Freakonomics Radio - Is San Francisco a Failed State? (And Other Questions You Shouldn’t Ask the Mayor)
Episode Date: January 22, 2025Stephen Dubner, live on stage, mixes it up with outbound mayor London Breed, and asks economists whether A.I. can be “human-centered” and if Tang is a gateway drug. SOURCES:London Breed, former m...ayor of San Francisco.Erik Brynjolfsson, professor of economics at Stanford UniversityKoleman Strumpf, professor of economics at Wake Forest University RESOURCES:"SF crime rate at lowest point in more than 20 years, mayor says," by George Kelly (The San Francisco Standard, 2025)"How the Trump Whale and Prediction Markets Beat the Pollsters in 2024," by Niall Ferguson and Manny Rincon-Cruz (Wall Street Journal, 2024)"Artificial Intelligence, Scientific Discovery, and Product Innovation," by Aidan Toner-Rodgers (MIT Department of Economics, 2024) EXTRAS:"Why Are Cities (Still) So Expensive?" by Freakonomics Radio (2020)
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Hey there, it's Stephen Dubner.
Every once in a while, we get out of our recording studio and take Freakonomics Radio on the
road.
We recently put on a live show in San Francisco at the historic Sidney Goldstein Theater.
If you were in the audience that night, thank you.
We had a blast.
Hope you did too.
If you were not there, this bonus episode is for you. It is a recording
of that show edited down to podcast length. We have got another live show coming up in
Los Angeles on February 13th. LA has been through so much with the wildfires, so much
destruction and death and fear. All of us who love that place are eager for its recovery
and we are hoping to do our
tiny part just by showing up.
A portion of our ticket sales will go to relief efforts.
I hope you'll join us if you can.
You can get tickets at Freakonomics.com slash live shows.
One word.
That's Thursday, February 13th in Los Angeles.
One of our guests will be the inimitable Ari Emanuel. Okay, here now is what
happened in San Francisco. As always, thanks for listening. There are so many of you.
This does not seem like a fair fight.
There's one of me and many of you. This does not seem like a fair fight. There's one of me and all of you.
I'm sure it'll work out okay, but...
You're smart.
Okay, yeah.
The hecklers begin.
Okay.
So, in case it's not clear, this is not what we typically do.
I assume most of you know Freakonomics Radio.
You wouldn't be here otherwise. The show that we make is the opposite of a live show.
Okay, the show we make is really, I'm a writer,
and it's a writer's show.
We come up with an idea, we do a bunch of research,
we figure out what kind of people to interview,
then we prepare for the interviews,
we do a lot of interviews.
We start to put together a script, a draft script. We rewrite it.
We start to mix the tape.
It takes many, many, many, many hours to make one episode.
And you know, that's the way we like it.
Tonight we've got like an hour and a half or two hours.
That's it.
We have no pause button.
We have no reconsideration.
It's just us here together.
So if you're up for that, I think we're going to have a very good time together.
That's the intention at least.
When I was a kid, I was very shy.
I still am, truthfully.
I had another problem in addition to shyness, which was that I really was curious. I wanted to find out stuff. In the old days, it took a lot of effort to find
out stuff. You'd have to go to the library or you would have to ask an adult. And when
you're shy, asking a stranger questions was not so easy. My solution to all of that was
to become a journalist where you're, okay okay I've never heard journalism applauded before so thank you.
So you know becoming a writer becoming a journalist really solved both problems
because all of a sudden you have permission to ask anybody any question
and you're getting to find out stuff all the time. Now, in the old days, writing for newspapers and magazines, and I wrote books for a while,
it was old-fashioned fun, physical, analog labor.
You'd go out with people, might be writing a piece about one person over many weeks or
months, you'd follow them around, might be a whole scene, and you'd come back after those
weeks or months with a whole bunch of cassette
tapes that you would then transcribe yourself as a writer.
That's how you got to really know the material.
You'd come back with all these notebooks full of stuff, and then you would sit
down to sift it and sort and write.
And I loved that.
I loved every single piece of it.
I still have all my notebooks.
I still have all those cassette tapes.
It was very, very labor intensive, but it was wonderful labor. And my favorite part of it
was always just hanging out with the people. A lot of it, honestly, was really boring,
but the parts that were exciting were so exciting when you really learn something. It makes
me think of what the physicist Richard Feynman, who's been a hero of mine for a long time,
what Feynman called the pleasure of finding things out.
And it was just so pleasurable that I never stopped.
What we do now with the radio show may seem different because it's audio and yada yada,
but it's really the same thing.
Coming up with ideas, putting yourself in position to have interesting conversations with people who are smart or weird or maybe
all of the above.
You know, I think if we were to go back 20 or 30 years to when digital everything was
really starting to explode, I don't know if any of us would have thought that we'd
have so much communication as we do and so little conversation.
I feel like because everyone is able to publish and be their own bullhorn, that in a way we've
sort of forgotten how to talk to each other.
By now I've probably interviewed, I don't know, 5,000, 10,000 people in my life.
And I can't think of a single one where afterward,
I didn't feel like my brain grew a little bit
or my heart grew a little bit.
It's an unbelievably valuable human trait
that we overlook, this ability of ours to have language
and have a conversation where we can learn about each other,
move each other and so on.
And so really tonight, that's what want to do. I just want to
have some good conversations. We've lined up some people I think are going to be
excellent for you and me to hear about. So we'll get started. Does anyone have any
complaints before we begin? I get your emails. I know who you are. All right, so we're going to have some good conversations.
Our first one, I think you will enjoy quite a bit.
Would you please welcome our first guest?
She is the mayor of San Francisco, London Breed.
How's things?
Well, freedom is fast approaching right now, so it's almost like I drop thousands of pounds.
So you call it freedom.
For those who don't know, you've got just a few days left.
Yes.
You must have some wild shit planned.
Oh.
Oh, yes.
Pull out those phones, because you guys are going to see a different mayor breed.
Let me start with, I mean, I hate to say it.
A lot of people think of San Francisco as kind of a failed state.
Not quite Haiti or Libya, but the stuff they see, they see the worst of the worst.
That's what the media does.
The media is really good at that.
And then it becomes a political weapon as well.
I mean, COVID was really hard.
You personally seem to have done, you know,
the shutdown, handled that really well,
aggressively, early and so on.
But tell me how the city is recovering.
Well, it has been a rough ride,
but I'm really excited about where we are now as a city.
The city has been more fun than it has been in a long time because...
More fun, you said?
More fun.
We have closed down streets to have night markets, first Thursdays, events, entertainment zones...
Because we need some joy.
The city has been a place of no, you can't do fun things, and
we turned it into a city of yes.
We have helped over 20,000 people exit homelessness.
We have had a significant decline in our crime rate and one of the lowest homicide rates
since the 1960s.
This is the work that we're doing, but we also know there's more to be done.
It's a major city.
Cities have challenges, but we are finally in a place where we build the capacity, we
change the laws, we made the hard decisions, and I just believe that the best is yet to
come.
The biggest thing that we do struggle with is the perception.
So we need people to come to San Francisco, or people who live here, to tell their own
story of San Francisco.
So driving in, I mean, it's a cliche, a cliche like you know you talk to a taxi driver,
Uber driver, you drive in from the airport.
I realize I'm not really seeing the city.
You didn't take a Waymo where you didn't have anybody to talk to?
I have to say I'm a little bit scared of the Waymo's so far.
How do you feel about them?
Well, it's interesting.
They become a tourist attraction in our city.
But you just said people do a lot of communication,
but not conversation.
So I don't know if I'm going to take away Mo.
Because you want someone to talk to you.
I want somebody to talk to.
All right, well, stick with me.
OK.
I will say driving in from the airport, what I saw mostly
were billboards for AI companies, which
I don't see in New York.
And then I get to the Tenderloin, and I feel like I'm in a Hieronymus Bosch painting.
It is wild, and it's heartbreaking.
I know it's been there forever, and I know it predated you,
but, you know, I just wonder how much
the perception hurt you running.
Okay, let me just ask the question I really want to ask.
Why'd you lose? You stood for re-election.
I'm going to say this with a lot of pride.
There was over $20 million spent on my race to unseat me. Why'd you lose? You stood for re-election. I'm going to say this with a lot of pride.
There was over $20 million spent on my race to unseat me.
Is this all Levi's money?
I don't know where the money came from, but there was a lot of money.
I think that things were not happening as quickly
as people wanted to see them happen.
And that is something I take full responsibility for
because this government and how bureaucracy works,
it is not designed
to make things move quickly.
When you say bureaucracy, do you mean mostly the board of supervisors?
I think I do mean a lot of the board of supervisors.
And now this new mayor is getting a good board.
I'm just so mad about it.
People say, Oh my goodness, your response to the pandemic was amazing. And yeah, it's because we cut bureaucracy.
We had emergency authority to make decisions
without the bull crap that gets in the way
of trying to make things move.
And then we go back to a post pandemic world
after we come out of that,
we needed to be able to act quickly
dealing with the rise in fentanyl overdose deaths
and the emptying of our shelter beds and the need to build more houses.
We had all these things we needed to do and could not move fast enough.
And the good news is we worked very hard to build our capacity to make the necessary changes,
to use technology, and to really help combat these issues.
And think about it.
Our crime rates have consistently been dropping.
I mean, even car break-ins are lower than 10,000
and this is a major city.
It hasn't been that low since 2015.
Let's talk about the major city thing
because I come from New York and.
And things happen.
Things happen in all major cities.
But that's my problem is I don't think of you as a major city.
I think of you as a very, very nice...
Now you understand why I don't do this live thing.
But don't you think of San Francisco as a major city?
Okay, Stephen, you better watch out what restaurant
you eat in. Somebody might put something in your food.
Well, that's not a nice way to make friends for the out of towners. But no, but but where
was I now major city? I'm going to skip that question. You lost some population during COVID.
I did read you say something about how
you had fewer people die here per capita
than any other big city in America.
But I was wondering, OK, but wait a minute.
Wait, save your applause because you'll boo me in a second.
But I wondered if that's just because everybody left.
No.
And they were dying elsewhere.
Listen, let me just say this. We shut down early. We made
really hard decisions. It was not easy. And the people of San Francisco really
came together to try and save lives. I was really proud of how people went
grocery shopping for folks. Folks showed up to work in the hospitals and people
sacrificed to make that happen. And so I'm very proud of that. But a lot of people did leave,
and they were talking a lot of crap
when they were leaving San Francisco,
but you know what?
Many of those people are back.
Because this is $34 billion in venture capitalist investment
of the top 20 AI,
artificial intelligence companies in the world.
Eight are right here in San Francisco.
Five million square feet of office lease sign
in San Francisco.
70% of the new office space is by new companies in AI.
People are coming back to San Francisco
because they know this is where they're going to be
successful despite what people try to say about this city.
It is still where people want to be.
Yeah, I'm really glad to hear that.
I do love your city. By saying I didn't think it was a
major city, mean to imply that I didn't love it.
But it has less than a million people. So I totally understand that.
This makes me think I live in New York and we lived there during the 9-11 attack. And it was
scary, very different event, obviously, and COVID. And I have a sister who lives in Buffalo,
who called us up and she was very worried about our family. She said, Steve, you know, you should really pick up
and my kids were very young, pick up and move to Buffalo. And I didn't even think it was
so terrible what I said. I said, Beth, you know, I'd rather die in New York than live
in Buffalo. And to be fair, Buffalo is a wonderful major city. So let me ask about you.
You grew up hard in public housing raised by your grandmother, all kinds of stuff around.
There was crime, there was drugs, your own family suffered from all that.
And the thing that I really want to know about you, you know, we have this idea when there
are people in the public eye, we just think they're invincible.
Everybody always has challenges and it's how they overcome them that really defines us.
So with you, I can't figure out how you got to where you got with the odds that you faced.
I'm not asking you for advice necessarily or if you have a superpower. But can you just describe what it took not
just to survive, but to thrive with those barriers?
There are so many different things that happened. Last time when we talked on the podcast, I
talked about my brother who's incarcerated and how we both went to the public school
system. He didn't even graduate from high school and I did. It's hard to finger point where the issue happened,
but I feel really honored and grateful to God for just the strength to overcome so many
of those obstacles and to get my education and to want to go back to the community and
make a difference.
Jared Ranere Obviously, you worked hard. Obviously, you
were disciplined and all that, but how much do you think is just temperament?
It's I don't know if I would say that I have the best temperament because I have a temper.
But I will say that I have remained true to who I am as a person.
But the whole reason why I got involved in public service in the first place
is because of violent crime in my community where people were dying, where our homicide
rates were significant in the 90s.
And it is just amazing to see us in a better place than we've ever been before.
And I have always said it is always the will of the voters that I'm going to respect and
be grateful that I had the opportunity to serve.
Do you feel that you were treated differently than the mayors who came before you who came from more traditional backgrounds? I think so a little bit, yeah. I didn't talk about it much, but when the
mayor calls you and to not return the mayor's call, that was pretty offensive or to sit in a meeting with me and to
look at my chief of staff and talk to him and not talk to me directly.
How do you handle that in the moment? In the moment, I'm like, hi, I'm right here.
Nice smile, and I'm the one who makes the decision and then I move on from it. I didn't come from money.
I come from the hood. I didn't have built-in relationships
with a lot of these people, but I did do what I could
to try and reach out to people
and develop those relationships
and make sure that my door was always open.
So even if someone opposed me,
which I had a member on the board of supervisors
who was just the worst person to work with.
That person's name was what again?
Well, here's the interesting part is somehow
once that person decided they wanted to work with me,
we developed a tight, really good working relationship.
And so what I've always said is, look, I may not like you,
I don't have to like you, but I will work with you.
I've heard you say that. I really like that.
I want to steal that because I think most of us, it's hard to do when you don't like
someone, but you need to work productively with them.
So what do you do?
Do you picture them, Nate?
What do you do?
No, I just think when I wake up in the morning, I'm the mayor of San Francisco.
Like I'm the mayor of San Francisco. Like, I'm the mayor of San Francisco.
So come right in. Look, sometimes it shows on my face, but I'm a grown up here and I
have to be better than somebody who's petty because you don't particularly care for someone.
I mean, you know what's in your head, but the business of the people is the most important.
I can't just support or work with the people who voted for me.
I can't just talk to the people that I want to talk to.
And it's what anybody in elected office should be if you are here for the right reasons to
get the business done for the people.
And I've been able to accomplish a lot because I've always kept the door open.
As we speak, you have a few days left in office, and I want to know what you're planning next,
if you have plans. And I also want to know, the Democrats got crushed this year, coast to coast,
and there's an election in about a month from now for DNC chair.
Is that something that you've poked around at by any chance?
So under the law, I can't look at other opportunities until I actually leave office.
And so I will be having a lot of meetings once I leave office because I need a job.
Let's just pretend that you're elected DNC chair in a month, whatever it is.
What would you say, considering the shellacking that the party had, what's a thing or two
that you think the Dems need to do to put themselves in position to win some more elections?
I think that the biggest thing we need to do is cultivate young, new talent.
I mean, my race is a perfect example.
I am a perfectly capable, qualified Democrat
who runs a major city, and when you have young Democrats,
you guys like that, huh?
When you have people in these various positions,
whether it's mayor or board of supervisors or other places.
We have to invest the resources into helping to grow our talent pool to ensure that we
have a pipeline.
Do you think the Republicans have done that well?
Or do you think that they're because look, Trump is no one's idea of an ideal candidate.
And yet one by a lot, you could read that a few ways.
A lot of people like Trump a lot, which is plainly the case and or the Democrats were really unpopular. I'm
just curious. And I know you face it yourself. Your far left hit you very, very hard. You
had to deal with a lot of things as ultimately a centrist them. So I'm just wondering if
the big tent needs to be reconfigured for the Dems. I think that the tent needs to be open.
Again, I come from nothing.
So I've only mostly volunteered and helped people in their campaign.
So it's significant that I'm mayor.
So how do we capitalize on that in order to ensure that people like me don't get lost
by the party, but really does start with how do you get more people choosing
to register as a Democrat rather than decline to state?
How do you feel about open primaries?
I would be open to it, but I'm not 100% sure that that's the right route to go.
Because why?
What's the advantage?
I mean, there are a lot of good arguments for why a two party system is not as bad as
we always say it is.
Because when you look at the alternatives, there are many countries with, you know, five, ten parties,
and they're in worse chaos, honestly.
I mean, it's politics. And you got to remember, politics is never going to be nice and wrapped into a neat little bowl.
It's going to be something you have to fight for.
The reason why I struggle with the open primary has a lot to do with, I want to see the Democrats united
and I want us to do the work to get behind the candidate,
whether we agree with that person or not,
to really fight for that candidate,
and also to listen to people as to why
they might want something different.
We may see something or hear something and we say,
oh, they don't know what they're talking about.
But you know what? If you listen closely and you hear what they're saying, you have to think
about, well how do we appeal to the people who we believe may not know what
they're talking about? I just think you have to be a little bit more open-minded
and not just toss someone to the side just because their beliefs aren't a
hundred percent of what you think our value system
should be because clearly we got a lot of work to do and we have to understand all those
different states differently than we have in the past.
That's really, really nicely said.
Congratulations on your career, everything.
Thank you for coming out tonight.
We will be back with more from our live show in San Francisco
right after this.
OK, back now to our recent live show in San Francisco.
All right, I'm having a good time.
Are you?
Are we okay?
You may be wondering why we are here at this big theater in San Francisco on this rather
awkward date.
It's January 3rd, I guess.
Nobody does events this week, the week of New Year's,
but we're here because this week in San Francisco
is the annual meeting of the American Economics Association.
The AEA is, as you can imagine,
it's a huge gathering of economists from all over the world,
and it really is as exciting as that sounds.
But then you ask, well, why would they hold it now all over the world. And it really is as exciting as that sounds.
But then you ask, well, why would they hold it now
in the week of New Year's when everything is dead,
everybody's traveling and so on.
And the reason is because economists are really cheap.
And when they're booking these conferences every year
in a different city, they want the cheapest week
for the hotels and the conference center,
and therefore they hold it immediately after New Year's.
And so when we heard it was coming to San Francisco
this year, major city, we decided,
you know, we go to these AEA conferences to scout stories
and to see our economist friends
and to look for new economist friends
for the sake of Freakonomics Radio and so on.
But then we also decide this year,
because we would be in a major city,
that we would put on this live show at the same time.
So we had the mayor, which is fantastic,
but we have another couple guests
that we were able to wrangle because the AEA was here.
We've got two more economists to come.
Let's welcome the first one.
Please give a warm hand to Mr. Coleman Strumpf.
Coleman, come on out.
Coleman, here are a few things I know about you.
As a kid, you got into trouble bringing candy bought at retail to school and selling it
at a very high markup, correct?
Yep.
My introduction to crime.
Introduction to crime or introduction to thinking like an economist.
Maybe they're not so different, but okay.
Maybe they're not so different.
I've been saying that a long time.
Nobody believed me.
I also know that as a child, you appeared in a TV commercial for Tang, the astronaut
beverage, is that true?
I, in fact, did with the rest of my family.
And I will only say if you spend a whole day drinking Tang, if you even know what that
is, you will not feel so good the next week.
All right.
You're now an economist at Wake Forest.
And most of your research that I'm familiar with at least has been about
What I would characterize as illicit and taboo activities. Would you name a few that you've looked into over the years?
Yeah sports betting not the stuff you do on your phone, but the guy in the corner
I've done some work on cannabis, which we might talk a little bit more about
I've done some work on cannabis, which we might talk a little bit more about. File sharing?
File sharing, like stealing digital products.
You're an empirical economist.
You work with data.
How do you get the data when you're dealing with illicit goods?
It's not as hard as you'd think.
I'll tell you about sports betting.
I was very interested in sports betting and I one time went to Las Vegas, which was about
the only place you could do sports betting. And I tried to wrangle up with one of the bookmakers. I was like,
can you give me some information about what you guys do? And he laughed at me. So maybe
kind of as a way of getting revenge on the guy, I ended up making a friend in Brooklyn's
district attorney's office and now I have a bunch of records on illegal bookmakers.
So I still don't know a lot about what the guys
in Las Vegas do, but I can tell you
about a lot of guys in New York.
So you blackmail people essentially, huh?
I get a little revenge.
The reason I wanted to have you on the show tonight
is you appeared in an episode we made back in,
I guess the fall, not long before the election,
talking about betting markets, prediction markets, which are
sometimes the same as betting markets, some legal, but mostly
kind of illegal.
Also, you helped us out with a later episode, we did a series
on the economics of cannabis, and you had a lot of data that
nobody else had about legal and illegal weed shops.
How can you tell an illegal from a legal weed shop, let's say in California, other than
maybe you go sample door to door?
I don't know how that works.
Those of you who in the audience who are interested in cannabis might know a website.
Should we turn the house lights on and have a show of hands or something?
You might know an app called,
you might know an app called weed maps.
Those of you who have never used it, it's, you know, maybe like Yelp for pot fired up
on your phone, but on the GPS tells you all the stores near you.
So I saw this app and I said, hmm, it'd be kind of cool if you could just get everything
that's on that site and stockpile it.
And if you spend a little time kicking around on that site and stockpile it.
If you spend a little time kicking around in the background, you can figure out a way
of doing that.
I always have a lot of computers running and a bunch of computers for several years just
pulling stuff off this site.
I have a list of all the stores.
How do I know who's legal and how do I know who's illegal?
The state of California publishes a list of the legal stores.
So I could start using that, but the information's a little bit incomplete.
So I had to look at different online sources, including Google Maps to see stores magically
turning from a kid's store into a weed store in Los Angeles.
And you can kind of figure out through a lot of sweat
which ones are legal and which ones are not.
Now, when they're listed on the site,
whether it's the weed map site of the California data,
there's a license number, I assume, right?
That's what makes illegal shop legal.
Do the illegal shops just make up a number?
Yeah, they either make up a number, go down the street,
look at the legal store, take a picture of that
and use that number, or sometimes they just put up stuff
that isn't even a valid number.
Now the thing that blows me away is when,
in a place like California,
let's take LA versus San Francisco.
In LA, you told us something like 70% of the weed shops
are illegal, so can you explain
how the economics of that works?
Why do they proliferate? Obviously it's cheaper because you're unlicensed of that works? Why do they proliferate?
Obviously it's cheaper because you're unlicensed,
but why are they allowed to proliferate?
Yeah, that's a great question.
There's not a lot of, I guess,
will among policymakers to do it.
The people who would be doing the enforcement, the police,
think about how hard this job is.
If I say arrest people who are doing some activity, well, I just
see as somebody doing this activity. Now you need to say not just as somebody selling cannabis,
but is it somebody who's licensed or unlicensed? They're literally doing the exact same thing.
Some people are doing it legally, some people are not doing it. It's not so easy.
But I would imagine that let's say you and I teamed up and we said, you know what?
Alcohol is pretty cheap to make. If you think about it, just ferment some stuff and you put it in a bottle and then you brand it.
And then you can sell it for like 20, 30, 50, 80, a hundred dollars.
And we know there's a lot of tax associated with that.
So let's say that you and I could either fake it or get the real stuff a little bit cheaper
and just open a liquor store without having to pay any of the taxes, regulation stuff. Why do we never see that?
In the wake of prohibition, actually, you did see things like that for 15 years. Through
the 1950s, you would have lots of arrests of people having illicit stills and things
of that sort. Today, in cannabis, the illegal people are pretty sophisticated.
So one of the things in this weed map state I have is I have a list of all the products.
What are some of your favorites?
Yeah, well, I like to observe them. Honestly, I'm a little out of date on them.
Is that true?
Yes.
You're not a big, I took you for a big, I don't know.
Yeah, I definitely have that, yeah. But at any rate, so I am familiar with some of the big The good news is apparently Tang is not a gateway drug then.
Yeah, right. Well, maybe it's a gateway drug to being an
economist. I don't really know. But at any rate, if you're
wanting to sort of pretend you're running a legitimate
place, you'll take a name brand and you'll just switch a
letter and they literally get old containers or you know, wrappers from legal stuff and they'll put it a letter. And they literally get old containers, or wrappers from legal stuff,
and they'll put it around the legal stuff.
Also, one thing you told us was that in San Francisco,
there are many fewer illegal shops,
which has to do with the way that they run their program.
So I don't know if Mayor Breed had anything to do
with setting up that program.
We actually interviewed the guy who did that,
but something like 20% of the shops here are illegal
versus LA about 70, right?
That's what your data.
So these are from a few years back, but I would say the number is probably still
about home.
I would think that the illegal shops benefit further by having legality
because that drives the price up with the licensing and it makes their stuff,
which might be identical, much cheaper.
Yeah.
And on top of that, there's the social norm.
I live in North Carolina where it's not so different from what I remember growing up in New York in San Francisco
all
California the norm about how acceptable is cannabis as a thing to be using much more accepted today than it used to be it's
Going to spill over to the illicit side as well
So I would I would argue demand is probably much higher. We could talk a long time about cannabis.
It's a very interesting economy.
Also the elections this year were interesting.
It got voted down in Florida,
I think North and South Dakota,
but it's interesting that, you know,
we're talking about what people used to call vices, right?
Sports betting, but it's now mostly legal in the US.
Cannabis, mostly legal in the US.
What about betting on elections?
You know a lot about that.
Do you think that will become fully legal in the US
in the next, you know, five, 10 years?
I usually, when I try to make a forecast,
I look at these markets to answer the question
rather than try to answer it on my own.
Things look pretty promising,
but everything is gonna be governed by what a judge will
maybe say about these things.
There was a lot of enthusiasm about these markets this time.
They did a pretty good job at forecasting the election.
You argue they do on average better than polling, yes?
Yeah, definitely.
There's a fundamental difference between polls and these markets.
The way a poll works, which is probably what most people
in the audience are familiar with,
is you talk to a bunch of people,
the representative of all voters,
and you see what they're thinking.
These markets are supposed to work
in a totally different way.
You step outside your own experience and say,
look, my goal, presumably, is to make some money
at forecasting the election.
Well, that has nothing to do with what I think
in terms of who I like.
I'm trying to guess what other people like.
Where's the information coming from?
Everywhere and anywhere.
Right, so why would it on average
be more accurate than polling?
Look, we've learned this election and past elections
that many pollsters are just not very good.
Let's be honest, right?
It's not a particularly scientific science
if you want to call it that, but still, why would they who are setting out to do one thing in a very binary way, I ask a bunch
of people, this candidate or that candidate, why would they not be better than a group of people
who are looking to profit from feeling they know a piece of information? This election was probably
the best case example
I could give of that.
So when people are polled about certain candidates,
they tend not to always say who they support.
So traditionally, Donald Trump underperforms and polls.
David Dinkins, I don't know if you remember this,
in New York City, the first black mayor of New York City,
he over polled by a lot.
A lot of people wanted to be seen saying that, yes, I will vote for the first African American mayor.
Right. So let me tell you about the person who was the most successful better in 2024,
who was a French citizen. He had a very similar view. He said, I don't think these polls are
working very well, but I'm going to run my own poll. And so he asked a slightly different question,
which was not who do you support,
who do you think your neighbors support?
There's a little bit of work that suggests
that people are a little bit more realistic
about thinking about that question
than what they themselves think.
Anyway, he was so confident in what he found
from this poll that he put down $80
million on Donald Trump to win.
And yeah, he made $80 million.
Does this suggest that pollsters next time around will basically emulate that methodology
of asking a question that's not so binary?
It's not so what are you going to do?
I'm pretty skeptical pollsters getting into the 21st century.
Like the writing has been on the wall.
Like forget about what I've just been saying.
Being a pollster is infinitely more difficult today than it was 40 years ago.
Absence of landlines.
Yeah.
You know, and I know who's calling and my phone doesn't equate to where I
physically am, it's just very hard to do polls.
The kind of advancements that they've made
are relatively marginal, in my opinion.
The thing that most surprised me about your work,
talking to you, is how the betting markets on elections
have been around for a long time
and have been accurate for a long time
and have been robust for a long time and have been robust for a long time.
Do you know anything about San Francisco history?
San Francisco definitely had their own markets, many of which were relatively big money, millions
of dollars in today's dollars.
They would take place in like cigar stores and things like that.
We're talking 1900, long time ago.
Some people had money, but a lot of people didn't have money.
But there were fewer things to bet on back then.
So people were really into betting on elections.
And so they would do these non-monetary bets
if you didn't have the cash.
They call them freak bets.
I don't really understand.
Freak? Freak bets.
As in?
F-R-E-A-K?
As in a certain book that I'm familiar with, yes.
I like the sound of that, yeah.
At any rate, they did all sorts of crazy things.
It was, I won't shave for the next 20 years.
I'll walk halfway across the country.
And these are documented somewhere?
Yeah, these are all at least newspaper stories.
And my favorite San Francisco story that I saw was,
in 1916, which was a very tightly contested election, two people bet.
Pete Slauson 1916?
Pete Slauson 1916. So, this is Woodrow Wilson getting reelected. And two people were betting
and the loser had to get dressed as a woman. These were two men.
Pete Slauson In public and private?
Pete Slauson In public and within a mile of here.
Pete Slauson And go out and parade around?
Pete Slauson And they would parade around. And so this one guy did, apparently it was not legal to dress as a woman at that point
in time.
This guy got arrested and then his friends came and bailed him out apparently.
So for losing the bet he had to dress as a woman and because it was illegal to dress
as a woman he was arrested?
He was arrested.
Wow.
Crime really does not pay.
That's brutal.
When was cross-dressing illegal until?
In San Francisco, I think 40 years
ago. Really? And that's San Francisco. Yeah. Yeah. Major city. All right. Well, Coleman,
thank you. It's always great to talk to you. Great. Thanks.
This is Stephen Dubner and you were listening to a Freakonomics Radio show we recorded live
in San Francisco on January 3rd.
We will be right back with our final guest.
We have one more guest tonight. He is an economist at a nearby school called Stanford,
I believe it's pronounced.
Would you please welcome Eric Brynjolfsson?
Okay.
I'm very fond of this man.
Very, very interesting and bright fellow.
So Eric, it says that you are,
you're a very, very, very, very, very, very, very, very, very,
very, very, very, very, very, very, very, very, very'm very fond of this man. Very, very interesting and bright fellow.
So Eric, it says that you are a senior fellow at the Stanford Institute for Human Centered
AI.
Is that correct so far?
So far, so good.
And you're also director of the Stanford Digital Economy Lab.
So I just want to know what both of those are.
I want to know what human centered AI is, honestly.
Well, that's a good question.
Fei Fei Li started it along with John Ichimendi
and they recruited me out to Stanford.
You were MIT?
Yeah, I was at a major city in Massachusetts.
You're picking bones with me
because that is the other city that thinks it's a major city.
I'm sorry, it keeps...
It's too bad we keep beating New York in all the sports, but that's just the way it goes.
Here's the thing about New York in sports.
When you're a major city, the sports don't really matter that much.
Good.
Yeah, you can cope.
So the idea is that AI is doing these amazing things, but we want to do it in service of
humans and make sure that we keep humans at the center of all of that.
A lot of technologists are very focused on the technology, but I'm an economist, as you
mentioned, and they're political scientists, sociologists, artists, and we're all working
to use AI to help lots of the other parts of the world and of academia.
When you talk about human center, I mean, one thing that comes to my mind is labor,
right?
Yes. You and I have had this conversation on the show
for probably eight or 10 years now about
to what degree does automation and AI mean job replacement?
And if so, how big a problem is that?
But you're talking about more than just machines
doing human jobs.
You're talking about having AI or having technologies
that let humans be human in their most essential
way or what?
Totally.
Too many people think of machines as just sort of trying to imitate humans.
There's this iconic test of artificial intelligence called the Turing test that many people are
familiar with, which is how much can you make a machine mimic a human to the point where
you can't tell which is which.
And that was, I think, a visionary idea when Alan Turing proposed it in 1950.
But in a way, it's a very constraining idea
because machines can help us do new things
we never could have done before.
And that's a much higher ceiling.
And so we want to look for ways
that machines can complement humans,
not simply imitate or replace them.
And so I wrote a paper recently called the Turing Trap,
trying to steer people away from this idea
of just imitating humans.
If we were having this conversation a year ago
about AI generally, the first five questions would be,
so, are the machines gonna wipe out humanity?
Now, it's not that nobody's thinking about that
and concerned about it anymore,
but it's no longer the conversation.
Why is that?
I think it's still part of the conversation.
I don't know, maybe in the press,
there's things that go up and down in cycles
to some extent.
AI is becoming much more powerful.
There continues to be rapid progress.
And the good news is we can have tremendously higher
productivity and wealth and have medical solutions
addressing poverty in the environment.
But it also raises a number of risks.
Misinformation or people using it in a way
that creates weird interpersonal dynamics,
AI boyfriends and girlfriends,
maybe millions of those that people have
as their primary relationship, pathogens,
and even catastrophic risks.
We'll say more about pathogens in AI.
Well, the great thing is AI can help us discover new drugs
as well as new materials.
There's just a study from a grad student at MIT
describing how researchers using AI
were able to discover 44% more materials
than a randomly assigned group
that didn't have access to the technology.
So big difference.
But some of those new materials could,
lots of them can do good things.
You could also create dangerous ones.
You can flip the bit on a drug that's meant to make you healthier and it could make you
much less healthy to the point of killing you.
So you know a lot more about this than most of us do.
You've come at it from a variety of angles.
We'll talk about the economic angle in a little bit.
But would you call yourself generally a techno-optimist?
I'd say I'm a mindful optimist. What I mean by that is that they're sort of blind optimists,
and I run into a lot of those in Silicon Valley who are just like, hey, don't worry, just chill,
it always works out in the past, you know, it's going to be great, just sit back and we're going
to have a great time. And there's a lot of pessimists who basically say the opposite.
And they both make the same mistake, I think, which is they take the agency away from us.
It's like, this technology is going to do stuff to us,
and whatever it is is what it is.
I think that we have a lot of choices.
One of the reasons I came to Stanford, the Center
for Human-Centered AI, is that I think
we can help steer the technology in ways.
And if we do it right, we could have the best decade
we've ever seen, but it's
not inevitable.
Okay. But we'll call you a mindful optimist is what you say.
Thank you.
Do you know much about what they call nominative determinism? You ever heard that phrase?
No.
It's the idea that your name, your very name has some effect.
That sounds like a good Freakonomics chapter.
You know, okay, we wrote a chapter about names that almost everybody remembers wrong.
Like we wrote that there is no such a thing.
Mr. Baker is a baker.
Yeah, exactly.
My name is Stephen Baker and I open a bakery or my name is Dennis and I become a dentist
and so on.
But there are people who believe that.
But with you, I got to thinking, I looked up the etymology of your name, Erik Brynjolfsson.
The internet tells me the last name is an Icelandic patronymic.
Yeah. Correct. Son of Brynjolf, with Brynjolf broken into
Bryn, which means armor. Yes.
And Jolf meaning wolf, so son of the armored wolf.
That is exactly right. And then Erik usually translates to
eternal ruler or ever powerful. So you are the ever powerful son of the armored wolf.
Do you think that's why you're an optimist?
So you are the ever powerful son of the armored wolf. Do you think that's why you're an optimist?
That would make sense.
That's what people, when I go to Iceland, that's how people know me.
It's true.
I've heard you talk in the past about, as I understand it, essentially a new way of
measuring our economy.
You call it GDPB.
So I want you to tell us about that.
I want you to tell us what the B stands for. But I want you to start at the beginning because
many people, even people who have nothing to do with economic sync, GDP is a highly
imperfect measure of what we want it to measure. And if I recall correctly, I don't know much
about this, but I'm sure you do, but the inventor, Simon Kuznets, when he created GDP, warned that it should not be used for essentially what we're using it for.
That's exactly right.
Simon Kuznets, his team in the 1930s basically developed what we now use as our national
accounts, GDP, productivity, is all based on this system of accounts.
Paul Samuels got one of the greatest inventions of the 20th century.
I agree, but it's also been massively abused and misused. Nowadays,
if you see a headline, the economy grew by 3.2%, they mean GDP increased by 3.2%.
And why is that an imprecise or not useful metric?
Well, GDP measures basically everything that's bought and sold in the economy. What that
means with few exceptions, if something doesn't have a price, it's not counted in GDP.
So we're missing a lot of important stuff, you know, clean air.
A classic problem is if I cook a meal for myself, that's not part of GDP.
But if I hire somebody to cook it or if somebody pays me to cook it, then it is part of GDP.
So you have a lot of little weirdnesses like that, a lot of household production is not
there.
And one of the biggest ones, I'm the director of the Stanford Digital Economy Lab, is all
these digital goods that are often free.
Wikipedia, search, Facebook, texting, email, if they have zero price, other than the electricity
and a few other things, they're basically not counted in GDP.
Yet people get a lot of value from them.
Right now, the average American spends a little over eight hours per day looking at a screen
of some sort. TV, computer, whatever.
That means they're spending slightly more than half their waking hours interacting with
bits, not with all the other things.
That means a big part of our lived experience is these things that are not being well measured
by traditional GDP.
So it's interesting because where you're heading here plainly is that we are richer than we appear because how we're counting wealth is imprecise
and incomplete. On the other hand, if we're even richer than the numbers say, why are so many
people so miserable? Well, you're absolutely right. We have a lot more wealth than we had before,
but we also did before as well. I mean, there's television and penicillin things
were also not counted very well.
But wealth is not the same as happiness as we know.
And so it doesn't automatically translate one for one.
But it does mean we have an imperfect measure
of the value that our economy is creating for us.
There is this famous in economics idea
of basically diminishing return on wealth and happiness
that was argued by Danny Kahneman and someone else.
I can't remember who that original paper.
Easterlin, it's called the Easterlin paradox
that what you just said that as people got richer,
they didn't seem to get happier.
More recent research found that actually
it just sort of is diminishing returns,
like you're saying, it's not that it actually stops.
Yeah, and I guess this is what gets us to GDPB.
So tell us what the B stands for.
Yeah.
Who are you working with or for?
And what is the intention of invoking this new measure?
So the B stands for the benefit.
As I said earlier, GDP is basically
a measure of production, what it costs to produce things.
The GDPB is trying to capture the consumer surplus.
It's the value between what the most you would have paid,
what you actually have to pay.
So with Wikipedia, if you would have been willing
to pay $15 a month and you pay zero,
you're getting $15 of consumer surplus.
And you're trying to measure that.
Yes, we are.
How do you do that?
So if I were to do a survey and say,
okay, I'll give you $500 to stop using the internet or stop using
emails, it'd be more realistically, for 30 days. Some of you would raise your hands and some of
you wouldn't. If I said, okay, what if I gave you $50? What if I gave you $5? You get fewer and
fewer people being willing to give it up. And that gives you a downward sloping demand curve. A lot
of people think it's worth at least $500. not so many think it's only worth $5.
The area under that curve, we call that consumer surplus.
If you do that for lots of different goods, you start getting a sense of how much value
all these different goods are creating.
Is this a government project?
No, it's something I came up with on my own where we decided that we should measure consumer
surplus and not just cost.
We started doing some small scale surveys
and we got some money from different groups
at National Science Foundation, the Sloan Foundation.
So I guess part of it is a government project.
And we'd love to get more support to do it at a larger scale.
We're doing about 250 goods right now,
including digital goods, non-digital goods.
We ultimately want to get a representative basket
of several thousand goods that we can track periodically alongside traditional GDP
and see how they compare.
The thing that's so interesting to me,
I mean, the whole thing is fascinating.
I'm curious to know what the ramifications would be
if your measure were to become widely embraced,
but one consequence that I could imagine
is that the way that our government currently looks at regulation and antitrust especially, which is going to change with
the new administration for sure, but when you're talking about basically the
hidden or uncounted benefits of many, many, many firms that are the targets of
regulators now, it could be that those benefits that are not being counted
should be reason for antitrust legislation
to be considered very differently.
Would you say that's the case?
Yeah, I mean, I think already there is a standard
among many antitrust experts that came out of Chicago,
actually, that we should look at consumer welfare
as the ultimate metric.
But that was a few decades ago.
I feel like we've moved past that now.
Well, that's the concept, but in terms of measuring,
so Lina Khan has a different measure, and there's an ongoing debate. But feel like we've moved past that. Well, that's the concept, but in terms of measuring. So, Lina Khan has a different measure
and there's an ongoing debate. But I like the consumer welfare standard, which is, you
know, is this concentration, this merger, the spin-off, whatever, is it making consumers
better off or worse off? And that's hard to measure, but our tool, GDPB, gives us a set
of measures for that. And you're right, in many cases, there's a tremendous amount of value from Google search
or from email.
One of my students was over in the European Commission, and they were upset about all
the money that the big companies based here in San Francisco and around the United States
were making on European consumers and saying, oh, this is a very unbalanced thing where
there's a lot of money going in this direction.
And he pointed out, well, actually, if you measure the value that people are getting,
there's far more value that French citizens are getting from these services than what
they're paying.
So the net gain is in the other direction.
That's really interesting.
I mean, I'm guessing that the way that European regulators think about American tech firms,
that argument, as true as it might be, is probably not going to change the regulatory
position.
Not as much as them having their own tech firms.
And so when they have companies like Mistral, I met with the finance minister in France
and he was coming around to the view that, well, actually maybe tech companies can create
some value now that we have one of our own.
So there's...
He didn't quite say it that way.
I would argue that Silicon Valley, Northern California generally have created an innovation
economy that is now global and just massively large and massively influential in many ways.
In a way, I feel like the global economy kind of is at root, the Silicon Valley economy.
I know we still do a lot of other stuff in this country, and it's not the majority of the economy by any stretch, but it's such a fundamental part
and more so, it has such sway in our daily lives, in our political lives and so on. And
when I hear you talk about GDP, I think if anything, we are underweighting the leverage
of this economy here. So I'm curious to know if you think I'm medium wrong, totally wrong, only a little bit wrong,
or maybe a little bit right.
I agree.
I mean, look, I moved out here four years ago from Boston,
another pretty innovative place,
but I really underestimated how amazing
the culture is out here.
I am constantly meeting people doing startup things.
They have these grand visions and dreams,
and I think they're mostly pretty sincere
about wanting to change the world for the better.
I moved here in summer of 2020.
I remember it was COVID.
We had this garden party
and I sort of half jokingly nervously said,
hey, are you guys all gonna be moving to like Austin
or Miami or something?
Did I kind of miss the party?
And they laughed and oh, don't worry.
Cause it kind of seems like San Francisco
and the Bay area is going downhill.
They said, don't worry, there'll be something.
And we didn't know about Chachi PT at that point,
maybe a few of the people in the room
might have been working on it for all I know.
But then of course there's this explosion.
And if anything, I think the tech innovation scene
is even more concentrated in the Bay Area now
than it was when I came in 2020.
And there's just a whole wave of innovations.
People talk about it, but, and I'm an economist,
I don't really fully appreciate it until I'm here.
There's a cultural element about it, but I'm an economist, I don't really fully appreciate it until I'm here.
There's a cultural element to it, an attitude.
It partly attracts people from around the world who have this mindset of wanting to
change the world.
People help each other to do it.
Like you said, it's been a tremendous engine of creativity and wealth creation.
What about the, I mean, I said it derisively and half jokingly, but what about the failed
state feel that San Francisco has projected to the world at least?
How do you reconcile the epicenter of the global tech machine and economy with the fact
that this is a city that has repelled people?
Yeah, it's a tragedy.
Part of it, to be fair, I think it's overrated.
Like London Breed was saying, I heard, you know, apparently it has the lowest
murder rate in 60 years.
And, you know, I come up to San Francisco a fair number of times.
I don't think it's like what is described by Elon Musk or others on Twitter.
Well, there's a...
Good timing.
But part of it is real.
I just walked over from Union Square and there were definitely some homeless people on the
street.
In the green room, I gave London Breed a little bit of a hard time about why do we allow this.
I think in some ways, I'm not a sociologist, but maybe all the wealth and success allows
a lot of sort of slack and allows them to get away with a lot of mismanagement.
I'm not signaling out her or anybody in particular, but I do think a lot of that government has
not managed as well as it could be.
They can get away with it because there's just so much innovation and wealth being created
that you can have a lot of slack.
I'm hoping that will get tightened up a bit because it doesn't reflect well on California
or on San Francisco.
With all the money being poured in to try to support San Francisco in the Bay Area,
we should have the cleanest streets, the police force the safest neighborhoods and we don't
So if you were mayor for you know a month
I think I'd be a terrible mayor economists do think differently about problem-solving, right?
Well, a lot of them are probably just common sense
But a few of them, you know where economists may differ, like I'm a huge fan of congestion pricing.
Almost everyone who I know who is not an economist doesn't think that's a good idea, but well,
I guess some of these guys may be economists.
What are the first rules of taxation?
You tend to get less of what you tax.
So if you're taxing work and investment, you're going to get less of that.
Why not tax pollution?
Why not tax congestion?
I also sometimes advise Singapore, and they've put in place all these rules that economists have. Well, you just slip that in. also sometimes advise Singapore and they've put in place all these rules that
economists have. You just slip that in. You sometimes advise Singapore?
No, no. Well. On Thursdays or what?
I've been there and met with senior officials just like I meet with senior officials in lots
of different places. I mean, not like an official advisor or anything.
Do you have a badge of some kind? A badge?
You have a cape? No, no. I am just a professor. But what I
like about Singapore is they listen to professors and they don't listen to professors
in the US Congress.
And that's one of the reasons that they're successful over there.
I think I'm biased.
And one of the reasons so many people are leaving California is because it's so expensive
here and it doesn't need to be.
And the reason it's so expensive is because a lot of people would love to live here, but
the housing prices are insanely high because it's supply and demand, it's elementary,
it's economics 101.
These are things that are actually really easy to fix
and we could do a lot better.
I see why they call you the ever powerful son
of the armored wolf, that was fantastic.
Eric Brynjolfsson, Coleman Strumpf, and Mayor London Breed for joining
us on stage in San Francisco.
And I would especially like to thank the 1500 folks who bought a ticket and came to hang
out with us. If you want to see Freakonomics Radio live, we have an upcoming show on February 13th in Los Angeles
with Ari Emanuel and other special guests.
Tickets are at Freakonomics.com slash live shows, one word.
And if you liked hearing what Eric Brynjolfsson had to say about the impact of AI,
be sure to catch the
next episode of Freakonomics Radio where we will hear about a new technology designed
to thwart AI.
That's right here in your podcast feed at our new time, Friday morning.
Until then, take care of yourself and if you can, someone else too.
Freakonomics Radio is produced by Stitcher and Renbud Radio. This episode was
produced by Abigail Lowenthal, Ellen Frankman, Morgan Levy, and Zach Lipinski with research
help from Dalvin Abouagy. Special thanks to Jesse McDaniel with Fresh AV, all the folks at Another
Planet Entertainment, the crew at the Sidney Goldstein Theater, and our partners SiriusXM and KQED Live.
The Freakonomics Radio Network staff also includes Alina Coleman, Augusta Chapman, Eleanor
Osborne, Elsa Hernandez, Gabriel Roth, Greg Rippon, Jasmine Klinger, Jeremy Johnston,
John Schnars, Neil Carruth, Sarah Lilly, and Teo Jacobs.
Our theme song is Mr. Fortune by the Hitchhikers.
Our composer is Luis Guerra.
Once again, thanks for listening.
I was able to get the Chinese government to commit to allowing San Francisco to host pandas.
You went to China to get the pandas.
I went to China to get some panda bears.
It's called panda diplomacy.
to get some panda bears. It's called panda diplomacy.