Freakonomics Radio - 525. In Search of the Real Adam Smith
Episode Date: December 8, 2022How did an affable 18th-century “moral philosopher” become the patron saint of cutthroat capitalism? Does “the invisible hand” mean what everyone thinks it does? We travel to Smith’s hometow...n in Scotland to uncover the man behind the myth. (Part 1 of a series.)
Transcript
Discussion (0)
The story we are beginning today is a story about one man, but it's also a story about
the whole world.
This one man happens to be an 18th century economist.
I hope that doesn't kill your interest because this is a good story.
This economist was born in Scotland in 1723.
Next year will mark the 300th anniversary of his birth.
But his ideas are still incredibly powerful today.
Why?
There's many reasons his thinking was powerful.
Interestingly, not the reason that most people think.
He did think like an economist.
He believes in free markets and a free society.
There's no getting around that.
But he was much more than that.
He forces you to look at yourself
and realize what makes you tick,
what pushes your buttons, rings your bells,
tightens your shoelaces.
Here is a sentence he once wrote
which may tighten your shoelaces.
Man naturally desires not only to be loved,
but to be lovely.
He was himself a lovely man.
He always had lots of friends.
He was a good-natured guy, very easy to get along with.
He did have quirks.
Very absent-minded, mumbling to himself, not really paying attention to what's going on.
But it was his ideas that mattered, and his ideas have reverberated.
It means if you work hard, you should make a decent living.
If you work hard, you should be able to support a family.
His ideas have been interpreted.
In the economic market, people who intend to serve only their own private interests
are led by an invisible hand to serve public interests that it was no part of their intention to promote. And they've been reinterpreted.
He certainly influenced Mrs. Thatcher.
Today, people are quite sure they know exactly who he was.
He was like the father or the founder of capitalism.
Father of, let's say, fair capitalism.
The father of economics. I do kind of groan a let's say, fair capitalism. The father of economics.
I do kind of groan a little when people say,
oh, founding father of economics.
There's more to him than that.
His name, by the way, is Adam Smith.
It's a pretty generic name, but the man was quite singular.
He worried about the ways that wealth
and an emphasis on material goods
can corrupt people's moral sentiments.
The theory of moral sentiments, the wealth of nations. Those were the books Adam Smith
left behind. Today on Freakonomics Radio, let's take a trip to see what else he left behind.
What we're looking at is where Adam Smith's house was.
Come with us in search of the real Adam Smith. Like I said, it's a good
story. And this is the first episode in what we think will be a three-part series. It begins right This is Freakonomics Radio, the podcast that explores the hidden side of everything, with your host, Stephen Dubner. If you know anything at all about Adam Smith,
it probably comes from his second and most famous book, The Wealth of Nations.
Full title, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.
It is a big book with annotated editions running more than a thousand pages.
It's not the wealth of individuals, it's the wealth of nations, right?
You may have also heard
Smith's most famous phrase,
the invisible hand,
which his disciples used to describe
how the economy should work.
They picked out the phrase,
the invisible hand,
which he uses just two or three times
and made that the central feature
of who Smith was.
And maybe you have read
some of Smith's first book,
The Theory of Moral Sentiments,
but probably not. I thought, well, I don't have to read this because it's not economics,
it's philosophy or psychology, you could call it. And I didn't read it forever. Most economists
don't. That first book, the one no one reads, it is essentially a call for what many modern liberals say they most believe in, sympathy.
The second book, the famous one, is a call for what many modern conservatives say they most believe in,
a free market economy with less government involvement.
Since most political people aren't willing to hold two potentially conflicting ideas in their mind at the same time,
or even ever,
they often simply ignore the idea they don't like. In the case of Adam Smith, the conservatives have
done a much better job of late promoting his views than have the liberals. Liberals tend to disparage
free market Smith without offering sympathetic Smith as balance. Both sides have turned him into
a caricature. Here's something the economic historian Robert Heilbronner once wrote.
No economist's name is more frequently invoked than that of Adam Smith, and no economist's works
are less frequently read. Obviously, that's an exaggeration. There are plenty of dead economists
that no one reads, but
you get the point. This brilliant and sympathetic man has been turned into a cardboard cutout.
Our mission today is to try to turn the cardboard cutout back into the real Adam Smith. So let's
begin at the beginning. Adam Smith was born in 1723 in Kirkcaldy, Scotland.
So you have to pronounce it Kirkcaldy. Kirkcaldy.
Sorry. Adam Smith was born in 1723 in Kirkcaldy, Scotland.
It's a small port city on the east coast in Fife County.
It lies just across the Firth of Forth from Edinburgh.
We are now approaching Kirkcaldy. Please mind the gap when alighting from this train.
We were meeting up with another Kirkcaldy native. His name is John Ewell.
Stephen, pleased to meet you.
Very pleased to meet you, John.
It's a pleasure. It's wonderful to have you here. Kirkcaldy, my hometown.
Born and raised?
Not born. I was born in Edinburgh, but raised in Kirkcaldy.
Yule is in his mid-70s. He's an actor and a playwright. One of his plays is called The
Invisible Hand. It's about the life and times of Adam Smith. It is a work of history, but also
a work of John Yule's imagination.
I get thrilled by this. I'm not an academic. I'm not an economist. I
concluded that Smith's just been misunderstood. Okay, so where are we going first? We're going
to the old Kirk where Adam Smith was baptized. A Kirk being Scottish for church. Yeah, old,
old stuff. How old is Kirk Cuddy? Oh, it's old. It was just one long town from the harbour along a stretch just along the coast.
And the industry back then, or how did people make a living? Fishing?
Fishing, salt, mining, a lot of mining.
Places riddled with coal mining.
And trade.
Trade was important to Kirkcaldy, and it would turn out to be very important to Adam Smith.
Now we are approaching the old church.
George, I hope you haven't been waiting there.
George, I'm Stephen. Good to meet you.
George, pray for you.
How do you do?
George Proudfoot is chair of the Kirkcaldy Civic Society and director of the Adam Smith Global Foundation.
Once we get inside the church, we also meet Rosemary Potter.
I'm the chair of the trust that owns the old Kirk now.
We're visiting on a Monday morning, but lucky for us,
the church organist has come in to practice.
So this is where Adam Smith begins.
He was baptized.
The only reason we know his tercentenary is next year
is because of the record in the church here
that he was baptized on the 5th of June.
We're in the 1807 part of the church.
The new part.
The new part, but the part that Adam Smith would have known
and would have come through is the tower,
which is 15th century.
That's the pulpit.
So he would have been baptised in the front of the church.
And you've got the graveyard,
or what you call the kirkyard, outside.
Are any of his relatives, maybe his father, buried there?
That we do not know because there's no records from that date that were lost.
They were lost in a ship.
In a ship? Why were the church records in a ship?
They were taking them over to Edinburgh. So we don't know if they were in that
or if they were just not recorded. We don't know.
Okay, so what do we know about Adam Smith and his family?
His father, Adam Smith Sr., died shortly before Adam was born.
He had worked at the port in Kirkcaldy as a customs agent, essentially a tax collector.
His death did not throw the Smiths into poverty, as Adam's mother came from money.
She was born Margaret Douglas.
The Douglas's were one of the oldest and most powerful families in Scotland. Adam was Margaret's only child. They were very close and would remain so until her death many years later.
And Adam never married, by the way. As a boy in Kirkcaldy, he got an excellent education.
In the various biographies, it was well recognized that he got good schooling.
That's George Proudfoot.
Not everywhere had a good school.
Dare I say it, grammar schools were very, very patchy.
But he was fortunate.
For example, it was not normal to teach Greek,
but the schoolmaster recognized
Smith's intellectual talents and then taught him some Greek. And of course, that was very,
very useful because when he went to Glasgow University when he was 14,
some of the classes were indeed taught in Greek. So it had a start.
That's right. Smith enrolled at Glasgow University at age 14, and he studied under a forward-thinking philosopher named Francis Hutchison.
This would start Smith on a lifetime of study, teaching, and writing in the fields of philosophy, theology, astronomy, ethics, jurisprudence, and, yes, political economy. But why is it his voice, one of the few from 300 years
ago, that still echoes in the modern era? Here, for instance, is U.S. President Ronald Reagan
from a 1988 radio address. The freedom to trade is not a new issue for America. In 1776,
our founding fathers signed the Declaration of Independence,
charging the British with a number of offenses, among them, and I quote,
cutting off our trade with all parts of the world, end quote. And that same year,
a Scottish economist named Adam Smith launched another revolution with a book entitled
The Wealth of Nations, which exposed for all
time the folly of protectionism.
And here's Barack Obama when he was president in 2013.
This shouldn't be an ideological question. It was Adam Smith, the father of free market
economics, who once said, they who feed, clothe, and lodge the whole body of the people
should have such a share of the produce of their own labor as to be themselves tolerably
well-fed, clothed, and lodged.
Everybody loves to quote Adam Smith. Everybody wants Adam Smith on their side.
And that is Glory Liu, a political scientist at
Harvard. People quote from the Bible to support whatever their views happen to be, right? That
more or less happens with the wealth of nations. Like it is very easy to quote things from the
wealth of nations without context and to have them support their views. Lou just published a book called Adam Smith's America,
how a Scottish philosopher became an icon of American capitalism.
I think one reason that Smith has had such staying power is because he wrote on some of
the most important questions about the human condition. What are the origins of morality?
Are we selfish or are we benevolent? And then,
of course, with the wealth of nations, how do you understand the forces of national wealth?
What makes a nation happy and productive? These are questions that aren't going away.
And so I think that that is certainly one reason why Smith is timeless, because Smith's questions are timeless.
Coming up after the break, timeless questions and, it turns out, timeless answers.
You need to pay attention to how people are producing and where they're producing and what they're producing.
This is Freakonomics Radio.
I'm Stephen Dubner in Scotland in search of the real Adam Smith.
The questions that Adam Smith was asking in the mid-18th century may not strike you as the kind of questions an economist might ask today.
And there's good reason for that. In Smith's day, he was primarily known as what's called a moral philosopher.
As the political scientist Glory Liu tells us, moral philosophy came with its own set of questions.
Where do our moral judgments come from?
How do we learn what's right and wrong? What counts as virtue? And these are the questions that animate
Smith's first book, The Theory of Moral Sentiments. What is it like when we see somebody in pain?
How do we feel when we tell a joke and somebody doesn't laugh. That is actually an example in the book.
And he uses all of these experiences to show how moral rules emerge from experience.
I see the theory of moral sentiments as showing this deeply humanistic, curious,
and imaginative person interested in what makes humans tick in all spheres of life.
In Adam Smith's hometown of Krakati,
the people planning his 300th birthday party
suspect it may be easier to just call him an economist.
A lot of people do not know who Adam Smith is.
And to tell them that he is a moral philosopher, I mean,
that just turns people off because they have no idea what a moral philosopher is.
George Proudfoot walks us from the old church down into the town centre so we can see what
Adam Smith used to see. This is the high street. The reason why it's a wider part of the street
is because this is where the market was.
And he would see the local trading market.
He would see local artisans selling their goods here.
What would they have been selling then?
Mostly it would be finished products from agricultural type of activities.
Things like leather making, local breads, ales, etc.
And was the market open every day or were there market days?
There were typically market days and there were also other very special days
that there would be markets.
But it would be busy
because it would attract people
from the hinterland of Kirkcaldy,
farms, etc.
Oh, so it was a big market town.
Oh yes, it was a big market town.
And of course that was very, very important
from Adam Smith's point of view
because he would observe that. He would town. And of course, that was very, very important from Adam Smith's point of view, because he would observe that.
He would observe the exchange of goods, the buying and selling.
Kirkcaldy wasn't just a big market town.
It was also a royal borough.
This was a designation from the British government, from the Crown, essentially,
which gave certain advantages to local landowners or burgesses.
It didn't cost them to sell their goods in the town.
And they had special privileges in terms of being able to trade.
That's a big deal.
Oh, it's a big deal.
How many royal boroughs were there in this neighborhood?
Well, there was half a dozen in the Fife area.
That was very, very important.
But also it had another side, which Smith recognised as well,
is it almost created a monopolistic situation where it was a closed shop.
Right, so if you were a farmer and you had some things you wanted to come sell,
unless you were part of the...
You had to pay tolls to come into Kirkcaldy,
and you also had to pay to have your stall here.
Very often, though, the richer farmers also were burgesses
because they had to have a house in the town.
So they had the best of both worlds. What George Proudfoot is describing here is how the landed
gentry, families like Adam Smith's family, how they stayed landed and wealthy. They operated
as a sort of cartel, kicking up taxes and fees to the crown, which in turn let the Burgesses dominate
local trade. Proudfoot walks us further down the high street. Just a few hundred yards away
is the wide-mouthed port where Adam Smith's father worked as a customs officer.
Just a basic question. We're looking at, it's called the Firth of Forth, is that right?
Can you explain those words?
I know of.
What's a Firth and what's Forth?
Inlet. Firth is the inlet, is it?
This is the last part of the river.
So it's an estuary because it's going both ways.
It's the Scottish word for an estuary.
And then Forth means?
It's the name of the river.
Oh, it's the name of the river.
It's the name of the river.
A wee bit shorter than the Hudson River.
We press on a bit further.
What we're looking at is where Adam Smith's house was.
And the reason why I say where it was
is because it was knocked down in 1834
and replaced by the building that we see just now.
So it's most unfortunate we don't have the actual building itself.
But this is incredibly central to everything. It's very central, I think. So it's most unfortunate we don't have the actual building itself.
But this is incredibly central to everything.
It's very central, and that's the thing that's got to be understood,
that he would see everything which was central to how Kirkcaldy as a town operated.
He's an observer. He's taking everything in.
And he will have been asking questions of people as a child and trying to understand literally trying to understand how let's say trading worked i don't mean to be rude
but how do we know that i mean we could assume that he was curious and observant and asking
people as a child but we don't really know do we i would say writing suggests that he was certainly
he was looking at things in the early part part of The Wealth of Nations, he talks about pin manufacture.
That was in Kirkcaldy, though.
That was in the next village to here.
If you have read even a little bit of The Wealth of Nations,
you may recall the passage that George Proudfoot is talking about here, the pin factory.
When modern readers see the word pin, we think of a little thing,
like the pins you remove from the packaging of a new shirt.
In 18th century Scotland, pins were hefty fasteners made of iron
and used in all sorts of industrial settings.
It would be for timber constructions.
It would be for shipping, anything attached together.
In the book, Smith describes how each of the workers at the pin factory had a specialized task.
One would draw out the iron, another would straighten it, another would cut it, and so on.
By dividing up the process like this, a group of factory workers could produce hundreds of pins a day.
What if each worker had to make a pin from start to finish?
Here is how Smith put it in The Wealth of Nations, as read by John Ewell.
If they had all wrought separately and independently and without any of them having
been educated to this peculiar business, they certainly could not each of them have made 20,
perhaps not one pin in a day.
By telling a small story about the pin factory, Adam Smith was making a larger argument about
some of the ingredients required for a thriving economy, specialization in labor,
and the division of labor. Smith was not afraid of large arguments.
What is Smith trying to explain in The Wealth of Nations?
Glory Liu again.
If you go at it with the mindset that this is a book of economics,
the way that we understand the field of economics today,
you're going to narrow your field of vision.
The structure of The Wealth of Nations is not just looking at
what happens at the level of individual motivations.
By the time you get to book three, Smith is looking at institutional history from like the fall of Rome to the beginning of modern Europe.
What was Smith's primary purpose of publishing that book or what did he hope would come of it? I think that Smith is hoping that educated readers will understand that national wealth
is not measured in terms of gold and silver coin, and that actually you need to pay attention to
output. You need to pay attention to how people are producing and where they're producing and
what they're producing.
The dominant economic ideology of Smith's day was called mercantilism.
Mercantilists believed that economic value is based on how much gold a country had to buy the goods it needed.
This could look something like a zero-sum game.
Gold or coin exchanged for wool or leather or flour. Wool or leather or flower
exchanged for gold or coin. How these goods were produced, not only the physical inputs,
but the human motivation, this hadn't been thought of as particularly relevant.
Adam Smith changed that. Here is a famous passage from the first of five books that make up The Wealth of
Nations. It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect
our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest. We address ourselves not to their
humanity, but to their self-love. Ah, yes, the butcher, baker, brewer, right? We don't get our
meals out of benevolence, but out of self-interest, mutual, yes, the butcher, baker, brewer, right? We don't get our meals out of benevolence,
but out of self-interest, mutual exchange, and mutual benefit. Smith in book one is really just
outlining some of the principles and observations he's making about economic life, right? Like,
how do we get our needs? We don't get our needs from benevolence alone. We get our needs because
we also care about our own interests, and it turns out everybody else does too.
This argument that self-interest is a sort of all-purpose economic lubricant, it may seem obvious today, but in the age of mercantilism, it was not at all obvious. This is why Adam Smith is called the founder of modern economic thought.
Yes. The state of the field was not like, I'm writing a new economics textbook for millions of college students in the United States to get their college degree. and send more gunboats out so that we can hoard more gold and coin? Or should we actually care about whether we have regulations
that prevent people from working in jobs
that would actually give them a meaningful way of life?
Right next to the site of Adam Smith's house in Kirkcaldy,
there is a plaque.
It's splattered with bird poop, but George Proudfoot can still make it out.
The sign says Adam Smith, 1723 to 1790, born in Kirkcaldy.
And it also says on the site stood the home of his mother, in which he lived from 1767 to 1776 and completed the Wealth of Nations. His grave is in
the Canongate churchyard in Edinburgh and the sign itself here was erected in 1953. But you see the
reference is the Wealth of Nations. It doesn't say the theory of moral sentiments but the theory of
moral sentiments tells you so much more about Smith
than what the Wealth of Nations does.
So this was erected 53. Who put this sign up?
The Kirkcaldy Antiquarian Society.
And why do you think they didn't acknowledge the theory of moral sentiments?
I think my understanding of Smith has moved on.
That would have been the book which people well recognized.
But for Smith scholars, of course, there's no question about it. The Theory of Moral Sentiments
is an extremely important book. You see the humanity and understanding of people
from the Theory of Moral Sentiments, even more so than the alternations.
Coming up, we hear from one Smith scholar who agrees.
The theory of moral sentiments is the more interesting, the richer,
in many ways the more innovative of the two books.
And why was all this innovation happening in Scotland?
I'm Stephen Dubner. This is Freakonomics Radio. We'll be right back.
Okay, so Adam Smith left his hometown of Kirkcaldy when he was 14 years old in the 1730s to attend the University of Glasgow, roughly 60 miles away.
And what was the state of Scotland in the 1700s?
They start the century. It's a poor, backward outpost on the fringe of Europe.
That is Dennis Rasmussen, a political theorist at Syracuse University.
By the middle of the century, it's really one of the cultural leaders of the
whole continent, to the point that even Voltaire admitted, I think a bit ruefully,
that now it's to Scotland of all places that we look for our idea of civilization. So what happened? How did Adam Smith's Scotland
go from backward to forward so quickly? I'd say that Scotland was undergoing an economic
boom at this time, thanks in large part to the union with England that created Great Britain
in 1707, brought with it, you know, greater access to the markets of England and the
colonies. And this economic boom, evidenced by the pin factories and the abundant ship traffic
that young Adam Smith had watched back in Kirkcaldy, this helped produce what came to be
called the Scottish Enlightenment, which was in full flower by the time Smith enrolled at the
University of Glasgow. Yeah, Francis Hutchison, who was Smith's teacher by the time Smith enrolled at the University of Glasgow.
Yeah, Francis Hutchison, who was Smith's teacher, the common sense philosopher Thomas Reed,
Adam Ferguson, the founder of modern geology was a guy named James Hutton,
a famous chemist named Joseph Black. There was James Watt of steam engine fame, important artists, the painter Alan Ramsey, the architect Robert Adam. So it really spanned a whole variety of fields. I want to know why this all happened in Scotland. My naive reasoning has
always been, well, there were a lot of well-educated people, strong literacy and university tradition,
and it was cold and dark for much of the year. So might as well stay inside and ponder the nature
of the human condition. But
I have no idea if that's right. Tell me. Yeah, maybe that's not far off. So it was probably the
most literate society in the world at that time, thanks to this innovative series of parish schools,
excellent universities, lots of clubs, debating societies, a really thriving publishing industry.
So there's a lot of cultural ferment, economic boom going on at this time. It's a really unbelievable renaissance.
Adam Smith thrived at the University of Glasgow, studying moral philosophy under Francis Hutchison. Upon graduation, he won a scholarship to Balliol College at Oxford University in England. Glory Lou again.
And the conditions of the scholarship are that you enter into the
Episcopalian ministry afterward. To be fair, a lot of university education at this point was
pointed in that direction, yeah. Exactly. So that doesn't necessarily indicate that he was
a committed Episcopalian. This was just a convenient way for him to attend Oxford.
But Smith disliked almost everything about Oxford, especially the professors,
whom he found both haughty and lazy. Years later, in The Wealth of Nations,
he would blame the incentives, explaining that professors were paid well whether they
taught well or not. In The University of Oxford, he wrote, the greater part of the public professors have for
these many years given up altogether even the pretense of teaching. Smith also disliked Oxford
because he was made to feel like a country bumpkin. He apparently kept to himself almost entirely.
This solitude turned out to be productive. When he's at Oxford, he starts reading David Hume's
treatise on human nature and gets in trouble for it because Hume is seen as like this blasphemous
atheist. But Hume is also the single most important intellectual influence on Smith's life.
Hume is widely seen today as maybe the greatest philosopher ever to write in the English language.
He was famous during his time.
Sometimes it might be better to say notorious because of his irreligious or anti-religious
writings.
He was 12 years older than Smith, and he had finished writing almost all of his philosophical
works before Smith even began to write his.
As philosophers go, David Hume was an empiricist.
Meaning that he thought that all knowledge comes through experience,
through the senses, rather than through some kind of abstract reason.
Was he a fun guy?
Yes. Hume was maybe the best-natured philosopher who ever lived. He was a big,
jovial guy who liked to, you know, drink and eat with his friends and play
cards and have fun. He was almost universally known during his time in France as Le Bon David,
the Good David. So, he was very well liked by those who were close to him, including
very religious people, the ministers among the Scottish literati. So, it's an interesting
contrast. He was very widely hated for his blatant irreligiosity,
but also very well loved by people who knew him well.
The fact that he was called the Bonne David, does that mean there was a Maldivide as well?
I don't know of one. He was just universally known as being a good, affable guy.
So, what was David Hume, the Bonne David, the famous irreligious philosopher?
What was he to Adam Smith?
Smith began as a fan reading Hume in his room at Oxford.
Ultimately, they became friends.
Correct.
So they're both from Scotland.
Hume is from just south of Edinburgh.
Smith is from just north of Edinburgh.
Much of their time, they actually didn't live together or in the same city. So they actually spent much less time together than you might expect,
given that they were best friends, which they were.
Yes. Yeah. Adam Smith and David Hume are best friends. It's very cute.
In their letters to one another, they call each other my dearest friend,
which they don't say to anyone else. It's very clear that they regard each other as
their closest friend. They both asked the other to be their literary executor when they were dying or feared they might be dying.
Dennis Rasmussen has published a book called The Infidel and the Professor.
The subtitle is David Hume, Adam Smith, and the Friendship that Shaped Modern Thought.
I asked him if that claim isn't a bit bold.
It is a bold claim. My defense of it,
the reason I went with it, was that very clearly Hume shaped every element of Smith's thought that
there is. And Smith himself shaped modern thought and the modern world in a deep way, which is why
you're doing this podcast series on him. Indeed. Scholars like Rasmussen see David Hume's fingerprints all over Adam Smith.
You can trace Hume's influence on virtually everything that Smith ever wrote.
For instance, even though Smith would become known as a champion of free trade and of a
commercial society in general, his view was remarkably nuanced. He weighed not just the benefits, but the costs, especially the human costs.
He recognized the real potential drawbacks and dangers of commercial society,
the ways that commerce can produce great inequalities,
the ways that the division of labor can exact an immense cost in human dignity
by making people feeble and ignorant.
The idea being, you know, you spend your whole life making the 17th part of a pin, you don't have any opportunity to exercise your body or your mind.
He worried about the ways that wealth and an emphasis on material goods can corrupt people's
moral sentiments. This wrestling that Smith did with how individual humans fit into a
rapidly industrializing economy, all that was to come years later. Let's get back to his bruising
experience at Oxford. From Oxford, he retreated to Kirkcaldy, where he spent the next two years
living with his mother, an 18th century version of failure to launch. Almost nothing is known
about that time in Smith's life, although John Yule, our playwright friend, suspects that Smith was
in a deep funk. In his play, here's what Yule has Smith's mother saying to him.
You need help. You spend hours talking to yourself, conversing with some imaginary
companion. You're distracted, absent-minded. Lord, one morning you walked several miles
along the seafront in your nightshirt.
You don't look at me when I talk to you. You've simply withdrawn from me. I cannot and I will not
tolerate it. However true or untrue that depiction may be, Smith did ultimately break his isolation.
He was hired to give freelance lectures in Edinburgh on rhetoric and jurisprudence.
And in 1751, he was offered a faculty position at the University of Glasgow, his alma mater.
He soon became chair of moral philosophy, and it was the lectures he gave in that capacity
which would become his first book, The Theory of Moral Sentiments.
Glasgow suited him well.
Edinburgh was the political and ecclesiastical capital of the country. This is where a lot of
the decision-making was made. But it was also a very cramped, squalid, filthy, stinky place.
Whereas Glasgow was the opposite. It was open and airy and well-designed. It was dominated by
its first-rate university that Smith was part of.
Well, if Smith was part of it, we wanted to be part of it too. So we got back on the train.
We'll soon arrive at Glasgow Queen Street High Level, which is the last station on this route.
And we found the most appropriate gentleman to be found.
My name is Craig Smith. I am the Adam Smith Senior Lecturer in the Scottish Enlightenment.
I assume the answer is no, but I would be remiss if I didn't ask.
Adam Smith, Craig Smith, no relation, I assume?
Sadly not, no relation. Although I do say to people, you can at least say you met
a Scotsman called Smith and talked about the wealth of nations in Glasgow.
Craig Smith walks us over to what is now called the Adam Smith Business School.
These are not the same buildings where Adam Smith taught in the 18th century.
This campus was built in the 19th century as the university expanded.
In the entry hall of the business school, at the foot of a grand wooden staircase,
there stands a marble statue of the man himself. So he's standing with his hand on a book and the volumes piled up around about
him. And we're told that he was a little bit, sometimes a little bit careless of his appearance.
So if you look, you see the button is undone in the middle of his waistcoat.
So that's supposed to have been a symbol. So so it was smith the academic essentially this one and he was also known to be a bit forgetful yes yes maybe not forgetful but
involved with his own mind let's say yeah he looks this smith looks like someone i'd want as my
professor he does and he's a good luck symbol to the students so there's a little tape to keep the
students from touching him because the hall upstairs is used for exams
and there was a habit of touching him for good luck as you go up the stairs.
From the Adam Smith Business School, we head to the Adam Smith Building,
which houses the social sciences. This is where Craig Smith keeps his office.
There are students rushing through the hallways and we grab one. His name
is Alvaro. He's from Spain and he says he will be writing his dissertation on the Scottish
Enlightenment. I asked Alvaro what he knew about Adam Smith before coming to Glasgow.
Nothing at all. I've only heard of him in like mainstream media. There's this concept that he's
an ultra-capitalist and he's willing to
override the rights of everyone, etc. And this course has opened my mind in the sense that
it's not that simple. And Adam Smith does recognize the flaws of capitalism.
We duck into Craig Smith's office. It's quiet and orderly. His shelves are stuffed with
philosophy books, biographies, and a vast array
of Smithiania. I've always tried to introduce students to the other elements of his thought
to show that he's a richer thinker and a more complex thinker. I mean, I happen to think that
of the two books, The Theory of Moral Sentiments is the more interesting, the richer, in many ways,
the more innovative of the two books. I'm really curious to know why you say that. I mean, I recognize that Theory of Moral Sentiments
is a very moving book on the human condition, really, but Wealth of Nations really took a step
back and tried to describe how the global economy worked, and this was a long time ago. So why would
you give the more innovative label to Moral Sentiments?
To be fair to Smith, I think what he does in The Wealth of Nations is radical,
but he's not the first person to try to do that. He's not the first person to try and write a
moral philosophy, but he is the first person, I think, to try and understand the reality of what
it is to make a moral judgment. So Smith's moral philosophy is not about telling you,
here's how you should live your life,
here's a program.
It's predominantly about explaining to you what happens when you make a moral decision.
And the way in which he does that,
I think is really, really quite striking.
He's able to point to things that readers today
recognize in their own lives
as reactions that they have to scenarios,
and he's able to build that and make an account, a coherent account of all of the different things
that come together to make our moral lives. I think that's a very radical thing to do
in moral philosophy.
It almost sounds as though you're saying that Smith described our daily behavior and our moral behavior
in a similar way as he describes economic transactions, which are there are costs and
benefits to everything. And sometimes the things that we think may be beneficial to us, like being
selfish, in fact have costs in the long run that make us worse off.
Yeah. No, I think that's right. And I think he also points out there that there's a whole set
of other considerations that people have. So cost-benefit analysis is their part of
human life, and he explores that brilliantly in The Wealth of Nations. But it's also true that
there are other concerns that people have about reputation, about sympathetic engagement with
other people, about trying to do the right thing. And those are equally a part of human experience.
You can't have a
rounded vision of what it's like to live a human life without both of those elements being present.
If Smith were alive and thinking and writing and teaching today, let's say here at Glasgow,
which department would he be in?
Oh, that's a good question. Yeah, well, he was such a polymath. So moral philosophy,
as he taught it, encompasses a range of different academic disciplines now. So he had a bit of economics, a bit of ethics, a bit of political science, a bit of jurisprudence, a bit of philosophy of science, a bit of literary studies.
How would you describe his teaching style or his persona? Yeah, this is interesting. So we have notes from a student who says that when
Smith started lecturing, he tried to adopt the style of his teacher, Francis Hutchison,
to be a kind of extemporary preacher, you know, to just stand and relate the work to the students.
But then he discovered he wasn't very comfortable doing that. So the description we have is of him
standing with his notes and working very close to his notes and encouraging the students not to take their
own notes, but to listen attentively to what he was saying. At one point, he's supposed to have
said, I hate scribblers because they put him off when he was giving his lectures.
The sound of other people scribbling.
Yeah. He was very well thought of though. The students admired him. His
classes were particularly large. He attracted students from around the world to come to Glasgow.
So on Rate My Professor, he had a good rating.
Yes. Well, you could buy a bust of Smith from a shop in Glasgow. So he was obviously
well-regarded, well-liked by his students.
How many philosophy professors do you know who attract students from around the world,
who have a bust in the campus bookstore?
Adam Smith was plainly an extraordinary thinker and writer.
There are Smith scholars who wish he'd written much more than he did,
or at least published more than he did.
There were just the two books, The Theory of Moral Sentiments and The Wealth of Nations, multiple editions of each since he was an inveterate reviser.
He also published a few essays on the history of astronomy, for instance, but all his unpublished
writings were burned upon his death. That was a common practice at the time. There was one other published work. It's a letter he wrote
following the death of his best friend, David Hume. Here again is Dennis Rasmussen.
This letter ended up being maybe the most controversial thing that Smith ever wrote.
It came in this very highly charged atmosphere because of Hume's irreligiosity. Few people in
18th century Britain were as forthright in their lack of religious faith as Hume's irreligiosity. Few people in 18th century Britain were as forthright
in their lack of religious faith as Hume was.
And as a result, as he neared his end,
everybody wanted to know how he would face death.
Would he show remorse?
Would he maybe even recant his skepticism?
And so Smith wanted to tell this story for people.
He wrote what was effectively the authorized version
of the story of Hume's death.
Smith doesn't explicitly call attention to Hume's impiety in the letter,
but he does make very clear that Hume died with remarkable good humor and without religion.
He chronicles, maybe even flaunts, Hume's cheerfulness and equanimity during his final days.
He depicts Hume telling jokes and playing cards and conversing cheerfully with his friends.
He also emphasizes the goodness of Hume's character. He concludes the letter in one of
the most fateful sentences that Smith ever wrote. He says that Hume, his unbelieving friend,
he approached as nearly to the idea of a perfectly wise and virtuous man as perhaps the nature of
human frailty will permit. And so this letter, I mean, this isn't nearly as well known,
of course, as his two books today, but this caused an absolute uproar in Smith's time.
Smith later very famously said that this letter brought on me 10 times more abuse than the very
violent attack I'd made on the entire commercial system of Great Britain, meaning, of course,
the wealth of nations. Wait a minute. Thealth of Nations is an attack on the entire commercial system of
Great Britain? That is not how The Wealth of Nations is read today. It is read as a tribute
to free market economics and an attack on, if anything, government interference.
So next week on the show, how did that happen and where did it happen?
The Chicago School picked up a few aspects of Smith's thought and made it the whole of Smith's
thought. How the invisible hand was made very visible and was used to slap around anyone who
disagreed. Oh, absolutely. We worked with Mrs. Thatcher on privatization, for example,
and contracting out local services. on the show. Until then, take care of yourself and, if you can, someone else too. Because,
as Smith says, we naturally desire not only to be loved, but to be lovely.
Freakonomics Radio is produced by Stitcher and Renbud Radio. You can find our entire archive
on any podcast app or at Freakonomics.com, where we also publish transcripts and show notes. You can reach us
directly at radio at Freakonomics.com. This episode was produced by Zach Lipinski. We had help in
Scotland from Josh Nixon and Upload Studios. Thanks also to John Yule for reading Adam Smith
and Claire Darbyshire for reading Margaret Smith. Our staff also includes Neil Carruth, Gabriel Roth,
Greg Rippin, Ryan Kelly, Rebecca Lee Douglas, Julie Canfor, Morgan Levy, Catherine Moncure,
Jasmine Klinger, Eleanor Osborne, Jeremy Johnston, Daria Klenert, Emma Terrell, Lyric Bowditch,
Alina Kullman, and Elsa Hernandez. Our theme song is Mr. Fortune by the Hitchhikers. You also heard
a bit of I'm in Love with Margaret Thatcher by Not Sensibles from 1979.
Special thanks to them.
Our regular music is composed by Luis Guerra.
As always, thanks for listening.
What did you think of John's play?
Oh, fantastic.
Which play were we talking about?
No, no.
Thanks, George.