Freakonomics Radio - 526. Was Adam Smith Really a Right-Winger?
Episode Date: December 15, 2022Economists and politicians have turned him into a mascot for free-market ideology. Some on the left say the right has badly misread him. Prepare for a very Smithy tug of war. (Part 2 of “In Search o...f the Real Adam Smith.”)
Transcript
Discussion (0)
what do you think adam smith would make of the uk economy today oh golly uh he'd think it's in a
great pickle i think he'd actually think that it's one of the most tyrannical systems that he'd ever
discovered the idea that government should be taking 40 percent of the national income in taxes of one sort or another,
not just direct taxes on income, but taxes on everything you spend, taxes on air travel,
all sorts of hidden taxes, taxes on work, taxes on jobs. He would think that this is the most
oppressive regime in the whole world. That is Eamon Butler.
I'm a director of the Adam Smith Institute, which is a free market think tank based in London.
In our previous episode, In Search of the Real Adam Smith,
we traveled to Scotland to see where Smith was born and spent most of his life.
That's the pulpit. So he would have been baptized in the front of the church there.
He seems to have been a sociable individual who took a full part in the life of the university.
Today, we're down in London. We are trying to figure out how a moral philosopher from
18th century Scotland became the patron saint of free market capitalism in the current century.
Did Smith, for instance, really see governments as tyrannical?
He distrust politicians,
both their abilities and often even their intentions. We'll find out when and where the modern view of Smith gained traction. The Chicago school picked up a few aspects of
Smith's thought and made it the whole of Smith's thought. And we'll hear how this interpretation of Smith is often quite wrong.
As much as that might have been efficient in terms of allocation,
it was horrible from the perspective of human welfare.
Today on Freakonomics Radio, prepare yourself for a tug of war.
There's raging debate in Smith scholarship among people who are sometimes called
left Smithians and right Smithians.
Whether you are a left Smithian or a right Smithian,
it's fair to say that we are all Smithians now,
even if you've never heard of him.
In Search of the Real Adam Smith,
part two starts right now.
This is Freakonomics Radio,
the podcast that explores the hidden side of everything with your host, Stephen Dubner. In 1759, Adam Smith published his first book, The Theory of Moral Sentiments.
He was in his mid-30s, and he'd spent the previous several years teaching moral philosophy at the University of Glasgow.
The initial reception of The Theory of Moral Sentiments was quite warm.
That's Glory Liu, a political scientist and Smith scholar.
The initial reviews in London magazines, as well as in the United States,
are praising Smith for the beauty of his writing.
But it wasn't just the beauty of Smith's writing that won praise.
It was his humanity, his sympathy.
He argued, for instance, that wealth does not necessarily indicate moral virtue,
nor does poverty preclude it. Here is a passage from the book.
This disposition to admire and almost to worship the rich and the powerful,
and to despise or at least to neglect persons of poor and mean condition,
though necessary both to establish and to maintain the distinction of
ranks and the order of society, is at the same time the great and most universal cause of the
corruption of our moral sentiments. The book brought Smith a sterling reputation as a writer,
philosopher, and public intellectual, which is why some of his friends thought it odd that he accepted a position as
a tutor to a 17-year-old duke, the stepson of a future chancellor of the Exchequer.
This assignment included travel around continental Europe. Smith grew bored with the tutelage itself,
but he did get to spend time with Voltaire, with the economist François Canet, and with Benjamin Franklin. He also had
the chance to observe how other nations were dealing with the massive economic changes
being produced by the rise in global trade and the onset of the Industrial Revolution.
In a word, he thought they were dealing poorly. Governments, he noted, often had protectionist
instincts, where Smith thought
they ought to be more open to free trade. After a couple of years, he returned to Scotland and
threw himself into his next book. Smith had never been accused of being a fast writer,
and it turned out to be 17 years between the publication of The Theory of Moral Sentiments
and the release of his second and final book, The Wealth of Nations.
The publication of The Wealth of Nations coincided with two major events. The first
was the death of the philosopher David Hume, Smith's best friend and most significant mentor.
We heard about that relationship in part one of this series.
Yes, yeah. Adam Smith and David Hume are best friends. It's very cute.
You can trace Hume's influence on virtually everything that Smith ever wrote.
And the second major event? Well, this was the year that Britain lost control of its colonies
in America. Eamon Butler again. The Wealth of Nations, his big book published in 1776, what a great year that was. It really is a polemic. It's a polemic against
economic centralism and restrictions on trade. So who, in your mind, did he write The Wealth
of Nations for? Oh, for the politicians of the day, because the politicians of the day were stuck
in this idea that you had to resist foreigners bringing
goods into your country. And similarly, you want to export as much as possible. So that was his
main target, people who wanted to control international trade and people who thought
that the key to wealth was getting lots of gold and silver in rather than producing stuff.
Now, when you say he was speaking to leaders, were those primarily
European? And I realize he started writing Wealth of Nations long before 1776. Do you think he had
America in mind at all? Oh, absolutely. I mean, there's lots of material in the Wealth of Nations,
which is very supportive of the colonists in terms of getting out of the control of
the UK control of trade. I mean,
the first edition of The Wealth of Nations was actually published in Russia. I've seen an edition
which has got Hamilton's signature on it. It did get right out around the world. And partly because
he'd written about the colonies and so on, I think the Americans took it up very enthusiastically,
the American founding fathers. So one of my favorite lines in The Wealth of Nations is from the very last paragraph.
Glory Lou again.
This is where Smith is giving his withering last remarks on the British Empire.
And he says,
If the colonies, notwithstanding their refusal to submit to British taxes, are still to be considered as provinces of the British Empire, their defense in some future war may cost Great Britain as great an expense than a century past, amused the people with the imagination that they possessed a great empire on the west side of the Atlantic.
This empire, however, has hitherto been not an empire, but the project of an empire, not a gold mine, but the project of a gold mine, a project which has cost, which continues to cost, and which if pursued in the same way as it has been hitherto, is likely to cost immense expense without being likely to bring any profit.
It's clear that he thinks that the colonial projects, both in the Americas as well as other parts of the British Empire, in Bengal, are a loss.
They are a huge financial drain.
Glory Liu recently published a book called Adam Smith's America, how a Scottish philosopher
became an icon of American Capitalism.
You write in your book that the wealth of nations became the origin point of the science of
political economy in the United States, and that Smith was both revered and criticized.
Sketch that out for me, both the reverence and the criticism. What I'm really trying to get a sense of is how
concretely or prominently did Adam Smith's ideas shape the U.S. political economy early on?
So the important thing in the founding era is that Smith is important as like a very
technical resource, but he hasn't quite obtained that halo around him yet.
He's not like Adam Smith, the father of all gifts and the markets
and people like genuflect when they hear his name.
He's well known, but he hasn't acquired that intellectual authority yet.
So his writing wasn't treated like a religious text, more like a blueprint, perhaps.
Absolutely. That's a great way of describing it. You have people like James Madison who will say things like, oh, you know, I own this great text on political economy and I'm a friend to commerce. a smart man who wrote 900 plus pages about different ways to think about commerce, the
relationship between agriculture and manufacturing, the conditions under which liberalized trade made
sense versus prioritizing national defense. This is the most sophisticated, most up-to-date analysis of what it means to be at the helm of a nation that cares about national wealth.
So it's natural that you have the founders, Madison, Hamilton, Jefferson,
reading The Wealth of Nations to understand a way of thinking of national wealth.
Glory Liu writes in her book that Alexander Hamilton actually cribbed bits of Adam Smith in his own report on national banks. And thus, the moral philosopher from Kirkcaldy, Scotland,
began to be woven into the fabric of the American experiment. By the mid-19th century,
political economy was an established academic discipline.
And Smith, himself dead by now for several decades,
was considered its founder.
American statesmen and attorneys
would study Smith in preparation for their careers.
In Congress, meanwhile,
there were vigorous debates about trade policy and tariffs.
The primary source of revenue for the federal government Meanwhile, there were vigorous debates about trade policy and tariffs.
The primary source of revenue for the federal government in its fledgling decades is from import taxes. And later on, much later on, like after the Civil War, the tariff becomes
a wedge issue. It's the issue that divides Democrats and Republicans, Republicans being the party
of protectionism and Democrats being the party of free trade. And Adam Smith became the wedge
with which to fight the wedge issue. You have people from both sides of the debate,
free trade and protectionism, being like, ah, but Adam Smith, look at what Adam Smith said. Oh,
even the apostle of free trade said that the home market was really important.
And so you start to see that, like, the intellectual authority matters.
It's not Smith's ideas that matter that much anymore.
It's his authority.
That authority rests on an assumption that the science he created, the science of political economy, was powerful. Smith continued to be cited by politicians and others throughout the 19th and early 20th
centuries.
Some used Smith to argue in favor of unbridled commerce and to rail against regulation.
Others went the opposite direction.
As the organized labor movement grew, for instance, the progressive economist Richard Ely argued that Adam Smith would have been firmly on the side of the unions.
If you know even a little bit about Adam Smith's reputation today, it may surprise you to learn this, that Smith was used in service of such progressive causes because Smith's reputation today runs conservative or at least libertarian. So where did that reputation come from? In her book, Glory Liu says it mostly came from the University of Chicago.
That's accurate according to my view of things. The University of Chicago Economics Department not only embraced Smith around the middle of the 20th century, but also, to quote you to yourself,
smoothed over or altogether obscured the complexities, tensions, and other problematic aspects characteristic of earlier readings of Smith.
Okay, so that's a lot to unpack.
Unpack that for me, please. One place to start is to ask, okay, well, what were the problems and complexities in the earlier versions of Smith?
So this brings us to kind of early Chicago school.
The figures that I look at are people like Jacob Viner and Frank Knight, and they are these, like, heavyweights.
The University of Chicago doesn't have the reputation that it does today when Jacob
Viner and Frank Knight were around in like the 1930s. They teach Smith as an early theorist of
price. So teaching Smith as an early theorist of price and somebody who gives scientific value and
a kind of objectivity to economics is really important for building intellectual credibility, let's call it, of Chicago's way of doing economics.
But then Viner and Knight go away.
They leave.
They die, right?
Yeah, yeah.
Then there's the new generation.
Here's what you write about them. working Smithian concepts like individualism, self-interest, and the invisible hand,
a new set of thinkers like Friedrich Hayek, George Stigler, and Milton Friedman transformed Smith
into an original way of thinking about an individualistic, market-oriented society that
was justifiable on social scientific grounds. So, wowser. That's an incredibly powerful sentence and, again,
much to be unpacked.
Let's start with self-interest. Self-interest, in old Chicago school view, is not just
rational utility-maximizing individualism. It's a human motivation among many. And there are extreme versions of self-interest
that are dangerous. We lose that texture when we get to somebody like George Stigler, who
looks to Smith as the Prometheus of economics. Self-interest has the most explanatory power.
Did Stigler view Smith that way because Stigler felt that way and looked for
support? Or was he persuaded of that view by Smith's writing itself? I think it was both.
And the reason why I say this is because Stigler loved the history of economic thought.
And so I don't want to treat Stigler like this kind of... A fanboy. A fanboy who's just cherry picking.
But I do think that it was this symbiotic relationship where like Stigler loved reading
Smith and he also happened to find the perfect mascot that coincided with his own views of what economics should be
and how to think about economics in relation to the politics of deregulation.
In Glory Liu's book, there is a photograph of a grinning George Stigler
wearing a t-shirt that says, Adam Smith's best friend.
Where did that come from? As the story goes,
Stigler liked to play a game with the very young children in his family where he would offer a
million dollars if they could answer a tough question. One day he asked, who is Adam Smith's
best friend? The answer Stigler was looking for was David Hume. The answer he got was,
you are Uncle George. It was a pretty good answer. Good
enough to go on a t-shirt, at least. Stigler and a few other Chicago economists had had a tremendous
impact on the reputation of a man who by then had been dead nearly 200 years.
Okay, so the Chicago school picked up a few aspects of Smith's thought and made it the whole of Smith's thought.
That is Dennis Rasmussen, another Smith scholar. He is a political scientist at Syracuse University.
They picked out the phrase, the invisible hand, which he uses just two or three times in his writings, and made that the central feature of who Smith was. To me, that's unfortunate. The phrase, the invisible hand, appears exactly once in The Wealth of Nations. It is in a section
about whether local businessmen would be tempted to use foreign trade to enrich themselves at the
expense of their nation. Smith's argument was that no, they wouldn't. Why not? Here is Smith's
reasoning.
By preferring the support of domestic to that of foreign industry, he intends only his own security,
and by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value,
he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases,
led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention.
Whether Smith was actually right in this regard and whether his reasoning holds up today,
that is a matter of debate.
During the past few decades of economic globalization,
there's plenty of evidence to the contrary.
In any case, Smith's phrase, the invisible hand, has come to mean something different.
Yeah, it's a lovely phrase, and nobody can deny that.
That's Craig Smith, yet another Adam Smith scholar. He is at the University of Glasgow.
One of the problems with it is that it's come to mean a particular set of modern ideas, a shorthand for a particular conception of how markets operate, that's not quite the same as the uses that Smith puts it to in his work. an unintended consequences explanation. So he explains how something is produced
out of social interaction without it being the intention of any of the actors.
But the unintended consequences being what economists call positive externalities versus
any negative externalities, correct?
Indeed. But you can also look elsewhere in his work and find unintended consequence arguments
with negative outcomes.
And it just so happens that the invisible hand as a nice phrase has become associated with positive cases of unintended consequences. And that's led to it then becoming associated with
a whole range of different arguments. What Craig Smith is saying here is that the phrase
the invisible hand today is used to imply that economic markets will operate perfectly well
if you just let them be. Even though that's not what Adam Smith was saying. Here is Dennis Rasmussen
again. I think one of the most valuable and interesting aspects of Smith's thought is
precisely that he recognized the real potential drawbacks and dangers of commercial society.
The ways that commerce can produce great society, the ways that commerce can
produce great inequalities, the ways that wealthy merchants and manufacturers collude against the
public interest, and above all, the way that the desire for wealth often leads people to submit to
endless toil and anxiety in the pursuit of just frivolous material goods that will produce only
fleeting satisfaction. And so I think too many of the Chicago school thinkers, even today's self-proclaimed Smithians,
read him as a mere apologist for commercial society, whereas I think he was anything but.
It's not that Smith didn't ultimately defend commercial society. He absolutely did.
He's absolutely convinced that commercial society's faults, though real and important,
are not nearly as numerous or as great
as those of other forms of society. That the security and liberty and prosperity that commercial
societies make possible constitutes a real improvement over the alternatives.
Do you think economists, including the Chicago School, knowingly exploited Smith's teachings, knowingly cherry-picked for
their purposes? Or were they true believers and focused on what resonated most and just didn't
really engage too much with the rest? My sense is the latter. Smith isn't a particularly easy
thinker to read or to understand. I mean, he writes in English and it's modern English,
so it can sometimes have the appearance of being very familiar and easy. But to understand. I mean, he writes in English and it's modern English, so it can sometimes have the appearance of being very familiar and easy. But to understand the nuance of his thought,
you really have to spend some time with it.
But the fact is that the Chicago economists, George Stigler and especially Milton Friedman,
did promote Adam Smith as a sort of superhero of economic thought.
Glory Liu again.
Friedman was a rhetorical genius.
Like, he was so charismatic and he was so good at speaking to the public.
Here, for instance, is Milton Friedman as host of the public television show Free to Choose. As Adam Smith wrote over 200 years ago,
in the economic market,
people who intend to serve only their own private interests are led by an invisible hand to serve public interests
that it was no part of their intention to promote.
This seemingly magical phenomenon, Friedman said,
was driven by what is called the price mechanism.
Adam Smith's flash of genius
was to see how prices that emerged in the market,
the prices of goods, the wages of labor, the cost of transport,
could coordinate the activities of millions of independent people, strangers to one another.
Glory Liu likes to call this invisible hand waving.
For Friedman, the idea of the invisible hand as the price mechanism
isn't just a descriptive metaphor. The price mechanism signaled what producers wanted to
produce and what buyers wanted to buy. So the price mechanism was a way to organize and allocate most efficiently.
And therefore, once you recognized how prices did that,
you didn't need centralized planning.
In other words, if markets can organize themselves so well
and so efficiently via the price mechanism,
you certainly don't want the government mucking things up
with unnecessary rules and regulations or, God forbid, with price controls.
Precisely.
And in fact, a lot of the time, experts, bureaucrats, government organizations act like private
interest groups and create huge inefficiencies. I think what we see in the Friedman-Stigler interpretation
is a way of treating the market as a moral thing in and of itself, right? While it appears
objective, scientific, and politically neutral to say that this is how prices work, there's an implicit moral claim that
those are the most important values, right? As opposed to equity, as opposed to universalism,
democracy. Here is maybe your harshest indictment of Friedman and his colleagues at Chicago.
You write, perhaps the greatest consequence of the Chicago Smith, Adam Smith, was that it served to reframe the problems of modern American capitalism and
modern society as problems that stemmed from government rather than the market itself.
What's your best evidence that the market itself is responsible for these problems
of modern American capitalism. standpoint of the failure of regulatory bodies and perhaps the market incentives to push a drug
onto the market. And as much as we think that might have been efficient in terms of allocation,
it was horrible from the perspective of just human welfare.
But the version of Adam Smith that was promoted by Milton Friedman and others at the University of Chicago would resonate well beyond academia.
Politicians in the U.S. and the U.K. began looking to Smith to shake up their struggling economies.
Coming up after the break, how one true believer brought Smith back to Britain just in time for a new revolution.
That was quite thrilling that it was an administration which was genuinely interested in ideas.
I'm Stephen Dubner. This is Freakonomics Radio. We'll be right back.
You might need a scorecard to keep track of the chaos in British politics lately. This past July,
amid rising inflation, a fragile economy, and a cornucopia of personal scandals, Boris Johnson resigned as prime minister.
It is clearly now the will of the parliamentary conservative party
that there should be a new leader of that party and therefore a new prime minister.
The next prime minister chosen by the conservatives was Liz Truss,
who had previously served as foreign secretary and international trade secretary.
I will deliver a bold plan to cut taxes and grow our economy.
Truss was an avowed fan of former Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher. In her agenda, cutting taxes and trimming government itself,
this held considerable appeal for the Thatcherite wing of the Conservative Party.
Everyone else was much less enthusiastic, especially the markets.
As soon as Truss announced her plans, interest rates spiked, the pound tanked.
And after just 44 days in office, the shortest term ever for a British prime minister, Liz Truss announced she would resign. Given the situation, I cannot deliver the mandate on which I was elected by the Conservative Party.
By the time we arrived in London in search of the real Adam Smith,
Truss's successor had just taken office, Rishi Sunak, a former chancellor of the Exchequer,
and he made clear that his economic plan wouldn't be quite so bold.
Some mistakes were made, not born of ill will or bad intentions,
quite the opposite, in fact, but mistakes nonetheless.
And so it was that Sunak took over No. 10 Downing Street in the heart of Westminster.
The man we had come to visit has an office just a short walk away.
Hello there.
Oh, hello, Eamon. Hi.
That, again, is Eamon Butler, director of the Adam Smith Institute.
The Institute's walls are adorned with Smith portraits.
One of them was on the 20-pound note for a while.
Now, I got a call from the Bank of England, their library,
and they said, do you have any good images of Adam Smith?
And I said, well, there's plenty, you know, what would you like?
And they said, well, I'm not really supposed to tell you this,
but we're thinking of putting him on a banknote.
And I thought, well, yes!
There are also some flags hanging on the walls,
the Scottish saltire in honor of Smith. There's also a big American flag, which it turns out
makes a lot of sense for the Adam Smith Institute in London would not exist were it not for America.
Let me explain. Eamon Butler grew up in the West Midlands of England, and in 1978, he got his PhD in moral philosophy from the University of St. Andrews in Scotland.
He and a couple of like-minded friends considered their professional prospects in the UK, and they didn't like what they saw.
We'd all emigrated to America, given that the British economy was plummeting, and so we joined what's called the brain drain. I spent a couple of years in America. I worked on Capitol Hill for a group of congressmen,
which was very educational because it let me understand how legislation was made,
which is a bit like making sausages, not very pleasant to watch. And then I taught philosophy
for a year in Hillsdale in Michigan. Butler was impressed with how some things were done in
America. The government didn't regulate industries as tightly as they did in the UK,
nor did they feel as compelled to nationalize all the industries as was common in the UK.
For example, in the United States, you had competition in telephones. Now, my economics
professor in St. Andrews told me that competition in telephones was theoretically impossible.
It was curious to Butler that the U.S. seemed more in sync with the free market teachings of Adam Smith than the government in the country that had produced Smith.
Just another prophet without honor in his own country.
Was the U.S. government more Smithian because the University of Chicago economists were doing such a good job promoting the invisible hand?
The message had certainly worked on Butler and his fellow British expats.
Friedman and Hayek and all of these great economists had laid the foundations, if you like, and people like us were intrigued and captured by these ideas.
So he and a couple of friends started up a free market think tank.
We'd seen lots of interesting ideas in America that we thought could work in the UK.
And originally, we thought we would swap ideas across the Atlantic.
Instead, they decided to relocate to London. This was in 1977. The Adam Smith Institute took up offices in Westminster,
and their timing turned out to be extraordinary. In 1979, Mrs. Thatcher was elected in the UK,
and we had a bit of an open goal in terms of promoting free market theories and free society
theories. If there is one political leader over the past half century
who embodied the conservative reading of Adam Smith,
the Smith of free markets, of economic liberty, of smaller government,
surely it's Margaret Thatcher. She was prime minister of the UK
from 1979 to 1990. It has been said that Thatcher carried in her handbag a copy of The Wealth of
Nations. One of the great debates of our time is about how much of your money should be spent by the state and how much you should
keep to spend on your family. Here was the big question. Would Britain be, as Adam Smith wrote
in The Wealth of Nations, a nation of shopkeepers or would it be a nation of government bureaucrats?
Thatcher sided with shopkeepers. There is no such thing as public money.
There is only taxpayers' money. And what did all this mean for Eamon Butler
and his new Adam Smith Institute? It's the most exciting time of my life.
When Mrs. Thatcher took office, what you had was an ideological administration. Before then,
politicians had all been managerialists. They were just trying to keep the show on the road. Whereas Mrs. Thatcher, daughter of a shopkeeper, she was determined to
run the economy like you would run a shop very prudently and to experiment with all sorts of
new ideas that had been off the agenda for such a long time because there was this sort of centrist
to left of center consensus. So that was quite thrilling that it was an administration which
was genuinely interested in ideas. Thatcher cut taxes, slashed government spending and curbed
the trade unions. She also set out to privatize a great many state assets and industries. It seemed
as if Thatcher was giving a great bear hug to Adam Smith and, by association, to the Adam Smith Institute.
Well, one of our first publications was on what we call quangos, quasi-autonomous non-government organizations.
They're sort of boards and committees around Whitehall that ministers appoint people to, but there's some very weird ones like the Hadrian's Wall Advisory Committee
and the Detergent and Allied Products Voluntary Notification Scheme Scrutiny Group.
And we discovered in the UK there were 3,068 of these. And we said, that's far too many. This is
just bureaucracy. Let's get rid of it. And we published that in a book, but it was a strange
book because it only had one page, but that page was 12 feet long,
which was a list of all of these quangos. So Mrs. Thatcher saw that and she got the head of the
civil service to meet up with us. And he said, well, the prime minister's told me I've got to
cut quangos. Which ones should I start with? So there was that. And then a second thing that we
sort of came up with was contracting out local
government services, repairing the roads and collecting the garbage and things like that.
We looked around the world for practical examples of where this had happened. And we discovered that
you save a lot of money and provide a much better service if you contract it out to private
companies. And again, Mrs. Thatcher saw our little pamphlet on that
and promptly, against all copyright rules, printed 20,000 copies and sent it to all of
her local government party members. I'm sure you sued, yes? We weren't too worried about it.
And then, of course, there was privatization with all the big industries, shipbuilding, steel,
railways, gas, water, electricity, trucking, telephones, all of
these things were nationalized industries. And we work on the intellectual means to
return them or take them into the private sector.
I'm sure many people listening to you will say, oh yeah, that was a turning point that was
important for an economic reform. And there are many others listening to you will say, oh, that was the darkest day ever when privatization began. So, to those in the
latter group who feel that this was a move in the wrong direction, a move that we are seeing
continuing to grow now to the point where many people feel, you know, that labor is continuing
to get squeezed and squeezed and squeezed, How do you defend or support that?
Well, when Mrs. Thatcher took office,
a third of the housing stock was owned by the local governments.
And what she did was to allow the tenants to buy their own properties
for a large discount.
So people did that because they knew that they'd be getting an asset
relatively cheaply.
But against that asset, they could borrow.
So they could start a business, for example.
So it was a great exercise in promoting a capital-owning democracy.
And that was a huge improvement.
Or if you look at telephones, one of the biggest privatization of the time in 1984, with millions of people buying the shares, that before that before then had been a state monopoly. It
had been basically run by the post office, believe it or not, telephones. So yeah, sure, mistakes
were made on the way in privatization in the UK because Britain was the first to do it. So
naturally you make mistakes. But generally speaking, we haven't reversed any of those
privatizations. Trucking is still private and telephones are still private and steel is still private and so on and so on.
The NHS, however, the National Health Service, is not private, is it?
That's correct. Yes, one of our great failures. People say it's a kind of religion in the UK that you have we do support the NHS. But it's a top-down Stalinist-style organisation,
and it's grotesquely inefficient. We're told, oh, it's the envy of the world, but nobody copies it.
So that tells you something. There's no reason why every doctor and nurse in the country should
be a civil servant, why every hospital should be a nationalised hospital. We don't do that with
anything else. If people need shoes or clothing,
we give them the money and they go out and they buy shoes and clothes. Why can't we do that with
healthcare? So you've got another new prime minister, Rishi Sunak, not nearly as that's
right as his very short-lived predecessor. But if you had maybe a couple hours today with the new prime minister to
deliver the economic gospel according to Adam Smith, what would you want to emphasize as actually
doable in this political and economic moment? Well, I would say that considerable reforms in
the government system are needed. You know, we have a huge bloated civil service. It's a complete
spaghetti, and nobody can navigate their way through it.
So why don't we just get rid of a lot of that?
Reforming the tax system and making it simple and straightforward,
we have the most complicated tax system in the world.
The planning reform, again, need to allow people to do what they like with their houses
instead of saying you can't build an extra room and things like that
when it doesn't affect anybody else.
But we have a system where, you know,
a few local residents can block an airport, for example,
and that's why it's taken 15 years to build a new runway at Heathrow.
So those sorts of reforms are just doing things
that everybody knows needs to be done,
but there's so many vested interests you have to cut through.
I asked Butler if he wanted to take a walk over to No. 10 Downing to see if we could talk our way in and present his Adam Smith-inspired advice. Butler was game. It was a lovely walk
through the old Westminster streets, some flint and brick architecture, some odes to Britain's inventive
past. These street lamps here, they're still gas, and they're the oldest street lamps in the world.
Really? Because what is now the home office used to be the gas works. Does that make sense that
they're still gas? No, it doesn't. It makes absolutely no sense at all. But it's, you know,
a nice tradition. And, you know, we do a lot of that silly stuff in Britain.
We arrive at 10 Downing Street.
There is a throng out front, some of them protesting against the state of the British economy.
I don't think any of it does any good.
I mean, I've always said if you have to go onto the streets, you've lost the arguments.
Butler and I squeeze past the throng and we walked down a barricaded path up to the
armed guard in front of number 10. Good morning. My friends are doing a radio show and we wanted
to have a chat with you. I'm not doing anything on the radio. Okay, so there would be no drop-in
visit with the prime minister. We passed the protesters again on our way out. I told Butler I had seen more
economic protest on this visit to the UK, more anger and fear than any time in my recent memory.
Well, the last time when there was real unrest was the so-called winter of discontent,
which was the winter before Mrs. Thatcher was elected. And I think it's that kind of sentiment
out there today that they're fed up with politicians you know that's why it's conservative party elected liz trust because she's
not a routine politician and it's why people voted for brexit because they were fed up with the
european way of the bureaucratic way of doing things and i suppose it's why people in america
voted for trump and why people in other european countries are voting for far-right candidates it's why people in America voted for Trump and why people in other European countries are voting for far-right candidates.
It's not that they particularly want far-right candidates.
They just don't want the centralist, bureaucratic, management-minded politicians.
For a brief moment, back when Liz Truss was prime minister and tried to channel Margaret Thatcher,
Eamon Butler and the Adam Smith Institute were poised to return to their glory days of real influence,
but it wasn't to be. With the new Sunak government that is more centralist and bureaucratic,
as Butler might put it, he seems nostalgic for the past.
I was once at a reception in Downing Street, and they were serving wine and canapes,
and some poor chap, his canape had a sort of blob of cream
or some sort of sauce on it,
and he dropped it and it splodged onto the carpet.
The Prime Minister, Mrs Thatcher, came up,
took a cloth out of her handbag and started wiping it up,
and the staff said,
Oh, it's all right, Prime Minister, you don't need to do that.
Oh, no, it's fine, I've got it now.
So that was what she was like.
She was very hands-on.
Coming up after the break,
how faithful is the Adam Smith Institute interpretation of Adam Smith?
Did you actually ever read the guy?
Because what you're saying has nothing to do with what he said.
This gets us to what has been called Das Adam Smith Problem.
There's no Das Adam Smith Problem.
Like, it's a pseudo problem.
Pseudo problem or not, we'll try to solve it.
This is Freakonomics Radio.
I'm Stephen Dubner in search of the real Adam Smith.
We'll be right back.
Eamon Butler, co-founder and director of the Adam Smith Institute in London,
was just telling us that Adam Smith and the wealth of nations
inspired Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher to privatize huge swaths of the British economy.
The water and gas and phone utilities, car and ship manufacturing,
the houses where nearly two million Britons lived, even British airways.
Butler thinks this all fit snugly with Adam Smith's view of smaller government
and that this sort of privatization is an excellent idea.
Not everyone agrees.
The real irony is that the privatization in the UK was often privatized by selling off the assets to other
governments. China, the French state. That is Mariana Mazzucato. Also, Macquarie, a very large
Australian financial company, has bought up our publicly owned green investment bank.
Big mistake, I think. Mazzucato is an economist at University College London. She thinks that certain champions of laissez-faire policies have misinterpreted and exploited Adam Smith, with privatization in the UK being a prime example.
UK privatization, one of the things it did is it not only sold it off to the private sector, but lots of different private sector companies.
So there's very little coordination.
So, say say public transport. The real question is, why did the UK government, when it sold public transport,
public rail, to, for example, Richard Branson with Virgin, why were there no conditions attached?
We could today have a low cost, accessible, modern, green, sustainable transport system. Instead, it's not sustainable,
it's not green, and it's definitely not accessible. It's extremely expensive. So conditionality,
like building into a deal when you're selling something off with strong publicly set conditions,
it doesn't mean the state does everything, but it means it has to have the confidence to say,
look, we developed this thing, we funded it. If a bit of it is going to get privatized, under what conditions to deliver a public goal?
But didn't Adam Smith want free markets, free from the interference of the state?
He didn't really mean free from the state.
When he talked about the free market, he meant free from rent, free from extraction of value from the system. Smith would have so much to say about the excess profits
that are being earned by energy and mining companies globally.
Modern day finance where you have $6 trillion in the last 10 years
having been used just to buy back shares,
to boost share prices, stock options and executive pay.
That's the modern day feudal kind of value extraction that Adam Smith would have ranted against.
If Adam Smith were forced to choose between private and state ownership of a given firm
or industry, he would almost certainly choose private. But he did warn of the tendency of
private firms to collude with one another, to fix prices and exploit the public.
Today's British public, having experienced a few decades of privatization,
seems to side with Mariana Mazzucato.
One fairly recent poll found that more than three quarters of the population
would prefer that services like gas, water, electricity, and railroads were publicly owned.
And what about the other services that governments typically provide, like education?
In Book 5 of The Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith would appear to be in favor of this.
For a very small expense, the public can facilitate, can encourage, and can even impose upon almost
the whole body of the people
the necessity of acquiring those most essential parts of education.
The public can facilitate this acquisition by establishing in every parish or district
a little school where children may be taught for a reward so moderate
that even a common laborer may afford it. So what does a Smithian on the right side
of the political spectrum, like Eamon Butler, make of this? And how can it be that right
Smithians and left Smithians come to such different conclusions when they read the same text?
Yes, because the Wealth of Nations is an enormous, elephantine, sprawling book,
and it's just full of facts and figures and
arguments, some of them not entirely consistent. So you can take Adam Smith in many different ways.
Now, I've heard you talk about Smith's advocacy or support for the government providing services
like education, infrastructure, law and order, and things like that. But then I've heard you say
that that argument, which occurred in the last book of The Wealth of Nations, book five,
you've said that he was rushed, you thought. Are you saying that he didn't really support
that much government intervention? Well, it took him 15 years to write this book.
And I think at the end of it, his friends would say, oh, come on, Smith, old chap,
you know, it's about time you got this finished. And so I think the final chapter is a little bit rushed.
Look, you're the Smith scholar, so who am I to argue with you? But everything I've read about
him and by him suggests he was, maybe perfectionist is not quite the right word, but I have heard him
called that. You really think he would publish The Wealth of Nations after working on it for
so many years with an incomplete idea of the degree to which the government should provide services like
education and transportation?
Yes, because I don't think that was the main thrust of his argument.
The main thrust of his argument was all the previous stuff about how the economy works,
and in particular, that restrictions on trade and commerce produce bad results, that they don't maximize human welfare.
So it wasn't his main thing.
And I think his publisher was on to him as well to get the thing out.
I think his poor chap was probably under a lot of pressure.
So to those in the modern era who want to use Smith to argue that government should, let's say, be massively downsized,
do you suggest they just
skip book five because it will? Well, if it was me, I wouldn't read the book at all because it's
enormous, 900 pages. 90 pages of it are what he calls a digression on the price of silver.
And it's in this 18th century language and it's really just impenetrable.
It may strike you as odd that the director of the Adam Smith Institute says we shouldn't actually read Adam Smith.
I think it's odd.
But remember what the economic historian Robert Heilbrunner once wrote.
No economist's name is more frequently invoked than that of Adam Smith, and no economist's works are less frequently read. But there is an even bigger issue. If you do read
Adam Smith and you read both his books, The Theory of Moral Sentiments and The Wealth of Nations,
you might conclude there is not one Adam Smith, but two Adam Smiths. Because this riddle was explored primarily
by Smith scholars in Germany in the 19th century,
this has come to be known as
Das Adam Smith Problem.
Glory Lou again.
Which was this theory that Smith changed his mind
or had a change of heart
between writing The Theory of Moral Sentiments in 1759
and The Wealth of Nations in 1776.
In other words, how could someone who wrote a book about the theory of moral sentiments and
the deep humanism we all strive for also be the person who wrote this guidebook to unfettered
capitalism? That's Das Adam Smith problem, essentially, yes?
Right, exactly.
And why did this happen in Germany?
Oh, I don't know.
German scholars are weird.
One reason why I think it happened in Germany and not in England and not in the United States
is because German scholars were really interested in Adam Smith as a thinker,
recovering the philosophical consistency of Smith's works,
as opposed to like what was
happening in England and what was happening in the United States, which is that people
didn't really care about what Smith actually said. Smith is really just whittled down to
the ideology of free trade. And what does Lew think of Das Adam Smith problem?
Any self-respecting Smith scholar will just be like, there's no Das Adam Smith problem.
Like, it's a pseudo problem.
Dennis Rasmussen, the Smith scholar at Syracuse University, agrees.
I think most Smith scholars today would say that this problem isn't a problem, that the two are perfectly compatible.
Sympathy in the theory of moral sentiments doesn't entail or require any kind of altruism or other directedness. It's perfectly compatible with people being
self-interested. And likewise, that the emphasis on self-interest in The Wealth of Nations wasn't
advocating that people be selfish, wasn't advocating that greed is good, to use the line
from the movie, but rather trying to describe how people interact. And also, the argument is a reliance on
self-interest can be liberating in the sense that if you rely on people's self-interest,
you don't have to rely on their benevolence. You don't have to act like a dog at a table
begging for scraps, right? You can count on people acting out of their self-interest.
There's a way in which this produces a sense of personal independence.
It does seem that the political right and the economic right and conservatives have done a
better job using Smith to advance their arguments, whereas the left and liberals
have neglected Smith to their peril. And there's a lot in his writing that I would
think they would want to use.
So there's raging debate in Smith scholarship among people who are sometimes called left
Smithians and right Smithians about where he would fit on today's political spectrum. I think once
a thinker has been claimed by one side reasonably successfully in this case, it's kind of hard for
the other side to reclaim them. They often just turn to a different thinker and find that to be
an easier path to take. But don't you think that's kind of a shame? Because when you read Smith,
there's a lot there for everyone, I would say. And in fact, I would argue that he is a really good thinker if you want to, I'm not saying unite the political extremes, but show that there's a very broad middle, that you can be really pro-market and really pro-human at the same time. So, wouldn't it be nice? It would absolutely be nice, yes. The different elements of Smith's thought that would push him in different directions, right?
He shows this very deep and palpable concern for the lot of the poor.
The wages, the conditions of the working poor are really his central measuring stick for the wealth of nations, for how wealthy an economy is.
It's not, you know, the holdings of the affluent few, but the ease of everyday people to attain the necessities of life. On the other hand, you know, there are elements of his thought
that push him toward the right of today's political spectrum. He really does distrust government. He
distrust politicians, both their abilities and often even their intentions. And so, there are
elements of his thought that push him in both directions. It's hard to know, to be honest,
where he would stand on today's political spectrum with regard to a lot of these questions, because
he saw the two as going hand in hand, right? A lot of the government programs that he's most
worried about are there to benefit the rich, and they unfortunately also harm the poor, right?
They're rent-seeking things that companies have, as he says, extorted from the legislature for the
support of
their own absurd and oppressive monopolies. They make ordinary goods more expensive. He thinks that
shrinking government, getting government less involved in the economy benefits the poor. What
would he think today about a government program designed explicitly to help the poor? It's really
hard to say. Is it his concern for the poor or his distrust of government that would win out at the end of the day? That's hard to know. The more we've been looking for the real Adam Smith these
past couple episodes, the more I've come to believe this Adam Smith problem may be real,
but it's not the same problem the German scholars were concerned with.
As Dennis Rasmussen just explained, it is not so hard to reconcile
the wealth of nations, Adam Smith, and the theory of moral sentiments, Adam Smith.
I think Das Adam Smith problem today is simply that most of the economists and politicians and
others who look to the wealth of nations for guidance have simply never read the theory of
moral sentiments.
Here is one such economist.
I thought, well, I don't have to read this because it's not economics. It's philosophy or psychology, you could call it.
And I didn't read it forever.
Most economists don't.
That is Russ Roberts.
He got his PhD from the University of Chicago during the era when Milton Friedman was turning
Adam Smith into
the poster boy of free market economics. Roberts went on to a long academic career at institutions
including George Mason University and the Hoover Institution at Stanford, places known for the kind
of conservatism or libertarianism that Adam Smith currently represents. And where is Roberts today?
I am president of Shalem College in Jerusalem, Israel. I am the host of Econ Talk, the podcast
and author of How Adam Smith Can Change Your Life, an unexpected guide to human nature and happiness.
So, question one, how did Adam Smith change your life?
So, my book is an attempt to bring to the modern reader Adam Smith's forgotten masterpiece,
The Theory of Moral Sentiments.
The Theory of Moral Sentiments tries to answer the question, why do we do anything that isn't just for ourselves?
Because we are self-interested.
We're not selfish, although some of us are, but our nature is to be self-interested. We're not selfish, although some of us are, but our nature is to be self-interested. We put ourselves at the center of our universe, and yet we often do kind and
thoughtful things for others. And Smith was interested in understanding why that was the case,
and that was what his book was about. And I didn't read it forever.
What was that experience like, reading it?
You know, I picked it up. I read the first page. I had no idea what it was talking about. It kind of starts in midstream. Read the second page. I read about,
I don't know, five, ten pages, and I thought, I don't really get this book at all. And so,
I persevered and eventually fell in love with the book. Adam Smith's a brilliant writer. He's a
brilliant stylist. He's one of the rare people writing in the 18th century that you
can read with utter delight and pleasure most of the time. He forces you to look at yourself
and realize what makes you tick, what pushes your buttons, rings your bells,
tightens your shoelaces. He understands our flaws. He understands our need for self-deception.
There's one passage from The Theory of Moral Sentiments that Robert spends
a lot of time on in his book. If you're going to read just one paragraph of The Theory of Moral
Sentiments, this might be the one. Man naturally desires not only to be loved, but to be lovely, or to be that thing which is the natural and proper object of love.
He naturally dreads not only to be hated, but to be hateful, or to be that thing which is the
natural and proper object of hatred. He desires not only praise, but praiseworthiness, or to be
that thing which, though it should be praised by nobody is
however the natural and proper object of praise. He dreads not only blame, but blameworthiness,
or to be that thing which though it should be blamed by nobody is however the natural and
proper object of blame. We want to be appreciated.
We want to matter.
And what he's saying there is that not only do we want to be praised
and honored and respected, but we want to earn that honestly.
We want to be praiseworthy.
We want to be honorable.
We want to merit the respect of others.
And then he says something really extraordinary.
He says, because we care, because we want to feel important, because we want to matter,
there are two ways to get there.
One is to pursue fame, wealth, and power.
Well, that's pretty primal, yeah.
The quieter path is to pursue wisdom and virtue, which he advocates for.
He says the pursuit of wealth, here's the person who wrote The Wealth of Nations,
says the pursuit of wealth is a fool's game.
It's going to degrade you.
You're going to do things you're going to be ashamed of and that you'll want to hide.
After you read The Theory of Moral Sentiments and started thinking and talking like this, did your economist colleagues think you'd gone soft? Yeah, economic decision-making is basically expected utility
maximization, which is just a fancy phrase for you do the thing that gives you the most pleasure
relative to pain as best as you can anticipate it. And of course, you make mistakes and things
that you thought were going to turn out well don't all the time. That's not a rejection of
economics. But I think the essence of the
economist approach is that we're constantly weighing our pleasure and pain on a daily basis
and trying to project how we're going to feel about the decisions we make. That's really not
the nature of the life well lived. It's not just about racking up utility points. And I think economists often forget this.
They focus on what's measurable. So in that sense, I've rejected a lot of the utilitarian
foundation of my field. You are a particularly good person to speak with about this because
you've got an appreciation for the full Adam Smith that many economists don't, but you're also
a University of Chicago guy. And in her new book,
Adam Smith's America, the political scientist, Gloria Liu, argues that it was that University
of Chicago economics department, especially Friedman and Stigler, who sort of cherry-picked
Smith's writing and turned him into a patron saint of free market capitalism in a way that a closer
reading of Smith,
especially the theory of moral sentiments, wouldn't support. Can you untangle this for me?
I mean, I don't mean to cast aspersions on Friedman and Stigler, both of whom were
amazingly sharp and shrewd and powerful economists, but I'm curious to know whether
you think that they hijacked the reputation to the detriment of the field.
I would say it a little differently. I would say that Milton Friedman is the patron saint
of free market economics, and he saw Adam Smith as a cousin, if not a close relative,
even closer relative, a brother in arms. I think that's roughly fair to Smith. I don't think there's anything in the theory of
moral sentiments that is an indictment of what we would normally call free market economics.
I know progressives have tried to claim Smith. Certainly, there are things in Smith that have
a progressive aspect to them. Often, it sometimes requires quoting him out of context, leaving out
the next paragraph or the one before.
But there are things in Smith that certainly conflict with standard free market dogma.
You write that Adam Smith has a way of saying things that get into your bones.
Can you talk about that a little bit more?
Smith was a great writer. He's a great communicator.
I think great writing is
underrated. It is no small feat to coin a phrase like the invisible hand. Smith used the phrase
the invisible hand twice in his two books, once in each. I would suggest that in neither one
is he using it in the way that modern people use it or modern economists.
In modern economics and public policy, it has come to mean that we don't have to worry about
certain problems because the market will take care of them. And that's the magic of the invisible
hand. Now, that gets laughed at a lot. The truth is, it is an extraordinary phenomenon that is underappreciated, but it should not be overappreciated. The underappreciated part is that over the last maybe 10, 15 years, hundreds of millions of Chinese citizens and people have moved from the countryside into the cities of China. Hundreds of millions. One of the greatest migrations, probably the greatest migration of people in human history, certainly from rural to urban areas.
Well, I assume a lot of those people started sending their kids to school.
And I assume a lot of those kids started using pencils. That ever affect your life in America?
Do you ever say, oh, I wish I could find a pencil, but of course I can't because they're all going
to the Chinese. Oh, there must have been a department set up to deal with that shortage, but there wasn't. That's
what modern economists mean by the invisible hand. We didn't have to worry about the availability of
pencils. That's the invisible hand. It's invisible, so we don't fully appreciate it. Now, you don't
want to carry it too far. It doesn't solve every problem. It doesn't solve pollution.
A lot of things require legislation, regulation, and so on.
Smith was not an anarchist.
His modern disciples, most of them are not anarchists.
They understand that not all problems solve themselves.
But the fact that any do is quite remarkable. My sense from reading your book on Adam Smith, my sense is that it's an act of acknowledging
who you were and wanted to be as a human, but it's sort of gotten away from. I want to know how
reading that book and then wrestling with that book and writing your own book about it,
I want to know how that changed you.
A very hard question to answer.
Because to me, reading your book felt like one long epiphany.
It was an intellectual but also sort of a spiritual and moral epiphany.
Most of us, when we have an epiphany, we come out a little bit different. And it may not be permanent, but also sort of a spiritual and moral epiphany. Most of us, when we have an
epiphany, we come out a little bit different. And it may not be permanent, but it may be. So
that's what I want to know. I mean, reading the theory of moral sentiments,
if you push your way through it, forces you to think about how you live your life. Economists,
you know, we think about incentives all the time. but often we get lazy and we focus on monetary incentives because they're everywhere.
And Upton Sinclair said it beautifully, it is difficult to get a man to understand something when his salary depends on not understanding it.
And that's the truth.
You are often pushed and pulled emotionally by who pays your salary and what they want from you.
When I read Adam Smith's book, The Theory of World Sentiments,
I realized that, you know, there's a lot of other things that push and pull people.
Now, come on, didn't you know that before?
Of course I did.
But reading Smith forced me to think of it and have it be at the front of my mind,
that we want to be loved. And so when you read that and you think of it and have it be at the front of my mind, that we want to be loved. And so,
when you read that and you think about it and you write a book about it, as I did,
it wouldn't be surprising that I started to also begin to think more
deeply, more focused on questions of what is the life well lived? I have trouble not thinking about it. Adam Smith led Russ Roberts to rethink himself, and it left him better off.
Over the past couple episodes, we have been rethinking Adam Smith,
and I would like to think it is leaving us better off.
If nothing else, we're starting to see him as more than the cardboard cutout he's been turned into.
Smith was a philosopher, but also fiercely practical.
He was a macro thinker, but micro as well.
He was a radical in some ways, but also respectful
and even acceptable to those with whom he disagreed.
So coming up next time in our third and final episode,
what would Adam Smith make of the current global economy?
He would have been appalled
by our brand of casino capitalism.
He thinks getting people out of poverty is good.
He thinks high wages and low profits are good.
It's difficult to know because he was a Whig.
And we'll head back to Scotland
to say goodbye to the man himself.
I like the grave.
I think it fits his personality and I think it fits his world and his place in it.
That's next time on the show.
Until then, take care of yourself and, if you can, someone else too. Thank you. Pinsky and mixed by Greg Rippin with help from Jeremy Johnston. We also had help in London from
Rob Double, Alex de La Salle and London Broadcast Studios and help in Scotland from Josh Nixon and
Upload Studios. Thanks also to John Ewell for reading Adam Smith. Our staff also includes
Morgan Levy, Ryan Kelly, Catherine Moncure, Alina Cullman, Rebecca Lee Douglas, Julie Canfor,
Eleanor Osborne, Jasmine Klinger, Gabriel Roth, and me, Stephen Dubner.
Our theme song is Mr. Fortune by The Hitchhikers.
Our main music is composed by Luis Guerra.
Big thanks to NotSensibles for letting us play some of their amazing 1979 song, I'm In Love, with Margaret Thatcher.
As always, thanks for listening.
I'm thinking of this quote.
Always, like, you know where it is, and then of course right when you want to find it, you can't find it.
The Freakonomics Radio Network.
The hidden side of everything. Stitcher.