Freakonomics Radio - Why Are There So Many Bad Bosses? (Update)
Episode Date: April 11, 2024People who are good at their jobs routinely get promoted into bigger jobs they’re bad at. We explain why firms keep producing incompetent managers — and why that’s unlikely to change. SOURCES:...Nick Bloom, professor of economics at Stanford University.Katie Johnson, freelance data and analytics coach.Kelly Shue, professor of finance at the Yale University School of Management.Steve Tadelis, professor of economics at the University of California, Berkeley Haas School of Business. RESOURCES:“People Management Skills, Employee Attrition, and Manager Rewards: An Empirical Analysis,” by Mitchell Hoffman and Steven Tadelis (Journal of Political Economy, 2021).“Promotions and the Peter Principle,” by Alan Benson, Danielle Li, and Kelly Shue (The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2019).“Bosses Matter: The Effects of Managers on Workers’ Performance,” by Kathryn L. Shaw (IZA World of Labor, 2019).“The Value of Bosses,” by Edward P. Lazear, Kathryn L. Shaw, and Christopher T. Stanton (Journal of Labor Economics, 2015).The Peter Principle: Why Things Always Go Wrong, by Laurence J. Peter and Raymond Hull (1969). EXTRAS:“The Secret Life of C.E.O.s” series by Freakonomics Radio.“What Does a C.E.O. Actually Do?” by Freakonomics Radio (2018).
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Hey there, it's Stephen Dubner.
This week we wanted to share an episode from our archives.
That's one of our most popular episodes, perhaps because it talks about a problem that many
of us have had.
It's called, why are there so many bad bosses?
I hope you enjoy it.
And if by chance you have already listened to this episode, do stick around to the end for a career update from this person.
My name's Katie Johnson and I'm a data scientist.
Johnson is 33 years old and lives in England.
She grew up near Bristol, went to university in Birmingham and held a series of increasingly impressive jobs at a series of companies.
These are all what are known as IC jobs.
IC standing for individual contributor, which means what?
It is someone who makes as opposed to managing people who make.
Johnson loved being an IC.
She loved analyzing data and she was really good at her job.
But after a while, she thought it might be nice to become
a boss. Yeah, I wanted to manage more and more people. And you wanted to manage more people
because why? You were just power hungry like the rest of us? I think there's a couple of reasons.
So the first is that I wanted to start getting more autonomy over what I was working on.
I would be working on stuff in my IC role,
and I think this isn't the most important thing. And I thought that if I became the leader of the
team, then I would get to pick what I worked on. Okay, that seems sensible.
The other reason was to have more impact at the companies I was working at. So you could
describe this as having a seat at the table. Also sensible.
I guess the final reason is that
we all kind of, not everyone I guess, but I was included in this, have a concept that
being more successful means being more senior. And so in order to not necessarily show others,
but definitely myself, that I had achieved and become successful, I needed to keep moving
upwards within a company. Johnson's father in his own career had
seen things differently. So my dad has been a network engineer. He recently retired, but he's
been that for his whole career. And he had absolutely no aspiration to become the manager.
He's like, why would I want to do that? But Katie Johnson did want to become a manager,
and several firms were willing to make her one. She took the most appealing offer at a
software firm that helps companies acquire new customers. And I was sent on some management
training and had to do what can only be described as a very long personality test. And the idea was
to tell me what I was good at being good at. And what was she particularly good at? Critical thinking, attention to detail,
courage, all these internal thinky type characteristics. You can see why Katie
Johnson would seem to be a great boss. Her new job title was head of data and analytics. She had
roughly 10 people reporting to her. The promotion came with more money, more prestige, more leverage to set the agenda.
Also, however, more meetings.
Oh, so many meetings.
Like compared to being a data scientist, I'd maybe have a half hour meeting in the morning
and then I'd just be free to do coding and thinking and making stuff.
But I was in meetings.
I think Tuesdays I used to be in meetings for like seven hours.
No offense, but did you not see that coming?
No, I really didn't. I thought it would just be like my normal data scientist job with a few
one-to-ones on the side. That was okay, because it's quite interesting. You're talking about the
work, you get into quite depth on problems with my team. It's more like the meetings,
like an hour's coffee with someone to try and set up a better working relationship
with their team,
times that by like five or 10 other teams.
It's just draining.
Keep in mind, this was happening
during the pandemic shutdown.
So all these meetings were virtual.
And as drained as Johnson was from all those meetings,
she was getting good reviews as a manager.
Yes, people would tell me what a great job I was doing.
I was coming across well.
But she found that being a boss made her miserable.
I would finish my day and my study,
walk into the living room, put a blanket over my head and cry
because I was in so much pain at how bored I was.
In retrospect, Katie Johnson had plainly erred in wanting to become a boss.
But she'd also felt that management was the only sensible way to advance her career.
And if you look at how most firms and institutions around the world operate,
you'd have to agree with her.
The question is, does this standard operating procedure produce good bosses or bad bosses,
or even horrible ones?
The horrible boss is a familiar caricature.
We all know the stereotypes, the screamer, the sadist, the idea stealer, the passive
aggressivist.
These are some of our most enduring characters in film.
You remember Blake from Glengarry Glen Ross, played by Alec Baldwin?
Put that coffee down. Coffee's for closers only.
Do call yourself a salesman, you son of a b****?
Or in the film Office Space, when Peter is trying to escape the office on Friday afternoon,
and he gets snagged by the boss.
Hello, Peter.
What's happening?
I'm going to need you to go ahead and come in tomorrow.
So if you could be here around nine, that would be great.
Okay.
Oh, and I almost forgot.
I'm also going to need you to go ahead and come in on Sunday, too.
Then there's Miranda Priestley, played by Meryl Streep, in The Devil Wears Prada.
You have no style or sense of fashion.
Well, I think that depends on what you're...
No, no. That wasn't a question.
The horrible boss motif is so attractive that the director Seth Gordon made a film called Horrible Bosses.
Yeah, we've got to trim some of the fat around here.
Trim the... What do you mean by trim the fat?
I want you to fire the fat people. Truly horrible bosses do occasionally turn up in real life, especially in Hollywood itself.
The producer Scott Rudin, for instance, has been accused of years worth of alleged abuses,
like smashing an assistant's hand with a computer monitor.
But even in Hollywood these days, and especially in more normal industries,
this sort of grotesquerie is harder to get away with.
Bosses who are outright monsters are more likely to lose their jobs.
But how much attention are we paying to the more common type of bad boss?
Someone who's simply incompetent or overstretched or even just miserable being a boss like Katie Johnson was.
Do we even know how many bad bosses are out there?
The more you dig, the more you learn that the science of boss behavior is not very scientific.
One Gallup poll shows that roughly 50% of American employees have,
at some point in their career, left a job because of a bad boss.
But an employee might have 10 or
20 bosses over a career, so maybe that number isn't so bad. A survey of European employees
found that only 13% rated their current boss as bad. So maybe the Hollywood caricature is way off.
Still, considering that nearly all of us will at some point in our
lives have a boss or be one, we thought there might be some boss questions worth asking. And so,
today on Freakonomics Radio, when a boss is a bad boss, have you ever wondered why?
There's no reason to believe that a great salesperson will be a great manager.
And yet, this kind of promotion happens all the time.
Why is that?
There are two ways to motivate people.
We can pay them a whole lot more, or we can give them an opportunity for promotion.
Today on the show, why good employees become bad bosses, and whether that will ever change.
Spoiler alert, probably not.
This is Freakonomics Radio,
the podcast that explores the hidden side of everything with your host, Stephen Dubner.
One of the reasons I became a writer years ago is because I didn't particularly like having a boss.
Like Katie Johnson, I prefer to set my own agenda, my own pace.
I also really like working alone.
Also like Katie Johnson, I am not particularly fond of meetings,
so I wouldn't be a very good boss either.
Fortunately, at Freakonomics Radio,
there are a couple other people who do all the bossy stuff,
leaving me pretty much free to do this,
what we're doing right now, asking questions, trying to find answers. So here's a question
I've always been curious about. How important are bosses anyway? I don't mean CEOs, the ultimate
boss. If you're interested in that, we once did a series called The Secret Life of CEOs. Today, we are just talking about
your standard issue middle manager. Do they really matter? Yes. Broadly speaking, managers matter.
Bosses matter for outcomes. That is Steve Tadellas. He's an economics professor at UC Berkeley's
Haas School of Business, a training ground for future bosses.
Management is not something that Tadellas himself aspires to.
Tell me how close you are to administration so I know how far away to be from you.
But he has spent time, while on sabbatical, working as a boss at some well-known firms.
When I was at eBay and Amazon,
I managed Teams and I enjoyed it very much.
How do you assess yourself as a manager in that realm?
I'm blushing, so.
Because you're the best ever?
No, but I'm pretty good,
so I'm feeling a little uncomfortable.
Your positive self-assessment is based on direct feedback or just a general warm glow feeling?
At eBay and Amazon, the feedback was actually formal through surveys.
Surveys, that is, with questions like, on a scale of one to five, how much do you agree
with the following statement? My boss generates a positive attitude in the team. Or my boss is
someone I can trust. Or, my boss provides continuous coaching and
guidance on how I can improve my performance. These surveys led Steve Tadellas to ask his own
bigger questions about bosses. For instance, does it really matter? Do these measures of
manager skills or characteristics, do they really have any value for the firm?
Is there some way in which managers
who score higher on these surveys
are actually contributing more?
These are eternal questions
in the field known as personnel economics.
You could ask the same questions about any manager,
the head coach of a football team,
the chairperson of your homeowner's association, the president of the United States.
But as I mentioned earlier, the academic literature on the impact of bosses is not particularly advanced.
You can see why if you think about it.
There are so many variables in the relationship between a boss and their employees
that it can be hard to pinpoint the effects of the boss.
This is why most research focuses on one single quantifiable metric, productivity. Eddie Lazier, Catherine Shaw, and Chris Stanton, where they show that there is variation in output of employees based on the managers that are in charge of them. loud to identify, but it appears to be something like a call center. The analysis looked at what
happened when a worker moved from what the researchers identified as an average boss
to a high-quality boss. Such a move, they found, increased productivity by as much as 50%. So,
if this were a call center and a given worker handled 100 calls per shift under an average boss,
an excellent boss could boost that to 150 calls.
So at least in this type of setting, a quote, good boss is doing something right,
but the data couldn't say what.
Steve Tedellis wanted to learn more, so he teamed up with Mitchell Hoffman, an economist at the University of Toronto's Rotman School of Management, to write a research paper.
I had access to interesting data and people in this company that will have to be unnamed because when it comes to personnel data, companies are very hesitant.
Tadellas would only say that this firm did high-tech, knowledge-based work.
Maybe, given his history, you might picture a firm like an eBay or an Amazon.
In any case, he is looking at a very different type of work than the earlier research with its narrow measure of productivity.
What we're doing is opening the hood up a little bit.
And what sort of data did they have access to? We have data that allows us to measure the impact of a particular manager skill
that we're calling people management skills,
as opposed to just do managers matter.
People management skills,
meaning the sort of things you find on those employee feedback surveys,
how well the manager coaches and communicates, how
trustworthy they are.
So that's the boss data.
On the employee side, Tadellas and Hoffman had a lot of concrete data, subjective performance
scores, as well as how often a given employee was promoted or given a raise, the number
of patents they filed, and whether they stayed at the firm or left.
In these high-tech, knowledge-based companies, retention is a very, very important focus
because getting these high-skilled workers is not easy, and there's a lot of competition.
And when you lose an employee, especially an employee that's very valuable,
then it could take months to replace them.
So Tidelis and Hoffman set about to sort through all this data to look for any causal relationships between the rating of a given manager and the various outcomes of the employees working under them.
What did they find?
For the most part, it was a big bag of nothing. We didn't find that the ratings of the managers seemed to impact the subjective performance of
their employees, their income, their promotions, or patent applications in a meaningful way.
That's right. On all those employee outcomes, performance, earnings, patents, it just didn't seem to
matter whether the manager was highly rated or poorly rated.
But there was one other outcome to look at.
Employee retention.
Bingo.
Tadellas and Hoffman looked at employees at this one firm who moved from a manager with
a poor rating to one with a high rating.
That's associated with an attrition drop of about 60%.
That is huge. And within that huge effect was an important nuance.
What we see then is that managers help retain better employees more than worse employees,
which shows that the impact of being a better manager
is strongest where it matters the most.
So, a good boss seems capable of keeping the best employees happy
and presumably productive.
Conversely, a bad boss might drive away the best employees.
The Tadellas-Hoffman paper was published in 2021 in the Journal of
Political Economy, one of the best econ journals. So, OK, the economics literature on bosses and
management just got a little bit deeper. But remember, employee retention was the only outcome
where it seemed to matter whether a boss was good or bad. And if you ask Steve Tedellis a more fundamental question,
like, what does a good boss actually do to instill this loyalty?
This is where I have to take a step back and say that there are certain things that
may be outside the scope of what economists should be dealing with.
If you were to make a list of things that you would like to
measure, were it possible, given the data, what would some of those things be? Really good question.
Something that's very hard to measure, that I believe is important, is compassion. I guess if
this is going to be on the radio, I might lose my economist card. Steve Tedellis is not the only
economist who's
been frustrated by the lack of evidence for what makes a good boss good. Maybe compassion is as
important as he suspects, but we just don't have any large-scale empirical evidence yet.
The Stanford economist Nicholas Bloom has been studying leadership and management for years. And yet...
No one could really give us a straight answer on what defined a good or a bad leader.
You look at the data and there's 10 different recipes for success. Maybe they each work for
a particular case study, but I've still 20 years later struggled to find anything that's the secret
recipe beyond saying, sure, there are some people that are better than others, but it's damn hard to tell what it is.
This has not stopped leadership gurus from promoting their pet theories.
As Bloom puts it, there is a ton of BS around this from airport bookstore pulp fiction.
And here's another reason to question the literature on management and bosses.
As we've been hearing,
most of the boss data comes from employee surveys.
Have you ever taken a survey that rates your manager?
If so, were you told it was anonymous?
Did you believe it was anonymous? Were your answers objective?
Or did you maybe think, well, my boss thinks I'm good at my job,
so I'm going to say they're good at theirs, or vice versa. I don't think my boss likes me,
so I'm sure not going to give them a good rating. As we have said before on this show,
survey data can be the lowest form of data. Here again is Steve Tadellas.
I'm sure you know that economists are very wary about using surveys. And economists believe in what we call a revealed preference
approach, meaning how you behave is telling me a lot more about you than what you say about yourself.
Just how big is the gap between what people say and how they behave? Over the
years, I have heard many economists give many examples of this gap. Steve Tadellas' example
is my all-time favorite. There is a lot of discussion about privacy and privacy regulation
these days. And you hear a lot of people saying how their privacy is important to them. And then
you turn to them and say, here's a Snickers bar.
Could I have your mother's maiden name?
And they say yes.
So it's a little bit confusing when you tell me that you really care about privacy.
And then you just scroll down on every app you download and click yes, yes, yes.
That doesn't tell me that you really care about privacy.
So the same is true for many other types of behavior.
So let's keep in mind that much of what we have been told in the past
about good bosses and bad bosses is not exactly evidence-based.
Researchers like Tadellas and Hoffman and Bloom
have been chipping away at the black box of boss behavior, but we've got a
long way to go. This means we need to keep looking for good data and asking good questions. So coming
up after the break, who becomes a boss and why? If so many people think the boss selection process
is stupid, why do firms keep doing it? And whatever happened to Katie Johnson?
I get to the end of the day, and the last thing I want to do is talk to someone else.
I'm Stephen Dubner. This is Freakonomics Radio. And remember, you can get our series,
The Secret Life of CEOs, and all our past episodes on any podcast app. We'll be right back.
Have you ever thought about where a boss comes from?
What I mean is why a given employee will rise from the ranks to become a manager?
Here's someone who's been thinking about that a lot.
My name is Kelly Hsu. I'm a professor of finance at the Yale School of Management.
Kelly Hsu, along with Alan Benson and Danielle Lee, published a paper in the Quarterly Journal of Economics, another top journal, called Promotions and the Peter Principle.
So the Peter Principle is a very funny and popular management book written by Lawrence J.
Peter, and his book offers an explanation for why we might see incompetent bosses everywhere.
Incompetent bosses everywhere?
Okay, I'm listening.
What is this explanation?
Let's go back to Lawrence J. Peter himself.
This is from a 1973 documentary.
The Peter Principle states very simply that in any hierarchy,
an employee tends to rise to his level of incompetence.
I'm sorry. As many times as I've heard that phrase, I still laugh at it just because it sounds like it's going to be not irreverent.
And then it turns immediately irreverent, which makes me chuckle.
Oh, exactly.
I think it's a funny idea, but it also rings true.
And it's funny in a kind of unpleasant way because it reminds people how much they dislike
their bosses.
Peter was a Canadian education scholar.
He used his daily observations to form a theory about job promotions.
I saw that very often a competent individual was promoted to something he couldn't do.
I saw a competent mechanic where he used to take my car. He was terrific.
He was very responsible, very precise, knew exactly what he was doing, so they made him foreman.
Now he's no longer fixing cars and he's trying to manage other mechanics.
And he's very incompetent.
The more Peter looked around, the more he saw people who were good at their jobs routinely stumbling into bigger jobs they weren't good at. In any organization where competence is essentially
eligibility for promotion and incompetence is a bar to promotion, people will rise to the level
of incompetence and tend to stay there. The book he wrote with Raymond Hull was called
The Peter Principle, Why Things Always Go Wrong. It wound up selling millions of copies.
The book was meant to satirize corporate strategy.
Nevertheless, a variety of big firms tried to recruit Peter to become their management guru.
He declined, saying that he didn't wish to rise to his own level of incompetence.
Kelly Hsu again. His idea is that firms and organizations
tend to promote people based upon their performance so far. What that means is a worker who is good at
her job will be quickly promoted to a new job role, which might require a different set of skills.
If she's good at that new role, she's going to be promoted again until she reaches a position
where she's actually a bad match for that new job role. And then she will no longer be promoted. On the one hand,
it would seem to make perfect sense that you promote someone who's good at their job. You
don't want to promote the bad workers. On the other hand, managing is not the same as doing.
There's no reason to believe that a great salesperson who knows how to negotiate deals
will be a great manager.
That, again, is the Berkeley economist Steve Tadellas.
I look here in my company, Berkeley.
Great researchers often make for lousy department chairs.
Great engineers often make for lousy engineering managers.
But here's the thing about the Peter Principle.
Even though the theory had been around for half a century, no one had ever
checked with real data from real companies whether Lawrence Peter was right. A few observations
about a car mechanic or an academic researcher turned department chair, those do not constitute
empirical proof, especially in the realm of management and all that airport bookstore
pulp fiction. This is where Kelly Hsu and her co-authors come in. They wanted to see if the
Peter Principle actually exists, and if so, what should be done about it. First step, get hold of
some data. We got our data from a company that offers sales performance management software and
services. Shu can't tell us the name of the company, but picture something like Salesforce.
A typical client of our data provider is a firm that employs business-to-business sales workers.
And that client firm would input the sales numbers and the whole organizational structure into a software program.
And what we're doing is we're studying the data that these client firms uploaded into the software program.
How many firms and how many workers?
We see data for about 40,000 business-to-business sales workers at over 130 different U.S.-based firms.
And how many of those were in managerial roles?
5,000 managers and about 1,500 promotion events. So in terms of empirical studies in your realm,
this is considered a pretty large and robust data set, or would you have liked it to be even bigger
than that? I would always prefer a bigger data set, but for this type of question, a very large and comprehensive data set.
So these are sales workers and sales managers.
What makes sales a good business function to study?
One is important to study sales workers because almost 10% of the U.S. labor force are somehow involved in the sales function.
The other benefit is that we have a very good measure of their performance.
So we can test, are the stronger performers more likely to be promoted?
So that makes a lot of sense from your perspective as the scholar.
From my perspective, as someone who's not in sales, I would think, well,
your findings may not translate very well.
That in a field like journalism or in healthcare or in many other fields, the measurables aren't
nearly as measurable as they are in sales. So how generalizable do you think your findings are?
I believe it's likely to apply to other settings where the skills required to succeed at one level
differ from skills required to succeed at one level differ from skills required
to succeed in the next level. So some examples are science, manufacturing, academia, entrepreneurship.
Can you think of industries or sectors where this problem wouldn't apply?
It's actually hard for me to think of a setting in which this problem wouldn't apply? It's actually hard for me to think of a setting which this problem wouldn't apply at
all. I've also seen it in the context of government structures. A good example is actually the ancient
Chinese imperial examination system. It's famous for being a meritocracy even thousands of years
ago. So you would take a test and the top scorers on the test would become administrators within the government bureaucracy.
But their problem was they would make the test based upon familiarity with classical poetry,
and the people who are best at that test would then become tax collectors, which is a different
skill set. But ancient Chinese poetry was an incredibly rich and diverse body of literature, yes? So I could imagine how
a mastery or even a deep appreciation of that could theoretically apply across a number of skills.
Theoretically, yes.
You sound unconvinced.
And to be fair, I do not have the historical data to prove that being
the best at classical poetry means you're not the best at tax collection.
Since you don't have that data, let's look at, say, modern U.S. politics. How would you assess
the relationship between a person who's electable and a person who will govern well?
Oh, that is a very good point. So someone who is electable might be very charismatic, very good at public speaking, whereas the actual function once someone has been elected might involve being good at deal making, back office politics, or understanding the actual details of the policies that they're passing.
Do you know anything about that question empirically?
I'm drawing a blank, but you really did raise a very good research idea.
Maybe I will look into this.
We've been thinking about settings where this type of problem might apply for a long time,
but somehow I'd never thought about the government or elected official example you
just raised.
But it seems like spot on for having potential as a problem.
Okay, before I hijack this conversation with Kelly Hsu to talk about politics and ancient Chinese poetry,
we were talking about her research paper that tried to identify the Peter Principle in the wild.
As Hsu told us, she had performance data on roughly 40,000 sales workers and around 130 companies. The next step was to confirm that companies indeed use
an employee's job performance as a trigger for promotion.
The answer? Yes.
We find that doubling in worker sales
corresponds to a 30% increase in their probability of being promoted.
Another way to look at it is if someone is the top sales worker within their team of five or six
people, then that top sales worker has about triple the probability of being promoted relative
to the average sales worker. Now, is that alone evidence of the Peter Principle?
No. Just to promote based upon past performance isn't necessarily a Peter Principle problem, because it could be that the best salespeople really are the best managers of salespeople. In that case, you want to promote the best salespeople.
Okay. So the next step, I guess, is seeing whether the best salespeople indeed do become the best managers.
How do you do that?
So first, we're going to measure the quality of each manager.
Managers in our data are no longer directly involved in sales.
Their job as a manager is to coordinate and facilitate the sales of their subordinates.
And presumably those subordinates are people they worked with
side by side and maybe competed against just the week before they were promoted. Is that the case
often? We actually see for the most part, people when they're promoted, they're rotated to a
different team, possibly because the firm overall is exactly afraid of those internal team dynamics
that you've just described. So we don't want to call someone a good manager just because her team sells a lot,
because we're worried that maybe she was lucky and she was assigned to great sales workers,
and those sales workers could have been great regardless of her managerial input.
To get around that problem, we're going to measure manager quality
as the manager's value added to her subordinate sales.
If my subordinates sell more when they work under me than when they worked under other managers, then I would be considered a high quality manager.
So here's the key question Kelly Hsu is asking.
Does being a good salesperson make you a good manager of other salespeople?
Here's what she found.
The manager with double the pre-promotion sales as another manager leads to about a 6% decline in subordinate sales.
Oh, my goodness.
Yes. What we find is that among promoted managers, those with low sales prior to their promotion,
they are actually better at managing their subordinates.
Let me say that again.
Oh, my goodness.
When these firms select people to be managers based on their current job performance,
they are actively making themselves worse off.
In other words,
the Peter principle is as real as Lawrence Peter said it was. And, I'm editorializing here, it would also seem to be incredibly stupid.
If the firm's only goal were to have the best possible managers, then the firm could,
by putting more weight on collaboration
experience and less weight on sales numbers, the firm could promote better managers and raise
overall firm sales numbers by about 30%. That's assuming that collaboration experience
is in fact more important for a manager than just high sales numbers. Still, a 30% increase in revenue simply
by killing off the Peter Principle? That would seem to be a no-brainer. So does this mean that
modern firms simply aren't aware of the age-old Peter Principle? Most firms are aware of the Peter
Principle problem, and it's a problem that they purposely choose to live with.
Some evidence we have indicating that in situations when the firm is trying to select
a new manager who is going to be in charge of a very large team, okay, so that's a situation which
manager quality matters a lot. In those situations, firms put less weight on a worker's sales numbers, probably because they know they're going to end up with a bad manager.
So Hsu is arguing that firms know they will get worse managers by simply promoting people who've been good at their previous jobs rather than people who might actually be good managers.
And yet, for the most part, they continue to do it, even though it hurts their profits.
Why would they do that?
Economists are always telling us that companies are, by definition, profit-maximizing machines.
Knowingly promoting a bad manager does not sound very profit-maximizing.
So are companies just making a mistake?
A firm having a Peter Principle problem
doesn't necessarily mean that the firm doesn't understand what it's doing or it's making a
mistake. So what is going on? After the break, Kelly Hsu gives us some answers. You don't want
to brag about your pay on your resume. I'm Stephen Dubner. This is Freakonomics Radio.
We'll be right back. want to brag about your pay on your resume. I'm Stephen Dubner. This is Freakonomics Radio.
We'll be right back.
Before the break, the Yale finance professor Kelly Hsu was telling us about a study she and her colleagues published about the Peter Principle. That's the idea that a good employee will be promoted to bigger and bigger jobs
until they get to a job they're not good at.
And then they tend to stay there.
But for years, the Peter Principle was just a theory.
Kelly Hsu wanted to see if it's real.
Using data on thousands of promotions,
she did find that when top performing salespeople
were promoted into management,
the sales performance on the teams they manage declined.
In other words, just because somebody's good at their job doesn't mean they'll be good at managing people doing that same job.
Xu also found evidence that firms know that the best salespeople make bad managers, and they choose to promote them anyway.
So, what is happening?
What we believe is happening is the firm is doing its best to motivate workers,
and they face a trade-off.
Okay, this is where it gets really interesting.
Promoting based upon past performance is very motivating to workers. So it's a very strong incentive system.
We can also work out that it's in some
ways cheaper than offering really strong pay for performance. So there are two ways to motivate
people. We can pay them a whole lot more, or we can give them an opportunity for promotion,
which they might value a whole lot because that's something that they can put on their resume,
and it increases their status in society. You don't want to brag about
your pay on your resume. I mean, the minute you say that, it makes me think, wait, maybe we should
make it more acceptable for people to brag about their pay because wouldn't that be more efficient
in the end and encourage less promotion of people who are going to be bad managers?
That's a fantastic idea. I don't know of research testing that directly, but I do know in other cultures so good that I've been rewarded a lot of raises.
And plainly, I'm very valuable to the firm, and I could be a manager if I wanted,
but I'm better than that. That's an incredibly ham-handed, naive way of putting it. But is there
any mechanism in managerial science for that kind of delineation between success on a financial level and success
on a managerial level? There have been some interesting attempts in that direction. So,
I've heard of many technology-focused firms, especially those in Silicon Valley.
They face this problem that they have a pool of very talented and skilled engineers,
and those engineers may not be the best managers
of engineers. Many of those firms offer something called a dual career track, where someone can
rise in the ranks of being an engineer, basically having a higher and higher title. So you can start
as engineer, then distinguished engineer, then lifetime distinguished engineer. And that's a way for the firm to
recognize someone's contributions in a public way without moving them over to management.
The Berkeley economist Steve Tadellas has also noticed this movement.
In companies like eBay, Google, Amazon, Facebook, there's the term of IC, or independent contributor.
And you will have people who are at the level of VP, not managing a single person, because
they are just gods in their realm of engineering or coding or architecture and so on.
By distinguishing between ICs and the so-called management talent, the firm is saying, look, we are going to promote people in ways that reward them for what they're great at.
You're not a great manager.
You're not going to get incentivized by becoming a manager.
Has that model trickled out at all of that high-tech realm. One area where I have seen it is in consulting
companies where you have the kind of deep technical talent, think of PhDs, etc.,
that will remain and be very heavily rewarded for the work they do, and they will not manage people.
The fact that Kelly Hsu and Steve Tadellas
can identify a handful of cases
where career success is not tied
to a promotion into management,
well, those are exceptions that prove the rule.
As Hsu found in her research,
the Peter Principle is alive and well,
as absurd as that may seem.
It is yet another confirmation that management science, as lovely as absurd as that may seem. It is yet another confirmation that
management science, as lovely a phrase as that may seem, is not yet very scientific.
Most firms stick with what they've always done. When an employee is good at what they do,
you turn them into a manager to oversee other people who do what they used to do,
even if they are not cut out to be a manager.
Like our friend Katie Johnson,
the English data scientist we met earlier.
I didn't see that there was another path
whereby I could be director level,
but not have direct reports.
I just didn't ever see that.
Looking back, there were some clues
that Johnson wasn't quite manager material.
You remember during management training, she took that personality test and she told us the areas
where she got high scores? Critical thinking, attention to detail, courage, all these kind of
internal thinky type characteristics. Well, those were not the only results of this test. Things that I can do,
but I struggle with was compassion, empathy, relationship building. I saw this output and I
was like, why didn't anyone do this to me before I got this job? Because this just screams great
data scientist, not so great manager. But it was too late. She'd already been made a manager. And as
you'll recall, it was not going well. I would finish my day and my study,
walking to the living room, put a blanket over my head and cry.
So let's say we're talking a scale of zero to 10. Where would you put your median satisfaction when you were an IC or a maker?
When I was a maker, I'd put myself as an eight and a half. I actually loved what I did. I
absolutely loved it. The only reason I would even deduct 1.5 points is because there were
some frustrations, as I mentioned, about not being heard and not being autonomous.
And then where would you put it, zero to 10,
when you'd become a full-on manager?
I would say I'd put myself more at like a four or a five.
A six would be a great day.
Okay, that's your personal satisfaction.
I do see, however, on LinkedIn, a review from your manager.
He writes, Katie is a rounded and passionate data leader with all the
qualities required to inspire, manage, and lead a team. Plus, she has got brilliant IC skills to
boot. And he notes that you are a real unicorn in the data analytics field. So that sounds like you
were the best manager ever. Yeah.
It's really nice, isn't it?
It's really nice.
Did he write that before or after you decided to quit?
He wrote that after.
You heard that right.
Katie Johnson quit that management job.
She quit being a boss entirely.
She went back to working as a data scientist at a different firm.
I don't know if you can ever be successful at something you don't like.
I want to do something that I love and I'm really passionate about because that's the only way.
Maybe other people are different, but I have to love it. I have to be like on a Sunday night,
I can't wait to start my work tomorrow and get back to what I was doing. And I was never, ever, ever going to have that in my management job.
So before you ever became a manager, as a maker, you said your average satisfaction or happiness
was around eight and a half. When you became a manager, it dropped to, let's call it five,
six on a great day. What is it now?
I'd say it's a nine and a half now. I'm super happy.
Are you getting paid less now as a data scientist than you were as a manager?
I'm getting paid more.
How did that happen?
I think there are more individual contributor roles now that pay good money.
I think that this technical specialist route is becoming more prominent and more rewarded.
And people do realize that there are going to be a lot of people who don't want to become the manager. And how do you motivate them? I believe you looked at the Peter
Principle paper. Is that right? Yeah, I did. The way the Peter Principle is usually described is
to me almost comical. It's that people rise to the level of their incompetence, which I find is
a bit cruel sounding, because one could also say that people rise to their ceiling of competence, right? And
then maybe they're not as good at that. It's not like they suddenly turn into idiots. But I am
curious, just your thoughts on the notion of promotion into management as a reward for being
good at what you've been doing all along. For me, this is where the idea of splitting out those
levels of seniority. So maybe you don't become the manager,
but you can become a technical expert and you are paid and rewarded for that is something that
helps with the incentives. What I would say on that, though, is often we have this dual career
tract of, OK, you can be a manager or you can be a technical specialist. But even though you might
get a quote unquote promotion and be paid more, the technical specialist still might be excluded from high level conversations. So being a manager just has this connotation of
seniority that a technical specialist doesn't necessarily and you still might be overlooked
in terms of just the respect. And I think that is motivating more than just, hey, here's a
promotion, here's a new job title. I think people want that autonomy and that having a seat at the table, people caring what you think.
It has to come with that.
I would think that many people who are promoted
from some sort of maker to some sort of manager,
that it would be hard to step back,
if for no other reason than it seems like a loss of status, yes?
It definitely feels like a loss of status.
I guess for me, I'm lucky that I don't
care what people think as much as other people or at all. I'm sure that was identified in your
personality test as well. Yeah, complete rogue, doesn't care what others think. People judge you,
which I find interesting because I don't know anyone who likes their job as much as I do.
So for people to look upon me and feel sorry for me in a sense that I have
chosen to go backwards in terms of career hierarchy, it's kind of telling in terms of what
we value out of a career. And you can tell them that if you hadn't done this, you wouldn't be on
Freakonomics Radio. Well, exactly. I got what I wanted. Was this the plan all along? Yeah, this is a big long game.
Thanks to Katie Johnson for sharing her boss and back story. Recently, she became her own boss,
working as a freelance data coach. She wrote to us, I am optimistic that my new venture will allow me to grow as a data professional, focusing on the elements of leadership I value while minimizing my exposure to the parts of leadership that I did not enjoy.
Thanks also to Kelly Hsu, Steve Tadellas, Nick Bloom, and all their collaborators for trying
to make this thing we call management science a bit more scientific. Coming up next time on the
show, it's time to take a look at one of our favorite
laws, the law of unintended consequences, in this case, applied to the modern workplace.
We will hear how laws and rules that are meant to protect certain workers don't. That's next
time on the show. Until then, take care of yourself, and if you can, someone else too.
Freakonomics Radio is produced by Stitcher and Renbud Radio.
You can find our entire archive on any podcast app,
also at Freakonomics.com,
where we publish transcripts and show notes.
This episode was produced by Ryan Kelly.
We had help from Jared Holt.
Our staff also includes Alina Kullman,
Augusta Chapman, Eleanor Osborne,
Elsa Hernandez, Gabriel Roth,
Greg Rippin, Jasmine Klinger, Jeremy Johnston, Julie Canfor, Lyric Bowditch, Morgan Levy,
Neil Carruth, Rebecca Lee Douglas, Sarah Lilly, and Zach Lipinski. Our theme song is Mr. Fortune by The Hitchhikers. The rest of our music is composed by Luis Guerra. As always, thank you
for listening. Do you ever want to tell your dean,
thanks so much for giving me all this managerial responsibility,
but I don't want it.
I don't want my reward for being a good scholar
to be that I have to do a bunch of management.
I haven't thought about that.
The Freakonomics Radio Network. I haven't thought about that.