free transit. You've got easier and cheaper access for passengers, especially low-income passengers. You've got fewer private cars, theoretically at least, and the congestion and pollution they create. Even the price tag sounds manageable. There's also the fact that even in places that don't have free transit, like New York City, a lot of passengers aren't paying anyway.
Starting point is 00:17:34 A nonprofit news organization called The City recently reported that nearly a third of all New York bus passengers fail to pay the fare, with that number rising above 50% in the Bronx. These free riders either board through the back doors or just walk past the driver without paying. The driver's union says that drivers risk being assaulted if they try to collect the fare. The head of New York's transit agency acknowledges that passengers who do pay feel like suckers. So coming up after the break, does all this mean that transit should just be free in New York and maybe everywhere? Just saying generally make it fare free for everything, for all types of trips,
Starting point is 00:18:15 I would not agree with it. I'm Stephen Dubner. This is Freakonomics Radio. We'll be right back. The thing about transportation is that everybody does it, and so everyone thinks they're an expert at it. That, again, is Brian Taylor. I go to a party and people come up and say, you know what they ought to do? They ought to put a monorail down the middle of the freeway. And I said, what are you doing? They said, well, I'm a cardiologist. I said, you know what you ought to do? You ought to do more angioplasties and less coronary artery bypass. They said, well, why do you say that? I said, well, I have as much expertise in cardiology as you do in transportation. I have a heart.
Starting point is 00:19:05 So what are Taylor's transportation credentials? I'm a professor of urban planning and public policy, and I direct the Institute of Transportation Studies at UCLA. Let me ask you to just brag for a minute, Brian. The UCLA Institute of Transportation Studies is to transportation studies as blank is to blank. The Yankees to baseball, maybe? It's one of four branches in the UC system. So there's a branch at UC Berkeley, UC Davis,
Starting point is 00:19:33 UC Irvine, and the one at UCLA. The four branches together are pretty unambiguously the premier transportation research institution in the world. What are you actually trying to accomplish with this research? I try to make it difficult for public officials to make bad decisions. So there are a lot of things about transportation that are counterintuitive. And because of that, it's a challenge to explain to
Starting point is 00:19:57 members of the media, to elected officials who have to make decisions, to members of the lay public, because so many things seem obvious, which aren't. Like widening a road will get rid of congestion, for example. There's a name for that, right? Brazes paradox or something? Yeah, it's basically the idea of latent demand. There's a demand for the use of the roadway, and the congestion increases the time cost of travel, so it raises the price of travel. When you add capacity, in the short term, that congestion goes down, the time cost of travel goes down,
Starting point is 00:20:29 and so it becomes cheaper to travel on that roadway from the user's perspective, and they fill it up until the price brings it back into equilibrium. It fits very consistently with economic theory, but the idea that demand is somehow fixed is something that people assume. They can't imagine that people's demand changes. If this paradox exists with new lanes of a highway, does it exist with public transport as well? There's this idea of elasticity. When there's a change in price, how do users respond? If it's very elastic, a change in price causes a big change in behavior. If it's inelastic, a change in price elicits a small change in behavior. In this case, we can think about price elasticity,
Starting point is 00:21:09 which is if the fare goes down to zero or goes up. And we can also think about service elasticity. So if the service becomes more frequent, people don't have to wait as long. And it turns out that people are at least as service elastic as they are price elastic. Okay, let's do a thought experiment. Imagine you run a big city transit agency and you get a financial windfall, maybe a couple hundred million dollars from a federal COVID relief fund. Considering what Brian Taylor just told us, that people are at least as service elastic as they are price elastic, how do you want to spend that windfall?
Starting point is 00:21:55 One thing we could spend it on is making the service free to everyone, and that might encourage more people to ride. Another thing we could do is to have more frequent service, and we know that people hate to wait, and that more frequent service would also encourage people to ride. What do you know about the pilot program in Boston for free buses and Mayor Wu's desire to expand that over time? They found that there was an increase in ridership as a result of the fare-free in comparison to other services that were similar in their operating characteristics. One of the things I want you to notice about that evaluation is what the writers commented on. The most frequent positive comment was that it sped boarding and alighting and increased service reliability. Okay, remember I was talking about how people are very service elastic? They really like reliable service.
Starting point is 00:22:41 We know that people wait wait time. They W-E-I-G-H-T-W-A-I-T time, at about one and a half to four and a half times in vehicle time. So let's just call it three times. That means if you wait 10 minutes for a bus, in your perception of the burden of that trip, you waited it like it was a half hour. So what I would say is that experiment tells us both that people responded to the free fare, they also responded to the fact that the boarding and alighting times are faster. If you have systems where people are fumbling in their pocket and uncrumpling dollar bills and sliding them in, that takes time. And that brings us to a thing about the way we charge for fares.
Starting point is 00:23:34 Ah, the way we charge for fares. This is one of Brian Taylor's pet peeves about public transit. A few years ago, he took his daughter to Boston to look at colleges. We did not wonder how we would pay for the hotel we stayed in. When we walked into a restaurant, we didn't say, do you take cash or credit cards or what? How will we pay for this? There was no uncertainty. But when it came to the public transit in Boston, we walked out to get on the T, and I'm someone who works in this field, we had no idea what to do. Absolutely no idea what to do. There was eight-point type laying out all of the fair policies. And I needed to go to a convenience store and buy a card.
Starting point is 00:24:12 Could I pay cash? I didn't know. There was confusion. Why public transit? Should it be so complicated and difficult to figure it out? I have cards from Sydney, Australia, from Brisbane, from London, from Tokyo, from Shanghai, all of which are different, all of which have different rules. To be fair, some of these places are much easier than others, and some use technology better, including, and this may surprise you, New York City. In New York recently, I was visiting my daughters. I used Google Pay to use the train.
Starting point is 00:24:44 What a breakthrough that was. So why don't all transit systems let you just use an app on your phone to pay? The problem is, because public transit is publicly owned and operated, and we see as our goal to give mobility to everyone, not everyone has access to a smartphone or to a credit card. So in our efforts to try and be as inclusive as possible, we end up making paying to and be as inclusive as possible, we end up making paying to use transit as confusing as possible. And that's a serious problem.
Starting point is 00:25:12 In one sentence, is free or as people like you call it, fair free public transit, a good idea or a bad idea on balance? I cannot answer that without context. First of all, I'm an academic, so don't ask an academic. What I can tell you, I'll just give you a very clear example. BART in the San Francisco Bay Area going into downtown San Francisco, those peak hour, peak direction commuters that is going downtown in the morning have higher incomes than the average driver. So you're saying making public transit free for those commuters doesn't make a lot of sense. First of all, they're not that price sensitive.
Starting point is 00:25:45 And secondly, it's just transferring a benefit to very high income commuters. On the other hand, local bus service in Lubbock, Texas, the users are almost uniformly low income. There, fare-free transit is essentially a transfer to lower income disadvantaged populations. Just saying generally make it fare-free for everything, for all types of trips, I would not agree with that. Okay, so that context is noted and appreciated, but it sounds as though one simple adjustment might be, hey, let's just make it means tested.
Starting point is 00:26:17 We do means testing for a lot of things in society. Is that a sensible way to think about public transit? Fare free public transit for, let's say, students and seniors, which a lot of places already overcome, and you may end up excluding people that you ought to help. On the other hand, the question is, do we need to give something valuable away to rich people for free on the argument that we want to help low-income people? The more you talk, the more complicated fare-free public transit. Isn't it great? Coming up, as we consider free public transit, we also need to ask, where do cars fit into all this?
Starting point is 00:27:16 I want to make driving great, but rare. And if you want to hear some earlier Freakonomics Radio shows about transportation, I would suggest episode 454, Should Traffic Lights Be Abolished? Episode 165, The Perfect Crime, which is about how easy it is as a driver to hit a pedestrian and get away with it. And episode 118, Parking is Hell. If none of those appeal to you, check out the other shows in the Freakonomics Radio Network. There's People I Mostly Admire, hosted by my Freakonomics friend and co-author Steve Levitt, Freakonomics MD, hosted by Bapu Jenna, and No Stupid Questions, hosted by Angela Duckworth and me, Stephen Dubner. You can get all our podcasts on any app for free. We will be right back. I think we often talk about economics and policy and
Starting point is 00:28:18 decision-making through data and graphs, and that's all really important. That, again, is Michelle Wu, the mayor of Boston. But it's really hard to actually conceptualize what this means for people unless you experience it directly, unless you are a daily commuter or need to get to work with a big double stroller with two little children under the age of three in it on our public transportation system. Wu wants to make public transit in Boston free. Fair free transportation is funding public transportation as a public good and recognizing the right to mobility for every person to belong
Starting point is 00:29:00 in every space and to be able to benefit from all that our city has to offer. So that's Wu's argument for Boston. But again, different places have different transportation needs and styles. The thing to understand about public transit is that public transit is very context specific. And that, again, is Brian Taylor, a transportation researcher at UCLA. We operate public transit in places like Bakersfield, California, and Tulsa, Oklahoma, and its relative utility compared to private vehicles is a fraction of driving, because the environment in those places is around rewarding having an automobile and punishing its absence. So when we talk about public transit,
Starting point is 00:29:45 abstracting it from the environment within which it operates is almost meaningless. Overall, the use of public transit is highly asymmetric. That is, it's not everybody rides a little bit. A very small share of the population rides a lot. Another chunk of the population rides occasionally, and most people don't ride at all. The thing you have to understand about public transit is there's New York and everything else. And in fact, I just reviewed an academic paper where they simply held New York out of the equation
Starting point is 00:30:15 because New York accounts for about four out of ten transit trips in the entire United States. There was a period where New York was gaining riders during a boom time a decade or so ago, and much of the country was losing riders. But it appeared, if you looked at the top line figures, that public transit was doing very well. New York was so big, it could by itself move the needle. Not long ago, Taylor and his colleagues were approached by the Southern California Association of Governments to figure out another drop in transit ridership. Los Angeles, Southern California, in fact the state, was on a pretty good run of increasing investment in public transit and rolled out a lot of new rail lines, improved bus service, and yet ridership was eroding at an accelerating rate.
Starting point is 00:31:05 What'd they figure out? There were many factors associated with eroding ridership, but the most important one was that households with no access to motor vehicles were gaining access to motor vehicles. You had lots of low-income households, immigrant households that were quite low-income that over time the economy had been doing reasonably well, and people were accumulating assets. And among those assets were motor vehicles. And even in middle and higher income households, you were going from one vehicle and two adults to two vehicles and two adults. Were there other factors that drove the decrease in California public transit use? There's evidence that the rise of Uber and Lyft had some effect, but it was relatively
Starting point is 00:31:47 modest. If one reason to have really great public transit is to increase mobility generally, and I don't know of a single economist or other social scientist, any scientist who doesn't think that increasing access to mobility at least is a really good thing. Rather than building these monstrously expensive public transit systems, would it just make more sense to buy cars for low-income people? I have another colleague who has gotten herself a lot of trouble over the years doing research showing that when low-income households get access to automobiles, all sorts of good things happen. The colleague he's referring to is, in fact, his wife, Evelyn Blumenberg, another transit scholar at UCLA.
Starting point is 00:32:30 Better access to food, better access to health care, to education, which many concerned about the problems of dependence on automobiles chafe against that and say, well, that's a problem. Her response is that we shouldn't balance our environmental policy on keeping poor people out of cars. You all have spent the last century building cities around automobile travel. Why should it surprise you that when low-income people get access to cars, they're better off? We can say that low-income travelers drive who says, hey, we need to do much less subsidizing and encouraging of car travel and more subsidizing and encouraging of public transit? Well, the question is, do we need to subsidize travel to use economist parlance if we properly priced automobile use? The need to subsidize transit would go down a lot because the demand for transit would go up a lot.
Starting point is 00:33:30 Imagine for a minute that Pete Buttigieg decided the transportation department is just too boring. He wants something saucier and he steps down and you, Brian Taylor, are immediately installed as Secretary of Transportation. Give me your top, let's say, five priorities. Well, first, my opinion of President Biden would probably slip a little if he made that choice. We have to think about climate change. You have to think about access by people who are disadvantaged.
Starting point is 00:34:00 Those would be two really important things. I think the third thing would be related to our ability to cope with shocks, wildfires in the West, pandemics, sea level rise, things like that. And I would certainly try to manage private vehicle travel. I want to make driving great, but rare. So, Secretary Taylor, I did not hear you name public transit at all, and especially fare-free public transit. What number on your list might that come in? To me, right now, the problem with public transit is the problem we have with cars. In fact, in the United States, we're investing more in public transit. And that's all for the good, except that it's undermined by policies that keep trying to make it easier and cheaper to drive. And now we say, OK, well, we're not going to make drivers responsible for the costs they impose on society. Let's see if we can make it even cheaper to go on public transit.
Starting point is 00:34:59 When Taylor says that we don't make drivers responsible for the costs they impose on society. He's really talking about two things. The first is that car travel produces a lot of what economists call negative externalities, things like pollution and congestion and accident risk that are not priced into the cost of travel. But there's also the fact that most of our roads are essentially free. They aren't priced according to supply or demand. The argument forever has been that you can't price for roads because it's a public good, and that's fundamentally not true. That is Shashi Verma, a longtime senior executive at Transport for London,
Starting point is 00:35:38 which oversees pretty much the entire transportation network in London, including the roadways. And some of those roadways now cost a lot of money to use. The congestion charge came in 2003 to discourage people from driving into central London. The congestion charge today means it will cost you 15 pounds to drive into central London during the day. It's estimated this has helped reduce roadside emissions there by up to 44%.
Starting point is 00:36:06 If you can get cars out of the way and get more buses on the road, that is an overall benefit for society. It's also a benefit for all the other things for which roads need to be used, which nobody would ever argue against. You wouldn't want to be in an ambulance caught up in traffic. So did congestion pricing in London increase public transit use? That question is not so easy to answer. It's very difficult to distinguish between the effect of the congestion charge versus other improvements we were making on buses. That's because at the same time congestion pricing came online for private vehicles. We were improving the quality of the bus network to give people an alternative anyway. That made it hard for researchers to isolate the effect of congestion pricing.
Starting point is 00:36:53 Still, if you look at things in the aggregate. The aggregate impact of all of those things was that bus ridership increased by 60%, six zero percent in a sixyear period from 2000 to 2006. Does this mean the key to increasing public transit everywhere is just to make driving painfully expensive? The negative incentive is very much on driving. But the answer cannot be, well, we've started charging you and go to the public transport system that already exists,
Starting point is 00:37:22 which is now going to become worse because there are more people using it. That cannot be the answer. So the two things, the incentive and the disincentive, have to go hand in hand. If you tell people you can't use your cars, you also have to give them an alternative. People won't start using public transit unless they have actual access to it. And that, again, is Markus Finbom, the Swedish traffic planner who used to be a fare dodger. By decreasing the cost of public transit and at the same time increasing the cost of car, you will definitely switch riders. One really good example is when they introduced the congestion fees in the Stockholm region here.
Starting point is 00:38:05 At the same time, they built a lot of park and ride systems. So if you lived in the outer parts of the region, you would take your car and park it and then take one of the new express buses directly into the city. And at the same time, they also introduced a one zone system. With just two dollars, you could jump on the bus from anywhere. And this really increased the attractiveness of the public transit. And if you compare this with when they introduced the congestion fees in Gothenburg, it was quite contested. Gothenburg is Sweden's second biggest city after Stockholm. And it's the main port city of Sweden as well. And they did not put as much resources into getting new access to public transit. So it just made car ridership more expensive. And this got people really, really angry and actually shifted the whole political situation in the local parliament in Gothenburg. The ruling party lost power. It had a big effect. Brian Taylor from UCLA has also
Starting point is 00:39:06 looked at the relationship between congestion pricing and public transit in Sweden. If you've ever been in Stockholm, it's shocking. Public transit gets around very quickly and easily. People do drive there, but the streets aren't packed with traffic. You can choose to drive in and out of central Stockholm, but you have to pay for it. And because of that, when you can take public transit or bike or walk or travel by some other means, people do it. So it's not that it's an unpleasant place to drive. It's that it's an expensive place to drive. It's the same thing as flying over Thanksgiving or Christmas or staying at a hotel during peak holiday periods. The price goes up and down to bring supply and demand in line.
Starting point is 00:39:46 Otherwise, we just have people queuing up, and that's what we do now. What do you know about what you call mode change when transit systems are either improved or made free? If there are new riders, where are they coming from? Are they people who were walking and biking? Are they drivers? Because that's kind of the environmental dream, right? That you take all these people clogging up the roads in cars, making pollution in cars,
Starting point is 00:40:09 and convert them to public transit. Does that actually happen? So that's a great question, and it gets to what is the goal of public transit. I talked about those two markets for transit, people who, because of age, income, or disability, don't have the ability to drive, and people traveling to places where parking is difficult or expensive. The latter group is more affluent. The former group is poor. That first group is transit's dirty little secret. The idea that it was providing an absolutely critical social service, a redistributive social service, is not something that you advertised to voters because that kind of a role didn't get as much support to saying, hey, we're going to provide an alternative to driving that's going to help to deal with
Starting point is 00:40:52 congestion, it's going to deal with environmental pollution, it's going to help slow climate change, that has broader appeal. So those are two different goals. They're sometimes congruent, but sometimes they're at odds. I think that's an important thing that your listeners think about is this opportunity cost of spending money to eliminate fares. Could we do things with that money that riders might value even more than a free ride? I would think that anyone before embarking on a fare-free program ought to ask that question, and the answer could be no.
Starting point is 00:41:23 But it could be yes. The equity arguments are strong. But we have to remember that what the characteristics of the ridership in the system are tell us a lot about who's going to benefit most from fare free. It sounds to me like the median person given a choice between taking a subway, commuter train or bus would much rather drive their car. Is that a true statement? Well, again, it depends on context. The Onion, the humor magazine, a while ago had an article that said, voters favor increased funding to public transit so that
Starting point is 00:41:59 others will use it and get off the road so they can drive better. So a colleague of mine, Michael Manville, essentially studied that question and he empirically supported the onion headline. And that is, in fact, why people vote for it, thinking that I'm not going to change my behavior, but other people might, and it'll make driving easier for me. So the question again comes back to, we are not managing automobile use
Starting point is 00:42:24 and we're trying to change pricing. And so what that means is that we may get benefit from fair free transit and that benefit's going to be more in terms of social equity benefits than environmental benefits. Well, that's a good thing on its own. But if the argument is that
Starting point is 00:42:38 this is going to reduce automobile dependence, that is likely to have modest effects at best. What do you think about this wrestling match between public transit and private automobiles? Your answer probably depends on where you live, maybe how old you are, how much you like your car, if you have one. Thank you so much to Brian Taylor, Marcus Feenbaum, Michelle Wu, Robbie Mackinnon, and Shashi Verma for helping us wrestle with this topic. Let us know what you thought. We are at radio at freakonomics.com, and we love feedback. Coming up next time on the show, we speak with the controversial Harvard economist Roland Fryer about his life's work.
Starting point is 00:43:25 Trying to make Black America happier, wealthier, healthier, more educated. That's all I've ever tried to do. And I refuse to lie to them. We'll hear about his research on policing. I had a five-hour meeting with Obama and activists and other folks. And we got zero done. On education. There's real pushback on incentive programs in schools by lots of folks.
Starting point is 00:43:51 And we'll hear about Friar's personal controversy, including a two-year suspension by Harvard. I broke a lot of glass early on in my career, and I don't think that was helpful. That's next time on the show. Until then, take care of yourself, and if you can, someone else, too. Freakonomics Radio is produced by Stitcher and Renbud Radio. You can find our
Starting point is 00:44:14 entire archive on any podcast app. This episode was produced by Ryan Kelly. We had research help from Samantha Resnick. Our staff also includes Neil Carruth, Gabriel Roth, Greg Rippin, Zach Lipinski, Rebecca Lee Douglas, Julie Canfor, Morgan Levy, Eleanor Osborne, Jeremy Johnston, Jasmine Klinger, Emma Terrell, Lyric Bowditch, Jacob Clemente, and Alina Kullman. Our theme song is Mr. Fortune by The Hitchhikers. All the other music was composed by Luis Guerra. If you would like to read a transcript or take a look at the underlying research of this or any episode, that is all at Freakonomics.com. Or you can also sign up for our newsletter. As always, thanks for listening. When you joined, was it still in the hooligan and criminal phase or more in the voice for another way of looking at transit phase? In the eyes of the public transit agency, definitely still is the first one. Freakonomics Radio Network, the hidden side of everything. Stitcher

There aren't comments yet for this episode. Click on any sentence in the transcript to leave a comment.