Freakonomics Radio - Make Me a Match (Ep. 209 Update)
Episode Date: May 25, 2023Sure, markets work well in general. But for some transactions — like school admissions and organ transplants — money alone can’t solve the problem. That’s when you need a market-design wizard ...like Al Roth. Plus: We hear from a listener who, inspired by this episode, made a remarkable decision.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Hey there, it's Stephen Dovner.
Before we get to today's episode, I have a couple announcements.
The first is a slight change of plans.
Last week, we told you that this week's episode would be about the super agent and dealmaker Ari Emanuel.
But that episode just isn't ready yet.
It's still in the oven.
So you'll be hearing that next week.
Here's the other announcement.
We recently
told you about a special series we're working on, a series about failure. We all know failure can be
hard to talk about, but there's also a lot to be learned from it. So we asked you to send in
your personal stories. We got a lot of replies, but the vast majority were from men. We know that
about half of our listeners are women, but for some reason, those weren't
the listeners who got back to us.
It could be that women simply don't fail as much, but we want to hear those stories too.
So if you are female and have any kind of failure story to tell, personal, professional,
academic, creative, whatever, We want to hear it. Just send an email to
radio at freakonomics.com with the subject line, failure. Thanks. Now, about today's show.
Last month, the federal government announced plans to modernize the U.S. organ donation system.
They want to speed up the process by which organ transplant patients are matched with donated organs. They also want to reduce racial inequities in the system.
When we saw this news, we decided to go into our archive and put together the episode you
are about to hear. It is a mashup of a 2015 episode, number 209, called Make Me a Match, and a portion of a 2016 episode, number 237, which includes a
personal story from a listener who was inspired by that earlier episode to make a remarkable
decision. All the relevant facts and figures have been updated. As always, thanks for listening.
Okay, I'm Al Roth, and I'm a professor of economics at Stanford.
For many years, Roth had taught economics at Harvard,
but he and his wife, who's a human factors engineer, had relocated.
We had just moved into our new apartment.
We had moved to Stanford in September of 2012.
Shortly thereafter, on October 15th, something memorable happened.
And my wife woke up around 3 in the morning and said, the phone's ringing.
And I woke up and it wasn't ringing anymore.
We only had one phone at that point and it was in her office, which was downstairs.
So I said to her, it's not ringing, and I went back to sleep.
And she went down and got the phone, and it started ringing again.
It turns out it's a good thing they call you back.
They don't go down their list.
And it was the Nobel Committee.
Roth, half asleep, was informed that he, along with Lloyd Shapley,
had won the Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences in memory of Alfred Nobel, also known as the Nobel Prize in Economics.
Did you think you had a chance?
You know, it's hard to answer that humbly.
So I knew that I was on the big list of people who, if I won a Nobel Prize, it wouldn't cause the Nobel Committee to be embarrassed. The newspapers the next day would not say
craziness and stop them. But there are many, many people in that category. So indeed,
we were asleep. We were not waiting for a call. And it's an interesting call because one of the things they're concerned
about, they have a lot of experience with this, is convincing you that it's not a prank.
So the person who first spoke to me said, you know, congratulations, you've won the Nobel Prize.
And then he said, and I'm here with six of my colleagues and two of them know you and they're
going to talk to you now. To persuade you that this is for real. Right. Either that or a very elaborate
prank. Exactly. But
they call you up and they say, so in half an hour
this is going to happen.
Get ready.
And, you know, I took a shower and got dressed, which was
a good thing because there wasn't an opportunity to do that
again all day. And what was the rest
of the day like then? Well, so at
five minutes to, someone
calls you back. And again, there's still,
I guess, concerned that you shouldn't appear confused on the phone. So what she said is she
said, point your browser to the Nobel site and you will see your name being announced. And then we
will come on the line and have a press conference by telephone. So by the time that happened,
I was ready. And then the Stanford press office fortunately fortunately, descended on our house at 4 a.m. and started fielding calls from journalists.
You know, they'd say, Professor Roth is ready now. Are you ready? And I'd get the phone and
I'd get five questions from someone and I would speak to many, many people. And apparently,
I mostly answered them very, very seriously, but I told a joke or two that I hadn't intended to tell
that people would say to me, oh, I heard you on NPR. You said something a little odd.
And then there was a press conference,
and then at 11, I had a class.
So people seemed a little surprised,
but that's how we ended the press conference.
This was a surprise, and it was a Monday,
and I teach on Mondays.
Word had traveled to your students by then, I assume.
It had.
There was champagne in the classroom.
Yeah, yeah.
So what kind of work did Al Roth do to land a Nobel Prize in economics?
Well, it's not the kind of work that typically wins a Nobel.
He has helped people who need a kidney transplant find a donor.
He's helped new doctors find their first jobs.
He's helped high school students in New York City find the right high school,
even though Roth himself, who grew up in New York City,
dropped out of high school.
I was a, you know, poor, ungrateful student
and didn't appreciate what my teachers were trying to do for me.
You should tell all your listeners they should complete high school. This is Freakonomics Radio, the podcast that explores the hidden side of everything.
With your host, Stephen Dubner.
Back in 2015, I visited Palo Alto, California, home to Stanford University and a few other things, to talk with Al Roth.
He was, as you have heard, a high school dropout.
But don't worry, he did go on to college, many, many years of college.
Not finishing high school isn't the only odd thing about Al Roth as a Nobel laureate.
Consider this.
Even though he won the prize in economics,
and even though he is a professor of economics, he is not technically an economist.
I mean, my degrees are in engineering. And, you know, I wrote a paper once,
a manifesto of market design called The Economist as Engineer.
Uh-huh, yeah.
So I think of myself as something like an engineer. I'd like to be an engineer.
A manifesto of market design, Roth calls it. The Nobel Committee's citation noted his
theory of stable allocations and the practice of market design. So,
what is market design and why can it win you a Nobel Prize?
Market design is an ancient human activity. You know, when you look at the distribution of stone tools around the Middle
East and Europe, you find that long before the invention of agriculture, stone tools were moving
thousands of miles from where they were quarried and made. And that's a sign that there were markets
for stone tools. There were ways to meet and trade things. And we don't really know much about those
markets, but the stone tools, which are very durable, are evidence that markets are older than agriculture. But the stone age
men who traded those stone tools and weapons had to make markets somehow. They had to make them
safe. They had to feel confident that they could bring the things they would trade for these stone
tools and not be robbed by guys with stone axes who would take their stuff. And that's been a big part of market
design for a long time, is making markets safe. Today, we think about fraud and identity theft
and securing your credit card. But there was a time when kings thought about securing the roads
against highwaymen so you wouldn't be waylaid on your way to and from the market. So if I were the king of England and I wanted to have markets in England, I had to make
sure that the roads were safe to get to the market.
Al Roth has now written a book, a really wonderful book, I should say. It's called
Who Gets What and Why? The New Economics of Matchmaking and Market Design. If market design
is, as Roth says, an ancient human
activity, why does someone like him need to get involved? After all, we're told that markets
generally organize themselves, right? There are sellers and buyers, supply meeting demand,
with price being the glue that holds it all together. In this regard, the invention of money
was a big breakthrough.
Barter is very hard because you need a double coincidence of wants.
You need to find someone who has what you want and who wants what you have.
You happen to have salt, I happen to have wool, and we each want what the other wants, or we find a third party.
Right.
Well, so finding the third party starts getting you involved in other things. And of course, money is a great market design invention for helping you find third parties because you can sell what you have for money and then go look for what you want.
But there are some transactions, entire realms of transactions, really,
where money cannot do what it does in a typical market,
where for whatever reason, supply is not allowed to naturally meet demand with price as the arbiter.
And that is where someone like Al Rol Roth comes in handy, the economist as engineer.
Because these atypical markets have to be set up differently.
They have to be helped along.
This is sometimes called a matching market.
Matching markets are markets where money, prices don't do all the work.
And some of the markets I've studied, we don't let prices do
any of the work. And I like to think of matching markets as markets where you can't just choose
what you want, even if you can afford it, you also have to be chosen. So job markets are like that.
Getting into college is like that. Those things cost money, but money doesn't decide who gets
into Stanford. Stanford
doesn't raise the tuition until supply equals demand and just enough freshmen want to come to
fill the seats. Stanford is expensive, but it's cheap enough that a lot of people would like to
come to Stanford. And so Stanford has this whole other set of market institutions, applications
and admissions, and you can't just come to Stanford, you have to be admitted.
Or think about this problem, which Al Roth has worked on directly.
What is the best way for hospitals to hire newly minted doctors,
and for those doctors to find the most appropriate hospital for them to work in?
The current system is called the National Resident Matching Program.
So I got involved in helping it during a crisis in the 1990s.
But you have to go back to the 1900s to understand how doctors get jobs.
And the 1900s is around the time when the medical degrees, as we know them, the MD degree, became the dominant medical degree.
And about 1900, that's when internships began.
So instead of graduating from medical school
and immediately beginning to practice medicine, as we say.
A word that's always bothered me.
Yes.
You should be good at it by now.
The first job, the standard first job for medical graduates
became what was called an internship and is today called a residency.
And that's a job where you work in a hospital and take care of patients under the supervision of a
more experienced attending physician. And it's a giant part of the professional education of
doctors. So it's very important to doctors where they get their internship and residency. And it's
very important to hospitals because the interns and residents
are a very important part of the labor force of a hospital.
As Roth tells it, there was an arms race
between hospitals for the best future doctors.
They began grabbing medical students earlier and earlier,
sometimes two years before graduation.
And when you try hiring people two years in advance,
it's hard to tell who the good doctors will be.
It's also hard for the doctors
to tell what kind of jobs they want.
So the medical schools intervened.
In 1952, they created
the National Resident Matching Program.
They developed a marketplace
that has a form that has survived till today,
although my colleagues and I have helped
modify it since then.
And what that form was, you go on interviews and you find out the salary and the working conditions of the
various jobs that you might be offered. And then instead of working the phones and maybe getting
an offer that says you have to take it yes or no right now on the phone, what you do is you consider
in advance which jobs you would like,
and you submit a rank order preference. This would be my first choice of the jobs I've interviewed at.
Here's my second choice. Here's my third. And the jobs do the same thing. The hospital residency
programs do the same thing. And then a match is made in a centralized clearinghouse.
By the 1990s, this system was showing strain. Some people thought the hospitals had too much
leverage over the residents. Also, by now, there were a lot more female medical students, some of whom had a
significant other who was also a medical student. And such a couple typically wanted to get a
residency in the same hospital, or at least in the same region. But the matching program couldn't
handle that kind of request. So those candidates might opt out. In 1995, Al Roth was asked to help
write an algorithm that could fix these problems. The algorithm worked well, and it now matches
about 40,000 applicants each year. It sounds as though this works pretty well, according to most
people involved. Yes, most people involved in this scenario are pretty happy with how it works, correct?
Well, labor markets are stressful for everyone.
So I think you're overstating how happy people are with the labor market.
But I think it works very well.
I mean, in the medical residency matching particularly, or at least as an improvement over what was before.
It's a vast improvement.
Okay.
Here's my question really for you is this, is broader labor markets. If we
consider the medical residency matching program relatively successful to what preceded it, at
least, why is it not used more widely in the labor markets? Well, the medical market is an easier one
to coordinate than many markets because just about everyone becomes available at the same time when
they graduate from medical school and they all start their jobs therefore at the same time when they graduate from medical school, and they all start their jobs, therefore, about the same time in July. So, it's a market that
can easily move people all at the same time. Whereas many markets, think about the market for
journalists, they might be hired at different moments, and jobs might become available and
need to be filled and not be able to wait for you to consider many jobs.
Yeah, but you and your colleagues are pretty brilliant and you have mathematical backgrounds.
I would think you could deal with rolling admissions. Is that right?
I mean, for all the talk about how modern labor markets have so many mismatches in them,
so many people doing jobs that they don't really want to be doing,
so many corporations with all these theoretically qualified people out there not being able to find
the people to fill them without going through a lot of, going to a lot of trouble. I mean,
hiring practices become more and more complicated, it seems, as one way to address the matching
problem. But it seems as though your complicated mathematical foundation might provide,
ironically, a simpler way to address that problem.
So, I'm not sure that's true.
Again, one of the special things about residency positions is, although they're very different
at different places, they're sort of similar to each other.
If you're thinking about should you be a journalist or an airplane pilot or a chef, you're dealing
with very different jobs with very different employers.
And one of the things that we do in the medical match is we make all the jobs available at the same time.
That allows you to consider them, to have preferences over them.
That's hard to do if you're thinking about being a chef or an auto mechanic. Sure.
I'm curious to know what's a market or scenario that you've looked at before that you thought, boy, I would love to help fix that one, but either haven't had a shot or maybe tried and failed?
Well, the markets for new lawyers might fall into that category. And certainly the
fanciest job that top graduates of elite law schools get is a lot like a medical residency.
It's a clerkship with an appellate judge.
That market is presently in the kind of situation that the doctor market was around 1940,
where jobs are being contracted far before law school graduation.
And probably a dozen times in the last 30 years, the lawyers have tried to
fix this with things like setting dates before which you shouldn't hire and things like that.
But it turns out it's hard to make rules that judges have to follow. Judges are a law unto
themselves and they break the rules. They cheat. If you know someone who's in law school now
who wants a clerkship,
they're probably going to get an offer sometime
in their second year,
so the middle of their second year,
a year and a half before they are ready to graduate.
And what would it take for you to have the authority
to get in there and redo that market?
Well, the question is,
is there a desire for judges to coordinate in a way that would control the market?
And so far, there hasn't been.
So you can win all the Nobel Prizes you want and there's a limit to your power nonetheless.
There is.
As complicated as it may seem to match future lawyers or doctors with their employers,
consider an even more complicated match.
A person who will die unless they can get a kidney transplant.
You can't buy a kidney.
You can't pay for somebody's college education to get a kidney.
You can't buy them a car.
It's illegal in the United States to obtain a kidney through any kind of valuable consideration.
That is Ruthanne Leishman.
I'm the program manager for the Kidney Pair Donation Program at the United Network for
Organ Sharing.
The United Network for Organ Sharing, or UNOS, maintains the registry of all the people in
the U.S. who need an organ transplant, at least for now.
The Biden administration's new modernization
effort would put some of UNOS's current responsibilities up for bid. According to
the National Kidney Foundation, out of the roughly 122,000 people awaiting an organ transplant,
more than 100,000 of them, roughly 80%, need a kidney.
We don't have enough supply of kidneys available. And so the list is ever
growing. But the number of kidneys available for transplant is pretty stagnant. It's estimated that
13 people die each day in the U.S. while waiting for a life-saving kidney transplant. And that's
because, as Leachman says, the demand for kidneys keeps rising, but the supply hasn't risen to meet it. Why is that?
Consider where most donated organs come from. They primarily come from cadavers, from people
who have died, but who have died under just the right circumstances, from a brain trauma,
for instance, to allow their still functioning organs to be harvested for transplant.
Only about 1% of the population who die are actually able to donate their organs.
So if you need a heart transplant, let's say, you are waiting for a cadaver organ.
But a kidney is different from a heart.
Why is that?
Because humans are born with two kidneys, and yet we really need only one.
Which means that in a country like the U.S.
with a few hundred million people, there are potentially a few hundred million spare kidneys
out there. When someone has kidney failure, typically both their kidneys fail, so they're
left with zero healthy kidneys, whereas the typical healthy person has a perfectly good spare.
So while it might seem that there is a massive demand for donated kidneys, remember,
there are more than 100,000 people on the list, the fact is that the potential supply
is really massive. Here's Al Roth again. If you're healthy enough, you can remain
healthy with just one. And that means if someone you love is dying of kidney disease,
you could give him a kidney and save his life. If you happen to be a match.
If you happen to be a match. And that's where kidney exchange comes in.
Ah, kidney exchange. Because remember, unlike some markets where price is allowed to let demand
meet supply, organ donation is a market that doesn't allow money. As a society, we've decided
it isn't right to reimburse people in any way for donating an organ,
although I should say some economists have argued
that we should rethink that.
But for now, at least,
kidney donation is reliant on altruism,
which, judging by the backlog of kidney patients
waiting for an organ, isn't working so well.
And that's why Al Roth got involved.
People often ask me how I got involved in kidney transplantation,
and I think the romantic thing that they're hoping I'll say
is that I knew someone who was ill or that I was ill.
But that isn't the case at all.
I entered through the mathematics.
Coming up on Freakonomics Radio,
how Al Roth and his comrades used mathematics to save lives.
And eventually we wrote a paper about how to organize kidney exchange
if you weren't too worried about logistical problems.
So we hadn't yet talked to doctors.
We hadn't yet talked to surgeons.
I'm Stephen Dubner.
This is Freakonomics Radio.
We'll be right back. Al Roth, high school dropout, Nobel laureate, author of the book Who Gets What and Why,
began working on organ donation more than 40 years ago, as it turned out.
So in 1974, in Volume 1, Number 1
of the Journal of Mathematical Economics,
Herb Scarfe and Lloyd Shapley,
with whom I eventually shared a Nobel Prize,
wrote an article about how to trade indivisible goods
when you couldn't use money.
And this was a theoretical argument.
It was entirely, yes.
Entirely theoretical.
And sort of whimsically, they said, let's call the object houses.
And let's suppose everyone has a house and people have preferences over houses and they can trade houses, but they can't use money.
All you can do is barter.
You can say, I'll trade my house for yours, or you could do it among three people.
You know, I'll give you my house and you give someone your house and he gives me his house. That's all you can do. How would trade work? So they wrote a
paper about that. And I had just gotten my PhD in 1974 when this article came out. And
I read their article and I thought, what an interesting problem to think about how to
trade without money. So I wrote some articles about that too,
with Andy Postlewaite. And-
Still theoretical, or did you attach-
Entirely theoretical. We were talking about how to trade houses. And of course,
no one trades houses without money. I can tell you, I've just bought a house in California,
and money played a role. But it's, you know, the way economists learn about things, the way
mathematical economists learn about things, is a little bit the way economists learn about things, the way mathematical economists learn about things
is a little bit the way children learn about things. You find toys to play with, and then by
playing with the toys, you gain experiences that might help you with other things. So this is a toy,
this toy model that allows you to think about the question of how to trade goods when you can't use
money, and when you can't divide the good.
You can't say, you have a big house and I have a little house,
so just give me half of your house for my house.
You know, you say, houses are indivisible.
We have to trade.
In 1982, Roth took a teaching job at the University of Pittsburgh,
which happened to have an excellent medical center with a prominent organ transplant program.
Roth began thinking about kidneys from the perspective of supply and demand.
Again, there's a seemingly huge demand for donated kidneys, but in fact, a much, much larger supply of potential kidneys for donation, since healthy people have two but only need one.
So let's say that your spouse or sibling or parent needs a kidney transplant.
You could voluntarily undergo surgery to give up one of yours,
if that is, you happen to be a biological match.
If you aren't a match, then you're healthy enough to give someone a kidney, but you can't give the person you love a kidney. So there they are with an indivisible object that we had been
calling houses, but now call it a kidney. And here are these incompatible patient donor pairs,
and they have an indivisible object, and it's against the law to buy and sell kidneys for
transplantation. So all of a sudden, this toy model that we'd been playing with that didn't
make a lot of sense
for houses
because we use money for houses
made sense for kidneys.
Was there a light bulb moment
for you where you saw
that the kidney was
the concrete version
of what had been discussed
in this model or no?
Again, I'd like to say
that there was,
but there wasn't.
Were you looking for something
to plug into that model?
I was looking for a teaching tool.
I was teaching
the model, and my students would say, this is an interesting model, but isn't it a little silly?
Here in Pittsburgh, we use money for housing, professor. And I'd say, yes, yes, but this is a
toy model. You should study it. But there we were at Pittsburgh, and we had all these
transplants going on. And I said, well, so supposing it's kidneys.
So we talked about kidney exchange without my ever thinking it would become a practical thing.
I was not seeking to design kidney exchange.
But in 1998, I moved to Boston to teach at Harvard.
And in 2000, the first kidney exchange in the United States was done in New England.
That's an exchange between incompatible patient-donor pairs, as Al Roth calls them,
two couples, let's say, with the healthy member of each couple agreeing to give a kidney to the
needy member of the other couple. The first kidney-paired exchange ever took place in South
Korea in 1991.
The first U.S. exchange that Roth mentioned
happened at Rhode Island Hospital
in Providence.
Then it was covered in the press.
It was an unusual thing.
And there I was.
I had notes about kidney exchange.
So with a former student of mine
from Pittsburgh
who was visiting at Harvard,
Utku Unver,
I said to him,
look at this. there's kidney exchange.
Let's give a class.
It's teaching a market design class.
Let's give a class on how we would do kidney exchange.
Meaning this one had happened without your help.
Yes.
And you looked at this and thought,
hey, if this is happening on a small scale,
we can maybe...
We can help organize it.
We have played all these years with toy models.
We know how to organize, on a large scale,
trade among people dealing with indivisible goods when you can't use money.
We know a lot about this.
Several other economists began thinking about the problem.
And eventually we wrote a paper about how to organize kidney exchange
if you weren't too worried about logistical problems.
So we hadn't yet talked to doctors.
We hadn't yet talked to surgeons.
Although...
Like where the kidney needs to be and what...
Right, and just...
What kind the preparation is for surgery and so on.
And how hard it is to do big exchanges
compared to little exchanges.
So we sent the paper to all the surgeons we could think of, and only one answered. It was
Frank Delmonico. And he was- That's a good one to have answered then, as it turns out, right?
Absolutely. He was the director of the New England Organ Bank, and he came to lunch,
and he and I have been colleagues on kidney exchange and other things for more than a
decade now. But we helped him build the New England Program for Kidney Exchange.
One person that Delmonico hired at the New England Program for Kidney Exchange, or NEPKI,
was Ruthanne Leishman, who helped set up their kidney-paired donation program.
Remember, the Rhode Island transplant had already happened in 2000.
But that was just done manually looking at the blood types
of the donors and the candidates. And then in 2004, we started working with Alan using his
optimization program. The idea behind using Al Roth's algorithm was to make it so transplant
centers could simply enter the medical and demographic data on potential organ donors
and recipients, type in a few keystrokes,
and then voila, it would produce a match.
It would really be impossible to do this by hand because of the number of antibodies that
we're talking about and the number of people that we're talking about.
We really need a computer to look at it, not just to do any kind of matching, but really
to optimize the matching.
Matching a potential kidney donor is harder than it sounds.
Not only does any given person have one of four major blood types, but we also each have
our own stew of antibodies and antigens.
We're born with a certain amount of inherited antigens, but when our bodies encounter foreign
antigens, we develop antibodies that battle them.
This can happen during a blood transfusion, for instance.
That was the case with a Minnesota woman named Julie Park.
What really happened was I broke my leg about, I don't know, five, eight years ago.
And unbeknownst to me, they gave me a blood transfusion during it.
And that just changed a bunch of antigens and
antibodies enough so that Ray no longer was going to be a match for me.
Ray is her husband, Ray Book. They've been married for more than 30 years.
Julie and I went to high school together, didn't know each other,
had one date when we were freshmen at the University of Minnesota.
I told her I'd get back to her, and at our 20-year class reunion, I got back to her.
Julie and Ray have one daughter, three grandchildren.
Julie has been a type 1 diabetic since she was 8 years old.
And it basically, you know, has caused all my medical issues over the years.
Julie got her first kidney transplant when she was 35.
It came from a deceased donor.
And it lasted me quite a while, and that was great, like 26-plus years.
And then that one, for whatever reason, was failing.
So all of a sudden I needed another one.
Ray's blood type is O, which means he's a universal donor.
We were kind of going down that road thinking he'd be able to donate to me someday.
But after that blood transfusion, Julie was told by her doctors that Ray was no longer a match.
In Julie's body, Ray's kidney would have failed.
Ruthanne Leishman is familiar with Julie's case.
She had a lot of antibodies. 94% was her antibody level, which means
basically she only matches with about 6% of the population.
So if Julie went the route that got her her first donated kidney,
it likely would have taken a long time to get another
one. Given her particulars, one doctor told her, she could wait five years or more. Years which,
as Leishman describes, are hard on anyone with kidney failure. And then they're waiting on
dialysis and then three days a week they go into a dialysis unit to have their blood cleared of the toxins that the kidney usually removes.
Or they're at home at night doing home peritoneal dialysis.
And so that's a nightly ritual for people.
And it makes it difficult to work.
It makes people tired.
It makes people sicker.
So when they do get a transplant, they may not be in the best health anymore. So it's challenging.
But Julie had the good fortune to be enrolled in a kidney exchange program.
And her chances were greatly increased because her husband Ray was offering to donate one of his kidneys to someone, anyone, since he wasn't a match with Julie.
This is what's known as being a paired donor,
meaning that Ray was offering his kidney under the condition
that his wife would receive a kidney donated by someone who was a match with her.
I wanted to help my wife in any way that I could,
so I went out and got tested.
All the information went into the computer.
We just put it out there into the network, And thank God there's a network like that.
And the algorithm obviously worked. And it worked fast.
You know, I went on dialysis November 1st. They called me around Christmas time and,
you know, told me, well, looks like we've got something, you know, on the schedule here. But, you know, you've got to heal this wound you've got on your foot.
So I spent the month of January in bed.
So anyway, that was January.
And then we had the transplant February 5th.
So, you know, it certainly wasn't five years or more.
The kidney exchange landscape has changed.
There have been consolidations.
NEPKI, for instance, has been dissolved under a push to create a national program.
And the numbers have grown.
Last year, for instance, there were just over 25,000 kidney transplants in the U.S.
About one-fourth of those came from living donors, not all from kidney-paired donation, but still, that's a lot.
There's also a special type of living donor that Al Roth's algorithm made possible.
Ray Book, you will remember, was a paired donor, but there's also room for what's called a non-directed donor.
Ruthann Leishman again.
Somebody who comes into the computer program
without a recipient. They don't know anybody who needs a kidney transplant. They just want
to donate to somebody and help somebody. Well, they come into the program and they match with
a recipient whose donor matches with another recipient, whose donor matches with another
recipient. And this can go on and on. And so instead of that non-directed donor
helping just one person receive a transplant,
they can help two, three, five, 10, 30, 60 people
receive a transplant as we go down the line in the chain.
It was one of these incredibly generous people,
a non-directed donor,
who wound up giving Julie Park a new kidney.
This chain started with a woman named Jodi.
Hello, my name is Jodi Shakely-Wright.
Jodi Shakely-Wright is 50 years old.
At the time, she was living in Charlotte, North Carolina.
In May 2012, I was working as a telephonic health coach
for a company in Dallas, Texas,
and I worked from home in Charlotte.
Had a client who needed to lose
20 pounds so that he could donate a kidney to his sister.
And I knew nothing about organ donation at the time.
And at first, I wanted to do some internet research to determine how his lifestyle might
change after the surgery, as well as what he could expect to do pre-op in order to prepare
for the procedure.
In my research, I came across something called kidney paired donation.
I wasn't really familiar with that at first, but I had also seen around the same time an
episode of Grey's Anatomy.
It's actually season five, episode five, if you're interested in checking that out.
But it's about paired donation.
And at first, when I had seen it on Grey's Anatomy, I wasn't really sure if it was a Hollywood thing or if it really existed.
So I did some more research and sure enough, it was a real thing. And I wasn't looking to donate,
but kind of sat back and thought, you know, I'm at a place in my life where I think that I'm
healthy enough. I work out of my house. I'm financially stable. And this is
something that I could do. She began working with the transplant center at Piedmont Hospital in
Atlanta. She went through a long series of physical and psychological tests. They wanted to know if I
had considered all of the factors why I should not donate. First and foremost, I was asked to make a few minor
lifestyle changes, or at least I felt that they were minor, but things like they didn't want me
to do any death-defying stunts like ride motorcycles or jump out of airplanes. I had already jumped out
of an airplane, so that was okay. But with one kidney, you kind of have to take a little bit more
care. So basically, you know, they wanted to make sure that I was sure about donating one of my kidneys
because I really only have, you know, one to donate.
I need the other one to survive.
And, you know, they really want you to think about things like,
are you going to be okay with the decisions that your recipient makes?
Meaning that once you give this kidney up, it's not mine to direct how it's used anymore.
And I was really okay with that. That's the recipient's call. I'm giving a gift.
After passing her tests, Shakley-Wright's information was entered into the computer
program used by the kidney-paired donor system, and the algorithm went to work on her data.
It quickly found a match. Julie Park in Minnesota. Less than two months later, it was
surgery day. My surgery was in Atlanta, first thing in the morning. And once they removed my kidney,
it's put in a styrofoam container and it's put on a commercial flight and was flown to Minneapolis. Her kidney is actually put on a plane and flown to Minnesota,
where it is transplanted into Julie.
I think I went in about 4 in the afternoon, something like that.
Julie's husband, the same day,
is having his kidney recovered at a hospital in Minnesota.
It was a very emotional time. I told my kidney,
go and do a good job and take care of somebody. And I shed some tears. So Ray's kidney, at the
same time that my kidney was flying from Atlanta to Minneapolis, his was flying from Minneapolis
to Atlanta for the second recipient in the chain to receive her kidney.
So Ray Book donated his kidney as a paired donor so that his wife, Julie Park, could get a kidney from a stranger, the non-directed donor, Jodi Shakely-Wright.
And who got Ray's kidney?
We did find out it was a woman that got my kidney.
And she was in the next room next to the woman who was donating to Julie.
Now, my recovery room in Atlanta was next door to Ray's recipient's recovery room.
And I had the respect enough not to barge in there and introduce myself,
although I have to be honest, I really wanted to.
All I know about her is that she's
doing well. That recipient had also come into the kidney exchange with someone willing to give her
a kidney, but she wasn't a match. So this person in Georgia who received Ray's kidney,
her daughter the same day went to the operating room and donated her kidney.
And that kidney stayed right there in the same hospital and went to somebody on the deceased donor wait list who didn't have a living donor available to them.
So, this one act of kindness by Jodi Shakley Wright.
Who donated out of the goodness of her heart.
She didn't even have anyone she was donating for.
This one act had a multiplier effect.
So what Jodi did by entering the program without a recipient attached to her,
she was able to unlock matches that otherwise wouldn't have been possible.
It also wouldn't have been possible without the algorithm created by Al Roth and his colleagues.
In 2022, there were over 1,000 paired donation transplants.
In 2000, we had two. We would have stayed doing two or four or six a year without the algorithm.
The entire process is incredible. I don't have that much knowledge about algorithms. It's been
a little
while since high school and college, so I'd have to revisit some of my math skills. But I do know
that it's amazingly complex. And just to match blood types and antibodies, and especially knowing
that at this time, there are almost 124,000 people in need of an organ.
So how somebody begins to sift through all that is beyond me.
But thankfully, it's not beyond everyone.
Al Roth again.
This is about exchange.
You know, the thing we can call it kidney exchanges.
There's real exchange going on.
So when I started talking to surgeons,
they didn't automatically think of economists as fellow members of the helping profession.
But when I talk about it nowadays, you know, I say exchange.
You know, that's what economists study.
Of course, this is a subject for economists.
But initially, many people found it odd that economists were getting involved in organizing surgeries. You write in the book, or maybe hint in the book, that all this work that
you and others have done to try to solve this problem will hopefully be obviated one day not
too long from now when there's either medical treatment or perhaps artificial organs. Yeah,
I mean... Oh, I hope so. I think that your grandchildren and maybe mine will just be
appalled. They'll say to you, you know, Grandpa, so tell me again.
You used to cut the organ out of a dead person
and sew it into a sick person,
and that was modern medicine?
And we'll have to say to them,
yeah, yeah, we were proud and lucky
to be able to do that.
It saved lots and lots of lives.
And even more antediluvian, perhaps,
would be the notion that you'd have had
to create this complicated way
to get a living donor to match with a donor,
yes? Right. So my hope is that stem cell technologies will allow you to grow a new
kidney the way you grew the ones you have originally. But we're far from that now.
And while that may eventually happen, everyone who has end-stage renal disease today will be
dead by that time. So our responsibility is to try to take care of the
people who are sick today, even though there will be better ways to take care of them in the future.
What's it feel like to have played a role in helping redesign? I don't know if you call this
a market. It is a market, yes? I call it a market. I mean, it's not a market where money plays a role,
but it's exchange, and you want to get efficient exchange.
You want to get as many and as good quality transplants as you can.
So, absolutely, it's a market.
So, there are a bunch of people out there who are alive who would not have been alive had not you and others working with you done what you've done.
What's that feel like?
Well, many others.
It feels good, but economics in general does good things for people. So, I think that it may be an illusion to say,
here we are, saving lives is not great, and it is great, but imagine all the other good things
that markets do. You know, the economy has been immensely productive.
We all live much, much longer
than people like us lived even 100 years ago.
And this has to do with the rapidly increasing prosperity
that the world experiences because of the way markets work.
So the big job of economists, of market designers,
is to help that process along. It's been going along for many, many centuries without the help
of economists, but it goes by trial and error. And maybe we can reduce some of the errors and
make some of the trials go more quickly and more fruitfully. That, again, was the economics professor and market design expert, Al Roth.
Not long after we first published this episode, we heard from someone who had been inspired
by Roth, inspired to do something that most of us wouldn't do.
We'll hear that story after the break.
I'm Stephen Dubner, and this is Freakonomics Radio.
Okay. Hello, Ned.
Stephen, how are you?
Hey, great. How are you? Nice to meet you.
Nice to hear you.
Thanks so much for doing this. I mean, doing the interview, but doing the actual deed.
That was a very easy thing to do. When I spoke with him in 2016, Ned Brooks was 65 years old.
I live in Norwalk, Connecticut.
I'm semi-retired after a couple of careers on Wall Street and in real estate.
He had been married for nearly 35 years, three grown children.
And one day, Brooks was in his car.
And we were listening to your podcast about Alvin Roth, the Nobel Prize winner in economics,
who created a model to trade indivisible items without the use of money. And I think he was
talking about houses at the time, but it seems to work very well for the kidney chain as well. And I listened to the podcast with growing interest because what came through to me about
the power of the kidney chain as somebody with a business background is the concept of leverage,
that one altruistic donor and an altruistic donor is someone who gives a kidney without having anybody
particular in mind to receive it. And it provides a lot of options for the people who put these
things together to start a kidney chain. And that results in a sequence of transplants that can
affect a lot of people. Now, had you ever considered giving a kidney before then?
No, no, I did not. And what was it about the
message from Al Roth in that podcast that either kind of alerted you? What did you learn or what
changed your mind that made you start to think about that then? Well, the concept that we have
two kidneys and we only need one. Now, did you know that ahead of time or not really? Yes, I did
know that much. What I did not know is all the benefits that accrues to one who donates a kidney. The process is lengthy in terms of the amount of testing that you go through to do so.
Wait, you're saying that the medical tests were the benefits?
Oh, absolutely.
I just want to clarify here.
Yeah, absolutely. Look, you get many thousands of dollars of testing for free.
Can I just say something?
Ned, I think you and I are fundamentally different people because if I were going to get several thousand dollars worth of something free, I would want it to be golf or something, fishing boat, not medical tests.
But tell me more about your great desire for this. Well, you're not 65, and knowing that all your organs are free of any contaminants is a very reassuring thing, actually.
Let me be clear.
It wasn't really all the free medical testing that made Brooks want to become a kidney donor?
I think this is something I have to do.
It required some thought, discussion with my wife that day in the car. I spent one restless night, probably about three hours, trying to understand what my own motivations were and if they were the right ones to be doing this.
And once I put that to rest, then it was a very easy thing to do.
Did you decide immediately to become a non-directed donor, meaning that your kidney would be
available for anyone who needed it? Or did you think about trying to help someone in particular?
As great as it would be to help someone in particular, I didn't know anyone who needed
a kidney. And in fact, the leverage comes from being an altruistic donor. You can't start a
kidney chain unless you're altruistic about it. Let's say I need a kidney
and my wife is willing to donate
or someone else in my family is willing to donate,
but they're not a match.
They're not a physiological match for me,
but they would donate a kidney of theirs
to someone else who is a match.
They then enter the chain, correct?
So call them couple A,
and couple B is in the same situation
as is couple C, D down the line.
But then there's this wild card X that's you, this guy who comes in who doesn't have anyone who needs one, who just wants to give.
Does that make you much more valuable?
That makes me valuable because it allows the algorithm to maximize the length of the chain and kick it off.
If you didn't have the altruistic donor to start, you'd have to have a perfect
match. I'm working with my hands as I'm doing this, which is a lot of arrows pointing to people
who all work out exactly the same. Talk about the procedure, working with the hospital,
and talk about how the relationship works so that you are not made to feel that you're being pressured.
Sure.
In my case, I had the operation done at New York Presbyterian.
And I chose New York Presbyterian because they do a lot of these operations.
And I think with any surgery like this, you want to go to a place that does a lot of them.
And so I was very comfortable with their record.
They've never lost a donor yet.
They provide you with two advocates, and those advocates are there to protect your interest throughout the process.
And you go in for testing.
You do it through your advocate.
You go in for psychological testing, physical testing. They want to make sure you're financially able to do this because, of course, you cannot be
compensated for a kidney donation. To what degree did they push back? In other words,
to what degree did they try actively to discourage you or at least make you take a step back and
think it through a little bit more? They didn't actively discourage me. The psychiatrist probed quite a bit,
but after I seemed to have satisfied her on the answers, that was the end of it. What they will
not do is they will not come after you to keep you coming to the hospital for every procedure
that needs to be done. In other words, they set the time and the date for your next appointment,
and they won't call you. It's up to you to make sure you're there.
Well, that's interesting. Yeah. And at no point did they catch on to the fact that you were just
in it for the free medical testing? Actually, yes. The doctor I spoke with
there said this is a little-known secret, but the testing is so good that everybody should at least
start out to be a kidney donor and find out how their tests go. That is a secret that I'm guessing
they really don't want broadcast because I can see an army of, you know, senior citizens flooding
in there for their tests only to say, you know, I think I'm going to hang on to the other kidney.
And then talk to me about your family's response. Was everybody on board? My wife was supportive.
As I said, I have three children.
One was very supportive, one was skeptical, and one was opposed.
And I guess that's what you get when you get three children.
But the skeptical one and the one who was opposed turned around once they felt like they got a lot more facts about it.
It's a very safe procedure relative to surgery in general.
And once they understood that, then I think their reservations went away.
I understand you wrote a letter to your family
when you had gotten pretty far along in the process.
By then, you'd undergone some of the testing?
Yes, yes.
Do you happen to have that letter handy?
Actually, I do have it here.
If you don't mind giving that a read, that'd be great.
Sure, okay. This is a letter that I wrote to my family when I realized this is what I wanted to
do and I wanted to inform them all at the same time. So I sent them an email and it goes like
this. All, as you've commented upon, I've had a number of medical tests over the summer.
I did not fully answer your questions about those because I wanted to wait until I cleared all the tests.
I'm happy to report that I'm about as healthy as is possible for a 65-year-old male to be. listening to a Freakonomics podcast about a man who won the Nobel Prize in economics
for constructing a model of a market to trade indivisible objects without the use of money.
He was thinking about houses, but it turns out that the model works very well for other things.
His work had been used to create an extensive network for the matching of kidney donors and
recipients. The more I listened to the podcast, the more fascinated I became as I learned that
just one altruistic donor, a person who donates without a targeted recipient, can launch a chain
of kidney transplants that can number as high as 43. I spoke with the National Kidney Foundation
and learned more about the process. I registered as a potential donor and began an extensive series
of tests at New York Presbyterian, which have now concluded with me being accepted as a kidney donor.
So, why am I doing this?
Many of our friends and acquaintances have had their share of health challenges in recent years.
It is mightily frustrating to watch the pain and suffering and be unable to give any help.
I, on the other hand, am in perfect health, I have no need for my second kidney,
and I appreciate that my actions may greatly benefit the lives of not just the recipients of those kidneys,
but their entire families. Without it being too much of a stretch, my one wholly redundant organ
can potentially change and improve the lives of hundreds of people. There were 5,355 kidney
transplants from living donors last year, and there are over 100,000 people on the
wait list right now for kidney. The operation is several hours. They start about 3 a.m. in order
to catch the morning flights around the country, particularly Los Angeles. L.A. does more transplants
than any place in the country, and New York Presbyterian does the most east of the Mississippi.
They will have me walking that same day, and I should stay two days in the hospital. I will be uncomfortable for two weeks and fully recovered after four weeks. The operation
is laparoscopic with a single incision in the abdomen. I've been working hard with my trainer
on my abs. My advocate tells me that because I am blood type O, a universal donor and an altruistic
donor, I will light up computer screens across the country when they list me tomorrow. I'm happy to
report that mom is fully on board with this.
I could go on for a while, but I think you have the picture.
If you have interest in hearing the podcast that inspired me, you can find it here.
And then I note the Freakonomics page and the short Freakonomics blog on the subject here.
Let me know if you have any questions.
Love you all.
Dad.
The left kidney that Brooks donated wound up launching a three-recipient chain.
I knew nothing about my recipient until the day of the surgery when I was told
that it was a 37-year-old female in Denver area and that she was very, very sick and unlikely to find a donor anytime
soon, and that this was a real one in a million match.
Did you know anything about the cause of her illness? And would that have mattered to you
if you did know?
No, I had no idea.
Look, you're not getting paid. You might get thanked. You might not get thanked. You're doing
this for your own set of reasons. Was it important to you that that person appreciate those reasons or
appreciate you? Or did it not really work that way for you? This is where the leverage comes in.
They ask that same question in the initial stages in a little bit different way. What they ask is,
if something happens to your recipient, how upset are you going to be? Quite frankly, my answer was, this is multiple people who are getting a transplant because of what I'm doing.
And if one of them doesn't work out, I'm terribly sorry, but it's going to change lives for all the others.
So, Ned, you learned a little bit about your recipient.
And from what I understand, you've been in contact, you received a letter from her. Is that right, expressing her thanks? The way this works is I go through my advocate at the hospital, writing a letter to the recipient that goes to the advocate at her hospital to her.
Then if she chooses to do so, she comes back to me with whatever she wants to say.
And then through the advocates, I go back and disclose my identification.
Then she does that back to me if she wants to.
And that's the way it worked. and disclose my identification, then she does that back to me if she wants to.
And that's the way it worked, and we've exchanged emails,
and I've gotten Christmas cards from her family and so forth.
So you haven't met with her or spoken with her by phone?
I have not met or spoken with her, no.
Okay, so here's the story.
I believe that if technology has served us well,
that she's on the other line right now,
Danielle from Centennial, Colorado.
Oh, my God. I've not spoken to her yet.
This would be great.
Danielle, can you hear us? This is Stephen Dubner.
Hi, I can hear you guys.
It's Ned.
Hi, Ned.
Hi.
How are you doing?
I'm doing great. Good, good. This is exciting. This is very exciting. It's great to hear your voice. How are you doing? I'm doing great.
Good, good. This is exciting.
This is very exciting. It's great to hear your voice.
How are you feeling?
I'm feeling good, feeling real good.
Lately, it's been a struggle since the surgery, but I'm doing good.
A lot better than I was.
Are you on lots of meds?
Yeah. Unfortunately, I'll have to be on a ton of meds for probably the rest of my life.
Hey, Danielle, this is Steven. Can you tell us a little bit about what led to your need for the kidney?
Sure, sure. It all started October 8, 2014.
I had received a call from my doctor saying that my blood work had come back.
I'd gone to my regular doctor just because I was having a severe headache that
wouldn't go away. And so they did some blood work. They called me the next day and said,
you need to get to the hospital immediately. And they were telling me my creatinine was at a 12,
and I had no idea what that was. And so I went to the hospital and I was immediately hospitalized
for the next 15 days, getting biopsies and MRIs and plasmapheresis and dialysis and
getting all these tubes put in my neck and chest. And it just all happened so fast. And to this day,
they still don't have any reason. It happened three weeks after I had my son, but they don't
want to associate it to that. So they really have no answers of why this all
happened to me. And what was your, A, I guess, prognosis? Did they think that you would survive?
And what was your prognosis for getting a donated kidney? Well, when they were hospitalized and
they'd had no answers, they were functioning a small part, but they said that they were
failing. But they had hoped, since they really
had no idea what was going on with me, that they would kind of kick back in and restart
themselves.
So we kind of just waited, and I started dialysis and everything, and while we were waiting
for those next couple months, I actually tried acupuncture for, you know, organ treatment
specifically for that.
I was trying everything.
And I said, you know what, I'm not going to wait any longer for them to restart.
I better get on the transplant list now.
So come January of 2015, I started the process of getting on the transplant list and starting there.
And what were you told about how long that would likely take you to get a donated kidney? Well, it came back that I had antibodies in my blood from blood transfusions
that I had during the hospitalization. And since from having children, they said I created all
these antibodies. So it made me a very rare match for, I wasn't a match to any of my family. And so they said, because of
my rare antibodies, I could possibly be on the list five to six years. So that's the kind of
range they gave me back in January of 2015. Then I was looking at five to six years being on dialysis.
Wow. How long was it before you heard that there was a donor?
Well, it was probably come May of 2015 that I started getting word.
Me and my father, we decided since I was having such a hard time and nobody in my family matched with me,
my father really wanted to donate on my behalf. So we heard about the paired donor program through the hospital,
and he wanted to donate his kidney on my behalf.
So it was probably around May of 2015 that we started the chain process,
and I had several chains lined up throughout the summer of 2015,
but they kept falling through due to, like, scheduling
and with some part of the chain, it kept falling through.
So I had many chains lined up throughout the summer,
and it was finally in August that we found, I guess, Ned was matched to me,
and we got the surgery date of September 22nd,
and it kind of just happened really quickly from there.
Way to go, Ned.
Thanks. What's it feel like for you, Ned,
hearing Danielle talk now? She's obviously in a much better situation today with your kidney in
her than she would be without. So what's that feel like to hear her on the other end of the line?
It's emotionally very powerful. It means a lot, a great deal. Yeah, it was a real struggle
going through dialysis in the last year. I had to do four hours of treatment, three days a week.
So basically it took 15 hours out of my time every week. And I would go into a dialysis center and
the first thing you do is you get checked in,
and they do your blood pressure, your weight, your temperature.
They go through, you know, all your symptoms that you're feeling,
and there's really no privacy when they're doing that.
I mean, the next patient's five feet from you in their chair,
and you're talking about all your bodily functions that are not going well for you
with all the medications you're taking and everything.
And it takes away a little bit of your integrity having to do that so publicly.
And then just to sit there for four hours doing nothing, I can't get up, I can't move,
my blood is just sitting there, you're watching your blood go through this machine.
And it's really, really depressing.
And it was hard for me.
I mean, I cried the first couple times just because I would sit there and I'd look around.
And I was the youngest, obviously, in the whole building at 37 years old.
And I was the only one driving myself there.
And, you know, it's just a really hard and depressing time to spend, you know, in your day.
So it was really hard for me to do because I had two small children as well.
It's remarkable.
You say you were crying then.
Now you sound so strong.
You know, Ned's on the other line blubbering there.
I'm on the border holding it together.
It's emotional every time I talk about my story too I'm curious, you said that your dad had entered the donor chain
Did he end up giving a kidney?
And if so, does he know who the recipient was?
He ended up giving his kidney
All we really know is that it went to Connecticut
Over there where Nat is
And we have not heard from the recipient on that end.
I have a copy of the letter that you wrote to your donor. It's unclear to me whether
you knew exactly who Ned was at this time. It begins, to my wonderful kidney donor, I
don't even know where to begin. And I've already started to cry.
Sorry. Okay. I have nothing to do with either of you and I'm crying. Okay. So, but then toward the
end, you write, just to let you know, your kidney is doing awesome. And I'm already getting my energy back. Danielle, what's it like to have this guy, Ned's kidney, inside of you?
Do you feel whole again? Do you feel different?
You know, it was amazing because the very next day after surgery,
I felt incredible.
I felt 100% different.
I didn't feel any of the symptoms that I was having before with the illness
and the nausea and the anxiety and everything I was going through.
I immediately felt better.
My body felt better.
And, yeah, I was eating and drinking the foods and liquids I was restricted to for so long.
And it's just I do have the energy again.
And it's amazing how much better I feel
and, you know, I don't know if he had any, you know,
food habits that I've picked up, but...
How do you feel about single malt scotch?
You know, I haven't had the craving for any scotch.
And it's funny because we joke about that with my dad
because he's a single malt scotch drinker, too.
And we say, oh, that person's probably craving it now.
Well, Danielle, I'm glad you're doing better.
And I hope you continue to do even better.
Yes.
Yes.
Thank you so much.
And, Ned, thank you so much for everything you've done for me and my family.
And no need to thank me anymore.
Thank you for being such a great recipient. And we'll be And no need to thank me anymore. Thank you for being such a great
recipient, and we'll be in touch.
Yes, we will. Thank you.
Danielle, thanks for jumping on the phone
with us. Bye-bye. All right. Bye-bye, guys.
Bye.
Well, Ned, how do you
feel now? See what you've
done now?
I was shaking in here.
This is really something.
She's a great person. Well, I know you didn't do it for the thanks, but thanks.
My pleasure.
Ned Brooks, inspired by his own experience and the need for more kidney donations,
started an organization to help build more altruistic kidney donor chains.
It is called the National Kidney Donation Organization.
Last year, they helped recruit about 600 living donors. They can be found at nkdo.org.
Coming up next time on the show,
as promised,
a sit down with the CEO of Endeavor,
Ari Emanuel.
I still shave my head on the same day
that they shaved my head.
I'm 62 and I still f***ing do it.
It's insane.
Freakonomics Radio is produced by Stitcher and Renbud Radio.
The original episode, Make Me a Match, number 209, was produced by Greg Rosalski.
And the conversation with Ned Brooks originally aired as part of an episode called Ask Not
What Your Podcast Can Do for You, produced by Irva Gunja.
That's episode 237. Thank you. and Elsa Hernandez. The executive team of the Freakonomics Radio Network is Neil Carruth,
Gabriel Roth, and me, Stephen Dubner. Our theme song is Mr. Fortune by the Hitchhikers.
Our original music is composed by Luis Guerra. As always, thanks for listening.
I've listened to you for so many countless hours that actually,
sitting here talking to you, I feel like I'm in my car.
I hope you don't talk back to me when you're in your car.
I don't know.
Maybe that wouldn't be a terrible thing.
The Freakonomics Radio Network.
The hidden side of everything.
Stitcher.