Freakonomics Radio - 72. Lottery Loopholes and Deadly Doctors
Episode Date: April 25, 2012What do you do when smart people keep making stupid mistakes? And: are we a nation of financial illiterates? ...
Transcript
Discussion (0)
There's something Peter Tufano wants to know about you.
If you had to, could you come up with $2,000 in 30 days?
That's the question he asked a whole bunch of people in 13 countries, including the U.S.
Why $2,000? Because an auto transmission is about $1,500.
Most estimates of what everyday emergencies are about are in that order of magnitude.
If you were to have a sick or ailing relative on the other side of the country and you had to buy full-price plane tickets, it could easily be that amount.
And then why this language come up with as opposed to save?
Because what we wanted to see if people had access to resources between savings and credit and friends and family. And about half of Americans are not able to come up with $2,000 in 30 days,
which means that they stand only one emergency or crisis
away from really quite dire circumstances.
Tufano has spent more than three decades in academia,
first at Harvard and now at Oxford Said Business School,
trying to figure out why consumers do what they do.
He wants to know how many checks you write and for what, how much you borrow and why,
and especially this, why Americans are so bad at saving money.
Our personal savings rate has been plunging for more than 20 years, actually went negative
in 2006.
The Great Recession
shocked it back into the positive. It's been at about 5% since 2008. But now it's started to fall
again. Think about what Tofano just said. Half of us don't have access to enough money to survive
one breakdown. And it's not just people who don't earn a lot of money. Tofano found that more than 20% of the households earning more than $150,000 a year couldn't come up with that $2,000 in 30 days.
Americans are, however, pretty good at spending money.
For example, this year, we'll spend about $60 billion, it's about $520 per household, on something that isn't very practical.
Good evening, ladies and gentlemen, and welcome to number 999,999,999th draw of for National Lottery.
From APM, American Public Media, and WNYC, this is Freakonomics Radio.
Today, instead of that scratch-off ticket, how about a no-lose lottery?
Plus, are we a nation of financial illiterates? Here's your host, Stephen Dubner.
Melissa Carney is an economist at the University of Maryland. When she was in grad school,
she used to stop at a little store in the evenings to get her milk and orange juice,
and she would notice that a lot of people were buying lottery tickets. And so I just sort of started chatting
with the vendor, and he said, oh, I have people coming in spending hundreds, thousands of dollars
on lottery tickets a month, a year. And so being a graduate student, I just downloaded some data
and started playing around and was struck in particular people do spend a lot of money buying
lottery tickets. So let's walk through some of the numbers on lottery gambling. In particular, people do spend a lot of money buying lottery tickets.
So let's walk through some of the numbers on lottery gambling.
In the U.S., how many people play the lottery?
Half of U.S. adults surveyed say they play the lottery at some point in the past year.
And would that make it the most popular form of gambling in the U.S.? Yeah, so by far.
So two out of three American adults report gambling, and it's 50% say they play lottery.
The next closest is casino, which is about one in five adults.
And why do so many people play the lottery?
Because it's fun. For a dollar or two, you buy the chance to dream, to dream big. And this remarkable bargain illustrates a phenomenon, a probabilistic oddity
that economists call skewness. That's the idea that there's some big prize way out there
that corresponds to a very small odd, but there's some potential of capturing that.
And that's what your typical money market account can't give you, right? So
you could, you can have $1,500 in your money market account, and every month, you might earn,
you know, $1 on it. But there's no chance in every month, will you earn $100,000 or even $10,000?
Now, I know, as an economist, you're not trained to answer this question. But as a human being,
tell me, why is skewness so important to us?
That's the chance of changing your life, right? That's the return, you know, that's the big win
outcome that might allow you to buy a beach house or, you know, to send your kids to college,
you know, or if it's less far out in the distribution, that might be what you need to
make a down payment on a house or buy a car or throw your daughter the wedding you want to throw her.
For a lot of people, skewness has an irresistible appeal.
And so a handful of researchers like Melissa Carney are trying to harness its power, the unlikely chance of changing your life with a big prize in order to solve America's low savings rate.
The idea is a new financial product that combines the thrill of the lottery with the goal of maybe accumulating more than $2,000 in a savings account.
So that a broken transmission doesn't become a full-blown crisis.
Here's Carney's pitch.
So we know Americans like gambling.
They always have.
The majority of them do it, and they're going to keep doing it.
And so what we do is take seriously the idea that people want some small chance of winning a large sum of money.
That market, that asset is missing from the
American landscape. Low wealth individuals, the only asset available to them that gives them some
chance of accumulating a large amount of money is the state lottery. And in fact, a recent national
survey of a thousand adults, one in five American adults said their greatest chance of accumulating, you know, hundreds of thousands of dollars was through the lottery.
That number jumps to 40% for folks making less than $25,000 a year.
So, you know, a lot of Americans think the lottery is their only chance at winning big sums of money, why don't we take that appetite for gambling, for a product like this, and attach
it to a savings vehicle that offers some positive return? It's a win-win situation.
This win-win situation has already worked in many other countries. It's called a prize-linked
savings plan, or PLS. Here's how it works.
People deposit money in a bank or maybe they buy a government bond.
And instead of receiving the going rate of interest, they'll get a smidge less, maybe a quarter of a percentage point less. And all those smidges are then gathered up into a prize pool.
And cash prizes are distributed from that pool, just like lottery winnings, maybe
once a month to a few lucky winners. And the losers, well, there are no losers, really.
Everyone keeps his original savings. So you could call a PLS plan a no-lose lottery.
It's the kind of idea that can really catch fire.
My name is Robert Cape.
I worked at First National Bank for 11 years where I headed up the investment product house.
And our focus was trying to look at ways of growing
the funding base of the bank.
First National Bank is in South Africa. In 2005, it started what would
turn out to be a phenomenally successful PLS program. It was born out of South Africa's
financial problems as the country struggled to put the apartheid era behind it. Millions of
black South Africans did not use banks for anything.
Robert Cape wanted to find a way to get some of them in the door.
Now, in South Africa, because so much of the population is unbanked,
so much of the savings are literally sitting under mattresses.
Now, this has got a double effect.
The one that it does really do badly at is it removes that funding from the mainstream banking environment.
So it can't be harnessed to lend out and fund economic growth because retail funding tends to come in from consumers and then get lent out to businesses who can then create jobs.
So that was the one problem. And the second problem was really that these people with the money under mattresses were excluded from the banking system. And by being excluded from the banking system, you miss out on so many benefits, which really help with people's individual development. For example, developing credit records, being less exposed to having your money stolen or lost on the way home. But Cape's bank had a problem.
Interest rates at the time weren't keeping up with inflation.
So putting your money in a plain old savings account might actually erode its value.
Cape's job was to make it worthwhile for customers to deposit new money. So instead of simply offering an account with a scrawny interest rate,
he would offer an account with practically no interest at all, but it came with the chance for a really big payday.
So what we did, we literally pooled all of these little 0.25% of interest.
And then what we did, we paid out that interest in lump sums to a few people.
So we paid out 150 people a month in lump sum prizes. So the first
prize would be a million rand, which is an enormous amount of money in South Africa.
And then there were three prizes of 100,000 rand, and then we went down to 20,000 rand and a few
prizes of 1,000 rand. So let's say I live in South Africa, I take the money I'm earning and
put it under my mattress or maybe buy some high-risk equities.
You're offering me the security of a bank account and the excitement of a chance to win a million rand, right?
What do you call this idea?
We call it the million-a-month account.
Mama.
And Mama became the trivial name for it.
And you're the man who gave birth to Mama.
Yes.
How successful was Mama?
Hugely. Probably too successful for its own good.
Mama attracted more than a million new customers to Capes Bank.
Other banks in South Africa took note and complained to regulators.
And then Capes Bank heard from someone else, the South African National Lottery.
Well, we engaged with them before we launched.
We wrote to them and asked them their opinion on the product.
They wrote us a letter back saying that they didn't think it was a lottery.
They thought it fell into a promotional competition, part of the legislation,
and that suggested that we just comply with the requirements of the promotional competition.
And we launched, and then nothing was heard from them for six or so months.
And then they contacted us to say, actually, they don't like what we're doing,
and they think that it's a lottery now.
So when you were starting out and there was very little money in your coffers,
they thought it wasn't a lottery.
But then after it got going for a while, and you had how much, a couple hundred million dollars?
About $200 million.
But more importantly, it was over a million customers that we had brought in.
And the National Lottery Board changed its mind then.
It thought, oh, that thing that we said a little while ago was not a lottery now looks a lot like a lottery.
Yes.
And what did they do then? Well, we first engaged with them and tried to discuss it.
But it was very clear that they were in no position or not wanting to even try to discuss what the issues were.
And so they took us to court to have us closed down.
In court, the South African National Lottery argued that First National Bank's PLS program infringed upon the lottery's domain, and it noted that PLS customers were surrendering
their rightful interest payment on their savings.
As opposed, that is, to surrendering the entire price of a lottery ticket.
Anyway, the court sided with the lottery and the PLS program was shut down.
Robert Cape stands by the program's success.
He says that 20% of the PLS accounts were opened by people who were previously unbanked. In 2009, after First National Bank's PLS program was shut down,
Cape was invited to Washington to talk to federal banking officials about its success.
Now, a bank in the U.S. can't set up a no-lose lottery either.
Why not? Because the only legal lotteries here are those that are run by the states themselves. Nice monopoly if you can get
it, right? State lotteries generate billions in revenues. And so while most state houses might
like to help their citizens save more money, they may not be willing to pit their
own lotteries against a rival lottery run by a bank.
But in 2009, the same year that Mama was shut down in South Africa, Peter Tufano and some
colleagues found a legal loophole in Michigan that let them set up a PLS plan there with
some credit unions.
Here's Dave Adams, CEO of the Michigan
Credit Union League. You know, banking can actually be pretty boring. It's not like we go to
social events and talk about how much we're saving and talk about a great new feature on our new
checking account. So what people want and need is a fun way to save. And in Michigan, we've come up
with what we think will accomplish that. It's a program
called Save to Win. And what it is, is it's using a lottery concept so that for every $25 they put
into one of these one-year certificates of deposit, they're going to get a chance at cash
prizes. And the cash prizes are given out every month by participating credit unions ranging from $50 to $500.
And then there's a grand prize at the end of the year, an opportunity to win a $100,000 grand prize.
So even with a sputtering economy and unappetizing interest rates, a handful of credit unions in Michigan opened 16,000 new savings
accounts. Who were these new customers? More than 60% of them had spent money on the lottery or
gambling in the previous six months, and 46% of them currently had no savings account. One new
customer was Billie June Smith. She's 88 years old. Said she was never very good at saving money,
much preferred to play the lottery.
But when she learned about her credit union's
save-to-win plan,
she started buying $25 certificates of deposit.
And she was the first grand prize winner.
So you put $75 of your own money
into a credit union savings account.
Right.
And as a result, you were entered into a lottery for which you won $100,000.
Right.
Well, that sounds like a pretty good deal to me.
What do you think?
Well, it is.
It has helped me a lot.
Now tell me what you've done with the money, Billy.
Well, my place is a double wide
and I had bought that way back when I retired. And we have removed the siding and put new siding
on it. We done it ourselves. My daughter and her husband live with me now. And I've had to replace the furnace just a month ago.
And I've put in water softer.
And I have put my money aside for the taxes.
And I do have another savings that I don't touch for just so long. And I can add to it
then. Now, what about all the save to win customers in Michigan who didn't win? Well,
they're on their way to their own reward, passing Peter Tufano's test.
They'll have money in the bank when a transmission conks out or when they need to fly across the country to visit a sick relative.
Timothy Flauka is executive director of the Doorways to Dreams Fund, which Tufano co-founded and which tries to bring new financial ideas like PLS to low and moderate income
consumers. Last year, Flauka says, was a pretty good one. So in 2011, Nebraska, North Carolina,
and Washington state all have passed bills that explicitly authorize prize-linked savings or
savings promotion raffles for credit unions. A number of other states have introduced bills or were looking at bills.
So we view all of that as very positive.
The PLS idea is making headway outside of credit unions too, like a new for-profit program
called Save Up, which rewards customers at thousands of banks for depositing money or
paying down debt. And in Alabama, where one foundation is
offering a $20,000 prize to encourage low-income families to invest their tax refund rather than
spend it. I know what you're thinking. You're thinking, wow, this PLS idea sounds great. An interesting, fiscally responsible, even fun way to encourage people to save more money.
So what's stopping it from going big time?
Coming up on Freakonomics Radio, we'll hear from some people who do not want it to go big time.
State lottery commissioners, to be precise.
And we brought the idea to someone at the U.S. Treasury Department.
He doesn't like it so much either. From WNYC and APM American Public Media, this is Freakonomics Radio.
Here's your host, Stephen Dubner.
The biggest lottery in the United States is run by New York State. Gordon Medenica, the state lottery director,
says that 75% of New Yorkers play,
generating nearly $8 billion in annual sales.
But in order to get there, New York,
like most states that have a lottery,
had to rewrite its existing laws that prohibit gambling.
New York first began in 1967, and it was the second state after New Hampshire to come in.
What was the original impetus?
Was it a budget shortfall essentially?
Did the state feel we need money?
We can void this ban on gambling in the state and come up with a way to do it?
I think it was both a desire to raise money and also I think it was a recognition that playing was going on anyway and it was
an attempt to tax and regulate an activity that they knew was very common among citizens.
And whether you go back to the numbers games that existed in urban areas and quite frankly
still exist or those kinds of activities and even sports betting today, which of course
technically is illegal but we all know is a huge business.
I think there was a recognition on the part of lawmakers that much like prohibition, better
to tax and regulate than to ostensibly call something illegal and pretend it doesn't
go on.
State governments do more than tax and regulate their lotteries. They take a big cut
for themselves. Now, in gambling circles, the commission taken by whoever operates the game
is known as the rake. With state lotteries, the rake can be as high as 60 percent, which means
that as little as 40 percent of the money taken in from ticket sales ends up in the
pool that pays the winners. The rest of the money usually goes to education and to cover overhead,
marketing, sales commissions. Now, compare the lotteries rake to the slot machines in a casino.
They pay out more than 90%, meaning a rake of 10%, meaning the state lotteries are, how to put this politely, extremely aggressive.
Yeah, oh yeah, it's a lot of money they take off.
Here's Melissa Carney again, the Maryland economist who studies the lottery.
Consumers are paying a very high price to buy this type of product. They can't get it from anywhere else legally. And then they have the lottery
commissions have the mandate to increase revenue. So they innovate, they advertise, they market.
Yeah, they sort of behave like monopolists. What do we know about people who play the lottery?
What's, for instance, the socioeconomic breakdown?
Okay, so this surprises a lot of people,
but people throughout the socioeconomic distribution
play state lotteries.
And so it's roughly 50 to 60% of men,
roughly 50 to 60% of women,
roughly 50 to 60% of people across the education spectrum.
So people with high school dropouts,
high school degree, college graduates. And when you look at the absolute dollars reported spending, it's not that different
across the income distribution. So sort of lower income households spend about as much in dollar
terms as higher income households. The flip side of that, of course, is that it winds up being a
larger share of lower income households' total spending.
So the people who can least afford to play the lottery buy just as many tickets as people who make a lot of money, which is why scholars like Carney and Peter Tufano think that prize-linked
savings or PLS plans could help America's pathetic savings rate. For a while, Tufano actually had
the New York State Lottery
looking into a collaboration.
But Gordon Medenica,
the lottery director,
told us that he did the math
and he just didn't think
that a no-lose lottery
could compete with the gigantic
state lottery payouts.
I asked Leo DiBenigno,
the state lottery director in Florida,
what he thought of the PLS plan
that Michigan credit unions have been offering.
From a purely lottery perspective, I think the Florida lottery is the only entity in Florida that can operate a lottery game.
So I've got to say that it probably sounds illegal under current Florida law.
States protect their lotteries because the lottery is bringing lots of money for the states
and look for that money to increase potentially big time. The Justice Department just cleared the
way for state lotteries to put their games online. Gordon Medenica, New York's lottery director,
says he was thrilled with the new ruling. I mean, who could blame him? Now, some of that money goes to education and other
worthy causes. But as Leo DiBenigno admits, that's not what motivates people to play.
Leo DiBenigno, Jr.: People play the lottery to win. They like the prizes. They like the
excitement. They like the fun, the possibility of winning sometimes $10, $20, $50 and sometimes
many multi-multi, multi millions of dollars.
I think the funding to education is ancillary.
It's an extra bonus that the public views the lottery as a different and unique and fun way to be able to fund at least some of the things that our education system needs.
The lottery has famously been called a tax on the stupid. The odds are
terrible because the state rakes a huge amount off the top, far more than any casino or horse
track would dare take. And they convert your hard-earned cash into an extra school's tax.
Now, you can understand why state lottery commissioners
like things just the way they are.
But what about the federal officials
who work on consumer protection, things like that?
What about someone like the assistant secretary
for financial institutions at the Treasury Department?
That was the position Michael Barr held
when I interviewed him about PLS programs.
I asked Barr if he ever played the lottery.
I haven't really played the lottery.
I think probably if I went back over my 45 years, I may have bought a scratch ticket or two in my 20s.
Now, why do you not play the lottery?
It's a fool's errand.
As you undoubtedly know, there are a handful of people who will make some money out of the lottery.
But most people most of the time will lose money.
It's not a great way of spending one's scarce resources. I don't know if you're aware of the pilot program that's been happening up in Michigan with the eight credit unions where a prize-linked savings program is actually underway.
Are you familiar at all with that called the Save to Win program?
Trevor Burrus I have not actually studied that. very simple reality, which is that it's typically illegal, that a private institution
like a bank or a credit union is not allowed to run a lottery according to state law, that
state law typically forbids gambling and in order to allow a state, let's say, to run
a lottery itself, there's a loophole that must be written and those loopholes have been
written.
Most states do have their own lotteries.
But for someone else to come in and do it, it would be illegal. If you looked at the landscape
and thought in my role in treasury here, I would like to encourage people to save more.
I'd like to make it worthwhile for them to save more and I'd like to remove barriers that prevent
them from participating in projects that let them save more.
Would you be in favor of sponsoring or trying to get rolling some legislation that would allow for a widespread deployment of prize-linked savings?
Do you think that's something that one doesn't have to pick is not the wisest course of action unless it's something that's absolutely essential to take on.
And I wouldn't have put that in the category of dollars are being spent on lottery tickets every year, which you call the fool's game. offer bank savings accounts that – whereby a customer can put in $100, enter a lottery,
maybe win, probably not, but maybe, and keep the $100.
Why isn't that something that's worth considering even in a politically fractious
environment when the potential benefit, getting people to save more, seems to be much larger than the potential downside
of angering some state lottery commissioners, let's say?
Steve, I think there are lots of different ways
of encouraging greater savings among all American families,
and I think we should continue to innovate and to try new approaches.
I think that the question that you posed
is potentially one aspect of one way to do that.
I don't think we yet know enough from the research to say it's the kind of thing that we think needs to happen on a wide scale in order to be effective.
And I think that we have a number of potential strategies to help meet the needs of American families to save that we haven't really fully explored
and that maybe raise a somewhat lower set of issues and barriers.
All right. So Treasury doesn't like prize-linked savings accounts.
Lottery commissioners don't like the idea. Maybe you don't like it either.
Maybe you think people ought to save money on their own.
But you know what?
We don't.
People respond to incentives.
And for a lot of us, the incentive to save for retirement, for emergencies, for whatever, is weak.
Why?
Well, because the payoff is abstract and it's too far in the future. It's the opposite of skewness.
Now, this dilemma doesn't just apply to saving money. Think of a school kid, a third or fourth grader.
You want me to do what? To bust my butt in school for 10 more years and then go to college just to get some job that I probably
won't even like? Or think about crime and punishment. If you look at the data, it turns
out that the death penalty, for instance, does not work as a crime deterrent. Why? Because,
as it's currently practiced at least, with the punishment waiting so far out in the future through a maze of delays and appeals, the incentive simply isn't strong enough to stop me from doing the crime right now.
Sometimes you need stronger incentives or maybe some good smoke and mirrors.
That's kind of what a prize-linked savings plan could offer. In a country where
it's easy to borrow your way into bankruptcy, where you can buy lottery tickets whenever you
buy a loaf of bread, PLS is like a big neon billboard that turns a boring old savings account
into an exaggeration of itself. Sticks money in here, it says,
and you just might hit a big payday.
And even if you don't,
well, your money still belongs to you.
I'll buy that for a dollar.
Wouldn't you? Coming up on Freakonomics Radio, if you can't coke someone into to be their own doctor, teaching everyone to be their own mechanic.
Not only is it inefficient, but it has a sort of culture of blaming the consumer.
America's financial illiteracy in a moment. From WNYC and APM American Public Media, this is Freakonomics Radio.
Here's your host, Stephen Dubner. In the mid-19th century, Vienna General Hospital was considered a world-class research center.
But the hospital's maternity ward did not have such a good reputation.
If you came in to have a doctor deliver your baby, you stood a 10 to 15 percent chance of dying from what was called childbed fever. Childbed fever is an infection primarily
of the uterus, and it spreads out through the tubes into the abdominal cavity of women immediately
after they have given birth. That's Sherwin Newland. He's a professor of medicine at Yale.
He wrote a book called The Doctor's Plague about the situation at Vienna General.
In 1847, a young Hungarian-born doctor named Ignaz Semmelweis joined the staff there.
He was horrified by the situation, and Semmelweis went digging in the numbers for a clue.
Now, here was something strange.
There were two separate maternity wards in the hospital,
one staffed by doctors, who were all male,
and the other by midwives, who were female.
The death rate in the midwives' ward was far lower,
so it seemed to be something the doctors were doing.
But what?
Then a clue came in the form of a tragedy.
A colleague of Semmelweis's died after getting gangrene.
He had pricked his finger with a knife while giving a lesson in autopsy.
And Semmelweis was away on a brief vacation when this happened. to study scrupulously the autopsy findings of his friend and noted that they were just like the autopsy findings
of women with childbed fever who were dying.
His conclusion?
Doctors were carrying what he called invisible cadaver particles
from the morgue into the maternity ward.
Today, we'd call them bacteria.
But remember, this is mid-1800s, pre-germ theory.
Consider a typical morning of a student or a young doctor in training.
The very first thing he would do in the morning was to go to the dead house,
as it was often called, and to do an autopsy on one of the women who
had died the day before.
And when the abdomen is open, there is a sea of pus around the uterus, around the tubes.
The young doctor will put his hands in this. He then probably wipes his hands on a towel and goes up to take on
his regular duties as an obstetrician in training.
Semmelweis ordered every medical attendant who entered the doctor's ward to submerge his hands
in a chlorine wash before seeing patients. Within six months,
the death rate of women in the doctor's ward had plummeted.
And that was it. It was as simple as that.
It was a stellar piece of medical detective work. Semmelweis not only found the cause of death,
but he figured out how to prevent it. So you know the rest of the story. It became standard
procedure for doctors to disinfect their hands, and they stopped passing germs along to patients,
right? Well, not exactly. Doctors are human. Michael Langberg is the chief medical officer at Cedars-Sinai Medical Center in Los Angeles.
He's been trying to get his doctors to do a better job washing their hands.
It hasn't been easy.
So there's something in the human condition that somehow disconnects what is really good evidence from personal choice and habit.
And I don't know why that is.
I'm not a psychiatrist.
My field is internal medicine.
I just have the observation.
Physicians are no different.
What's disturbing about physicians is since they're human,
you would expect them to have the same rate as everybody else,
if not even greater rates, if not 100%, than other health care providers.
And at Cedars-Sinai,
I regret to report that they're the lowest rate. So even at an excellent hospital like Cedars-Sinai
in Los Angeles, it's the doctors who have the lowest rate of hand hygiene. Now, isn't that
bizarre? With most problems in society, we subscribe to the belief that education is the
answer, especially when you're talking about risky behaviors like drunk driving or risky sex or whatnot.
But here, the doctors are the most educated people in the hospital and the worst at washing their hands.
So how is a hospital like Cedars-Sinai supposed to solve that problem?
We'll tell you about that later.
But first, let's take a look at another problem,
another instance of where knowing the right thing
is not always connected to doing the right thing.
Yep, we're going to talk about money.
Hi, I'm Austin Goolsbee.
I'm a professor at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, and I'm the former chair of the Council of Economic Advisors.
Which means that you worked as an economist in the White House bending the president's ear.
Something like that.
Something like that.
Just give me for a second your view of how important financial literacy is to a well-functioning society. the basics of how to save money, if you're going to invest some money, where are you putting it,
that you're not taking crazy risks that you don't understand and things like that.
But then, you know, we saw through the 2000s as we, in some ways, ripped up the rules of the road
and took away some of the restrictions that financial institutions had in offering financial products to consumers,
there were a lot of people with limited financial literacy who got into extremely complicated mortgages,
and those mortgages blew up, and the magnification of those explosions essentially caused the financial crisis and the worst recession of most any of our lifetimes.
Wow, that's quite a claim that financial illiteracy, individuals not knowing what they were doing with their personal finances helped cause the Great Recession.
How bad off are we?
Anna Maria Lussardi is a professor of economics at the George Washington University School of Business.
She's originally from Italy, but she spent the past 10 years looking into America's financial literacy.
On a scale of 1 to 10, she says,
I would describe it as a 4. into America's financial literacy. On a scale of 1 to 10, she says,
I would describe it as a 4.
If I have to give a number, I would describe it as insufficient and deeply insufficient in a sense.
Now, the good news is that other countries aren't necessarily better than us.
The bad news is that Lusardi isn't just guessing how bad we are.
She knows it from the data that she's collected. The bad news is that Lusardi isn't just guessing how bad we are.
She knows it from the data that she's collected.
It began with a survey administered by the National Institutes of Health and the University of Michigan called the Health and Retirement Study.
Lusardi and a colleague were allowed to stick in a few questions designed to see what people knew about money.
So we were only three and they were very simple.
They were one simple question about can people do a 2% calculation?
Here's the actual question. See if you know the answer.
Suppose you had $100 in a savings account and the interest rate was 2% per year.
After five years, how much do you think you would have in the account if you left the money to grow?
More than $102?
Exactly $102?
Or less than $102?
You know, we wanted to test interest compounding,
but we end up really asking people, you know,
how much do you get on your saving account
if you invest, you know, $100 do you get on your saving account if you invest, you know,
$100 and the interest rate is 2%? The answer is more than $102. That's the miracle of compound
interest. All right, here's the second question. Imagine that the interest rate on your savings
account was 1% per year and inflation was 2% per year. After one year, would you be able to buy more than,
exactly the same as, or less than today with the money in this account? The answer is less than
today. That's what inflation does. And here's the third question. Do you think that the following
statement is true or false? Buying a single company stock usually provides
a safer return than a stock mutual fund. The answer is false. A single stock is more volatile
than a mutual fund. All right. How'd you do? Did you ace them? Turns out that only 50% of
respondents got both of the first two questions right right and only a third of the people got all three answers right.
And no offense, but these are pretty basic questions.
It was a surprise in a sense that we were expecting people not to know very much,
but we were surprised by how little people knew,
given that we were giving this interview to people who were 50 and older.
So they had already engaged in probably a lot of financial transactions.
Lussardi was so struck by the sad state of our financial literacy,
not just among older people, but as she discovered in later surveys
among young adults, women, and minorities,
that she's become an advocate for fixing this problem.
The obvious solution, as she sees it, is to make financial literacy part of our educational curriculum.
High school would probably be the best place because we all know that educating people about risk is the best way to solve a problem, isn't it?
Isn't it?
It's sort of like saying, well, we should start teaching everybody to be their own doctor, teaching everyone to be their own mechanic.
Not only is it inefficient, but it has a sort of culture of blaming the consumer.
That's Lauren Willis.
She's a professor at Loyola Law School Los Angeles.
She teaches contracts and consumer law. Lately, she has argued in a couple of law journals against widespread financial education.
She's come to believe that a little bit of education can give people the illusion that they're better than they are at making financial decisions and an overconfidence that can lead to reckless behavior.
She first developed this position after reading a speech by Fed Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke
about the need for financial literacy education. The evidence suggests that financial counseling
can improve consumers' management of their credit. My written testimony describes a number
of other studies that document the positive effects of financial education and knowledge on financial outcomes.
And he cited some papers that he said supported the idea that this would work.
And I went and looked at those papers, hopeful that I would find something that worked and I was appalled. They absolutely did
not prove that financial literacy education was effective. They proved that
people liked the classes. They'd take a survey and people say, yeah I liked it, or
at least the people who stuck around to fill out the survey. And people, you know,
people are very polite. They would say, yeah sure I'm gonna do all those things
you told me to do when I get home. But there was no real evidence that people actually changed their behavior and
had changed outcomes. So we've got a puzzle here, don't we? You've got the Fed chairman and one
leading scholar saying that education is the way out of our widespread financial illiteracy.
And you've got another scholar saying, hold everything.
That would be a disaster.
So we decided to get these two scholars together for a chat.
Anna Maria Lussardi in favor of financial education and Lauren Willis against.
We began with something they agree on.
There are tens of millions of financial illiterates in this fine country of ours and that is not a good thing.
So that does sound bad, the fact that you both think that Americans are quite financially illiterate.
But maybe we should just think too bad for those people.
Those are dumb people.
And that's what, you know, that's what evolution is for and capitalism takes care of them.
So, you know, anyone who chooses to smarten up, well, you know, that's a big advantage
for them.
What's wrong with thinking like that?
I don't like this kind of thinking very much.
I have to say. I actually
think that people are very smart and they try to do the best of what they can do, but I think it's
very expensive to acquire financial education. And that's why, you know, for the normal literacy,
you know, we have set up school. Imagine a world where, you know, we don't have school and people
have to do the education themselves.
It's very expensive and very inefficient.
And there is an externality.
There is a cost to society of what other people do.
So, Lauren, it sounds as though you have a lot of respect for Ana Maria's research. What do you think when you hear her describe this new curriculum that should be taught in schools throughout the land of teaching children and then older teenagers and adults to be financially literate?
You think that's a good idea?
The problem is we are just not going to commit the resources that we would need to do that.
You know, we currently don't teach people how to do math terribly well.
And I actually think math makes a difference.
Just plain old math.
There are studies that show that folks with basic math skills do better financially later in their lives.
There is no evidence that people who know the difference between a stock and a bond do better later in their lives as a consequence of being taught that.
It's sort of like saying, well, we should start teaching everybody to be their own doctor,
teaching everyone to be their own mechanic, you know, something like that.
It's terribly inefficient to do that.
So your position then is what?
So if you say, Lauren, that Ana Maria understands the problem quite well, but that really she's attacking the demand side.
And really it sounds to me like you're identifying a big set of problems on the supply side.
So if that's the case, what do you propose?
Well, a few things.
One is I think we've moved to a point where financial decisions are complex because there are complex products out there. It's not just to fool people. I mean, there really are
good complicated products out there and good complicated decisions that need to be made.
We need to train and regulate a cadre of financial advisors, neutral financial advisors that are not going to be conflicted by also being salespeople. And so then that's...
And these people are employed by whom then?
Well, it would have to work in a similar way to other professions. And so there would have to be
some folks that were doing pro bono work, as well as it simply would need to become
also something that people expected to pay
some kind of flat fee for to get financial advice.
And Ana Maria, when you hear Lauren say that your idea for educating people, for giving
them more financial literacy in the, let's say, the school system for over the course
of many years, when you hear her say that your proposal for that is just too expensive
and cumbersome, and it probably
won't work on top of that. What do you say to that? Actually, this is exactly what people always
tell me. It's expensive to do financial education. I think it's expensive not to do financial
education. And we have just seen the consequences of that. Think of how expensive has been the cost
of this financial crisis.
You know, a lot of people tell me that, you know, financial education is very difficult. And I love
this analogy of driving because, you know, driving is also very difficult. And look what we have done.
We have put 15 years old, you know, on the road. And imagine what could happen if you were putting people on the road without giving them a driving license, without checking that they are able to drive.
Imagine that.
Well, also, there's the assumption that just about anybody can be taught this, what might look from a distance, like a rather complex set of skills, driving a heavy car, right?
Yeah. And, you know, we are not asking people to
drive in a Formula One race. What we are only asking you is to go, you know, slow and to be
able to reach your destination and, you know, not to have accident that can hurt you and others.
I think the problem actually is that the current world we live in does require people
to act like they're Formula One drivers, right?
I mean, let me just read you from the Federal Reserve Board Consumer Handbook on adjustable
rate mortgages.
To compare two arms, adjustable rate mortgages with each other, to compare an arm with a fixed rate mortgage, you need to know about indexes, margins, discounts, caps on rates and
payments, negative amortization, payment options, and recasting your loan. And so what we're
expecting from people is, in fact, Formula One.
So where do you come down in this debate?
Is financial illiteracy something that should be fought on the demand side
through widespread education like Anna Maria Lussardi suggests?
Or on the supply side through better regulation of financial instruments
and a new cadre of financial advisors like Lauren Willis wants?
It seems obvious, to me at least,
that some combination of both would be much better than nothing at all.
I get Willis's argument that widespread financial education
might be a massive waste of money.
And sure, I can get behind her call for more transparency in financial products,
but do we really want to rely upon a bunch of pro bono financial advisors to get people out of their messes?
The fact is that financial illiteracy is a hard problem to solve.
It requires a fair amount of knowledge, a good bit of willpower, and it probably calls
for some creativity, like other hard problems.
You remember the situation at Cedars-Sinai Medical Center with doctors not washing their hands?
Dr. Michael Langberg says their hand hygiene rate was about 65%.
That would mean that 35% of the time it wasn't being done.
And that translated to our medical staff as potential
harm. So what do you do? The doctors are the best educated people in the hospital. So it wasn't as
if they didn't know the danger of carrying around bacteria on their hands. Cedars-Sinai tried a
bunch of ideas that seemed to make sense. They put up signs and sent out emails. They handed out
bottles of hand sanitizer. They even awarded $10 Starbucks gift cards to doctors who did wash their
hands. But none of this boosted the hand-washing rate. So rather than moving forward, Cedars-Sinai
took a step backward. We had an effort to prove to the physicians that, believe it or not,
physicians' hands can carry organisms. We would go to the leadership of the medical staff and ask
them if they wanted to have their hands cultured, for example, and they did. And they were cultured,
and some of them were pretty ugly. That's right. The docs were asked to lay their palms in Petri dishes,
which were then sent to the lab.
After two days of incubation,
the dishes grew a bunch of yellow bumps in the shape of a hand.
Bacteria.
That's when the hospital's chief of staff made a clever and creative decision
to take a photo of one of those disgusting bacteria-laden palm prints
and make it the screensaver on the hospital's computers. The screensaver did its job. The staff
was shocked and disgusted, and the hand-washing rate shot up to nearly 100 percent. Victory! But to keep the rate high, Cedars-Sinai has had to be vigilant and sometimes
a little bit wicked. Would you believe public shaming? That's right. The names of doctors who
failed to wash their hands were posted during departmental meetings. The first time it happened,
I think subsequently,
other people in the room are texting the individuals to say,
you know, do you know that your name is up here for having been caught not doing hand hygiene?
And as much as we want to reward people for doing it,
these kinds of consequence actions
have had a really important impact
on the way in which physicians are really
aware of hand hygiene.
It's humbling, isn't it?
To think that the best educated people in the hospital need to be tricked and shamed,
even frightened into washing their hands. It shows just how hard behavior change can be,
whether it's hand washing or something like
learning how to do a better job with your personal finances.
We like to think we can flick a switch,
make a resolution, maybe take a course,
and suddenly we start doing the right thing,
the responsible thing.
But it can take all kinds of incentives, all kinds of carrots and sticks to make that happen.
What if we used the kind of tricks that Cedars-S remind you what you might be eating in old age if you don't learn a bit more about investing?
What if your adjustable rate mortgage application came with a picture of the future you living in a new cardboard shack?
Freakonomics Radio is produced by WNYC, APM, American Public Media, and Dubner Productions.
This episode was produced by Colin Campbell, Beret Lam, and Diana Nguyen.
Our staff includes Susie Lechtenberg, Catherine Wells, and Chris Bannon.
David Herman is our engineer.
If you want more Freakonomics Radio, subscribe to our free podcast on iTunes and go to Freakonomics.com,
where you'll find lots of radio,
a blog, the books, and more.