In Good Company with Nicolai Tangen - Annie Duke: Quitting, Bill Gates, and poker

Episode Date: February 14, 2024

In the face of tough decisions, we’re terrible quitters. And that is significantly holding us back. In this episode, Annie Duke blends her experience at the poker table with her academic background,... offering unique insights into the human psyche, decision-making and quitting.The production team on this episode were PLAN-B's PÃ¥l Huuse and Niklas Figenschau Johansen. Background research was done by Sigurd Brekke.Links:Watch the episode on YouTube: Norges Bank Investment Management - YouTubeWant to learn more about the fund? The fund | Norges Bank Investment Management (nbim.no)Follow Nicolai Tangen on LinkedIn: Nicolai Tangen | LinkedInFollow NBIM on LinkedIn: Norges Bank Investment Management: Administrator for bedriftsside | LinkedInFollow NBIM on Instagram: Explore Norges Bank Investment Management on Instagram Hosted on Acast. See acast.com/privacy for more information.

Transcript
Discussion (0)
Starting point is 00:00:00 Today, we have a special bonus episode with Annie Duke, one of the best poker players in the world, bestselling author, and somebody I love to talk to. She's got really unique perspective on when to fold your cards, sell your shares, and dump your husband. Annie, thank you so much for joining us today. Thank you. I want to just clarify, I would not say I'm one of the best poker players in the world anymore. I did retire in 2012. That's all good. Now, you wrote a book called Quit. Why is it so hard for people to quit? Oh, gosh, you know, it's, I think that the issue with quitting is that there's just a lot of cognitive biases that line up and result in this failure to stop things. So it's hard to pinpoint
Starting point is 00:00:58 one thing, right? So we know that we have this kind of cultural bias against quitting where we, in English, we have like lots of aphorisms like quitters never win and winners never quit. You know, if at first you don't succeed, try, try again, which obviously is encouraging not quitting. So when we look at a lot of the way that we think about quitting from a cultural standpoint. We think that quitters are losers or weak-willed or lack character. So that's kind of like on the cultural side. But then there's a lot of cognitive biases that we know about sort of individually, things like sunk cost bias and Dowman effect, which we can go into a whole bunch of things like that, where when you actually look across those biases, they all result in a failure to stop things. So I think it's very multi-pronged, which I think is part of what makes
Starting point is 00:01:53 it such a hard problem to address. Well, let's touch on some of these things. So sunk costs, what does that mean? Why is it so difficult to sell the losers? Yeah. So when we're trying to make a decision about whether to continue something, we take into account what we've already spent. In other words, costs that we've already sunk into the project, and that isn't just money. It can be time and attention and effort.
Starting point is 00:02:21 So what we'd ideally like to do as humans is when we're approaching something that we're trying to decide whether we're going to continue, we would only continue that thing if we were willing to start it fresh today. So if we applied that to, for example, a stock that we bought, let's say that there's a stock trading at 40 and we've never owned it. And we look at it and we do our analysis on it and we decide that it's not a buy, that we ought not buy it at 40. We'd like to then, if we bought it at 50 and it's now trading at 40, be able to sell it. Because when it's trading at 40, regardless of whether we owned it at 50, what we're really saying is that I wouldn't buy it today. So if I wouldn't buy it today, I should sell it,
Starting point is 00:03:13 because holding is the same as buying, right? So the problem with the sunk cost fallacy is that we don't do that. And we have that feeling that I think everybody can intuit of, if I sell it, I won't be able to get my money back. If I walk away now, I'll have wasted everything that I put into it. So as an example, if you're in a job that there's no way that you would take today, you won't walk away because you're afraid you'll have wasted everything that you put into it, all the training, all the time, and that kind of thing. But again, if you wouldn't take it today, you ought not to continue
Starting point is 00:03:49 forward. And really what it comes down to is that we have this irrationality where we think of waste as a retrospective problem, what I will have wasted, as opposed to a prospective problem, which is, is the next dollar, the next unit of effort or attention that I put into this thing going forward going to be a positive expected value? Am I going to actually win to it? And we have to start getting our eyes forward on these things. You also talk about the same issue when it comes to mountaineering and, for instance, climbing Mount Everest. When do you quit? When do you call it a day? When do you give up? Yeah. So these are all expected value problems, right? So expected value is just simply
Starting point is 00:04:34 what is your sort of weighted average of the probabilities and payoffs across a set of outcomes that are available to you. And when we're investing, we're trying to make positive expected value investments, meaning as I think about the outcomes that are available for whatever instrument it is that I'm investing in, I think that in the long run, on average, I'm going to make money. And then we can take it a step further and say, this is going to be a better expected value in comparison to other options that I have available to me. So an option could be negative expectancy on its own, meaning if I buy this stock, I'm actually losing to that decision. Or it could be, I can buy this stock and I'm winning to the decision, but not as much as I
Starting point is 00:05:22 would win if I put my money in a different stock. Okay, so that's how we want to think about expected value. So expected value only makes sense if you related to, Nikolai, what you value or what your goals are, right? So something that might be positive expected value for me might be negative expected value for you and vice versa. So we can think about, for me, I wouldn't want to start climbing Mount Everest because like the discomfort and I'd be very cold and it wouldn't really be my thing. But for you, you may be somebody who really wants to stand on the top of the world and do something that is different than almost any human being has been
Starting point is 00:06:01 able to accomplish. I'll tell you one thing, Annie, I can guarantee you I will never stand at the top of endeavors. Well, fair enough. So for you, it wouldn't be positive expectancy to start. But for me, maybe that's something where I'm willing to tolerate certain risk, in this case, death and injury, in order to be able to say, I have stood at the top of the world and done something that most people are never going to do in their whole lives. But even so, in there is some tolerance for the probability of death. So when you should stop climbing, when you should say, no, I'm going to turn around, is the moment when the probability of death and severe injury is higher than your intention at the beginning of the climb. In your book, you differentiate between quitting and failure.
Starting point is 00:06:50 Yeah. So failure for me doesn't mean just stopping something that you started and not achieving your goal. I don't think that that's really what failure is. I think that failure is one of two things. It's stopping something that is still worth it just because it's hard. So I would consider that failure, right? Like if it's still worth it, you shouldn't stop. But failure is also failing to stop something that is no longer worthwhile. So I think, for example, if you continue to climb Everest when you're in the middle of a blizzard, I would consider that a failure. So some people don't want to turn around there because they're going to process that as a
Starting point is 00:07:35 failure to have reached the summit. But I think that once you start climbing under conditions when you're clearly negative expectancy, then that's failure. If we take a very simple example like the stock, right? So we buy a stock at 50, we sell it at 40, we feel like a failure because we lost $10. But what the real failure is would be to continue to hold it when you could put those resources, that $40,
Starting point is 00:07:58 into something that is actually going to win. That's actual failure. You talk about the kill criteria. Now, how can one plan for quitting? Yeah. So here's the interesting thing about quitting. We think that if we buy a stock based on a particular thesis or we invest based on a particular thesis, that when the signals that we ought to be seeing in the future that that thesis implies don't materialize, that obviously we're going to sell and we're going to take risk off. But we know that that's not true, that that's a really bonkers intuition. And in fact, when we see those signals, we'll often escalate our commitment to the cause.
Starting point is 00:08:38 That's where we get that sort of old saw of like, well, now it's really cheap. And you actually want to buy more, right? Even though you wouldn't start it today. So how do we actually overcome that problem? Because obviously, if we're rationalizing away or ignoring the signals that tell us we should stop, how do we solve the problem? And it turns out there's a relatively simple trick that actually really drastically increases the chance that you'll stop when the time is right. And that is to think about what those signals that you might encounter are in the future, and then commit before you start to actions if you see those signals. So I'll give you a very simple example. Let's just imagine that it's 2021 and you have bought Bitcoin. And your stated reason, your thesis for buying Bitcoin is that you believe it will be a good hedge against the market going down.
Starting point is 00:09:38 Okay, so that's why you are buying it. If the market goes down, you believe that Bitcoin will be uncorrelated with that. And so it will act as a good hedge against sort of market chaos. So now I'm going to say to you, Nikolai, all right, so let's say that you buy it. How much of a correlation would you have to see over what time period between the market going down and Bitcoin going down as well? Right? So we can now write that down, right? So if you see a strong enough correlation and you determine what that is over a certain amount of time, so it's durable, that you'll actually start to take risk off
Starting point is 00:10:11 and sell Bitcoin. So if we do that in advance, you're much more likely to take risk off than if you just say, well, my thesis implies that. So obviously I'm going to pay attention when Bitcoin is going down along with the market. And what that helps you to avoid is rationalization. No, I still believe it. And now Bitcoin's cheaper, so I'll buy more. Or the other thing that will happen in order to avoid selling is thesis creep. Well, yeah, okay. It is correlated, but actually I own Bitcoin as a philosophical move, right? Or something like that. So there's a very simple example of a kill criteria that actually mountaineers use. So if you take Everest, on summit day, they leave Camp 4 at about midnight.
Starting point is 00:11:00 And the reason is that they want to get to this part of the mountain called the Southeast Ridge, which is really dangerous. You have to go up single file. They want to get to this part of the mountain called the southeast ridge which is really dangerous you have to go up single file they want to get there in daylight on the way up the mountain but they also want to get there in time that they can come back down and and traverse it again in daylight all right so this is kind of a ballet right like they've got to sort of deal with this dance so they leave at midnight but what that also means is in order to get back down the southeast ridge you must have reached the summit by 1 p.m. And if you reach the summit past 1 p.m., the probability that you're coming down that Southeast Ridge in darkness is too high. And the Southeast Ridge, again, is very, very dangerous. You don't want to traverse it in
Starting point is 00:11:38 darkness. So they actually set on that day a turnaround time of 1 p.m. No matter where you are on the mountain, you have to turn around at 1 p.m. So this is a very good, simple example of a kill criteria that gets people to turn around when they otherwise might not. Now, quitting is one aspect of decision making. But what are the other biases you account for the most in decision-making generally? So I think probably the biggest bias that I see, and actually we just had in America the playoffs with the Detroit Lions, who made some decisions in the fourth quarter that people are really criticizing. And this leads me to probably
Starting point is 00:12:26 the biggest bias that I see, which is resulting. So resulting is otherwise known as outcome bias. And it's a bias where you judge the quality of the decision by the quality of the outcome. So the Lions had a couple of times where they went for it on fourth down. And I don't know, I actually don't know what the analytics are, whether that was correct for them to do on those tries. But if it was mathematically correct, it was mathematically correct. It doesn't really matter. But none of it worked out. So I think Nate Silver posted that I was going to set fourth down decisions back, you know, a decade just because it didn't work out. So, you know,
Starting point is 00:13:06 one of the famous examples of that actually also comes from American football. In the 2015 Super Bowl, the Seattle Seahawks were on the one yard line of the New England Patriots. So they have to move the ball one yard. They're four points down, meaning they have to score a touchdown in order to go ahead. And there's only 26 seconds left in the whole game. And Pete Carroll decides to throw a pass play in this situation. And the expected play is for them to run the ball, hand it off to the running back, try to get across the goal line. But he chooses a pass play. The pass is intercepted. And people to this day think it was one of the worst calls in Super Bowl history. I'm not going to go into the details of the math, but it's not even close.
Starting point is 00:13:50 The choice that he made is the much better choice, like by a lot. So how should we evaluate a decision like that? Well, we should evaluate by, is it the best expected value decision? So in this particular case, we can work the math out, right? Like what's the probability of a touchdown? What's the probability of an interception? What's the probability of an incomplete pass? What's the probability of the run scoring?
Starting point is 00:14:14 So on and so forth, because we have base rates for all that stuff. And we can figure out like which on average is going to get you the best results. But what happens is that the outcome so overshadows, the result of the decision so overshadows, the result of the decision so overshadows our ability to think that through, that none of that really matters when we're evaluating the decision. And we can see that with the Pete Carroll decision. It's intercepted. He loses the game. Everybody says it's the worst decision in Super Bowl history. But we can do the thought experiment really easily. Well, what if it had been caught for the game-winning touchdown? Obviously, everybody would have said it was
Starting point is 00:14:47 an amazing decision. And as you know, in investing, it's like if you invest in one stock and it loses, it doesn't mean it was a bad decision. If you invest in a well-diversified portfolio over some durable period of time where you continually are performing below beta, now I can say something about your decision-making, right? But I have to have enough data points to be able to do that. And what we do instead is we take one data point, we look at the outcome and say, that was a mistake. What is your perspective on intuition and analysis and decision-making? So first of all, let me just say about intuition that intuition
Starting point is 00:15:28 can be pattern recognition, very accurate, right? intuition can be very accurate, your gut can be very accurate. The problem is, it's very hard to know if it's very accurate. And it's very hard to spot errors in your intuition if we don't make what your intuition is intuiting explicit. So basically what I try to get people to do when I'm working with clients is I take, I say, look, you have some model that you're using for making these decisions. I would like to take that model and make it explicit and then make sure that you're using for making these decisions. I would like to take that model and make it explicit and then make sure that you're judging your decisions based on that model. This is for
Starting point is 00:16:12 big decisions. So let me give you an example. So one of the favorite things that venture investors, early stage venture investors like to say, and I'm sure you've heard this is, when you ask them how they make their decisions, they say, I know a good founder when I see one. Right? Okay. So what I would say to somebody in that situation is, I can't disagree with you. You may very well know a good founder when you see one. I don't have the data to be able to disagree with you. But what do you mean by good founder? So now I'm going to ask them to be explicit by what they mean by good founder. What is your model of a good founder, right? Is it someone who's gone really deep on the problem? Is it someone who is single-minded? Is it someone who, whatever it is, right? So we're
Starting point is 00:16:56 going to write down what are the qualities of somebody, a founder that makes you put them in the category of good founder. And then I might go beyond that and say, when you think about the investment broadly, what are the things that you're thinking about, right? So they might tell me, well, I want it to be in a good market with no headwinds and growing TAM. I want the product to be something that is going to solve a problem for people, whatever. So we're now going to create a decision rubric,
Starting point is 00:17:24 which basically is an explicit representation of what your model of a good investment is. So all I'm doing is taking your belief. I'm not disagreeing with what you think. I'm taking how you model these problems and I'm making it explicit. Now what that's going to do is as you make decisions about investments, it's going to reduce the noise in your investments. It's also going to reduce the bias because it's going to be hard for you to downplay bad signals or overplay good signals. And then the other thing it's going to do is it's going to help you to up-level your team very quickly. Because let's say, Nikolai, that you are actually amazing. Now we've created the model of how you view investments. It's now explicit.
Starting point is 00:18:06 We can share that out with the other people on your team who now are going to learn a lot faster how to make great investments. Not only that, we become a data collection machine because every investment we're actually now writing down explicitly what is Nikolai's point of view on this investment. So now when we get a good or bad result, we can now go back and not fall into the resulting problem because we can go back and look at what you were thinking at the time. What are the other keys to making group decisions better? The most important part is when you are collecting people's judgments,
Starting point is 00:18:47 is when you are collecting people's judgments, you should do so in what we would call a nominal group. So a nominal group is a group of people who are working together, but for the time that they're in a nominal group, they're working independently of each other. So in other words, let's imagine that I create this investment rubric. Okay, so I've got this investment rubric, and I'm going to have you rate on a scale of one to seven, how strong the market is. I'm simplifying how strong the product is, how strong the founder is. I'm going to have you make some forecasts of whatever, like you could make a forecast of how many widgets do you believe this company is going to produce in the next six months, whatever. So it's whatever you care about in an investment. So you're going to fill that out. I don't want to get your opinion
Starting point is 00:19:25 in front of other people. So I'm going to give you that rubric independently of the next person and the next person and the next person. And this is probably the single biggest thing you can do in order to improve decision-making. Because when you talk in groups, it makes your decisions in general worse. And what I mean by that is not that you discuss other people's opinions in groups, it's that you do the opinion discovery in groups. Because remember, decisions have two parts, right? There are facts,
Starting point is 00:19:56 but then there are also your subjective judgments, right? Like how are you modeling those facts? So you could look at facts about a particular market So you could look at facts about a particular market and I could look at facts about a particular market and we could have very different judgments of that market even so. So where we're gonna be really helped as a team is to understand that you're really bullish on that market.
Starting point is 00:20:19 I'm really bearish on that market, even though we're looking at the same set of facts. And for me to truly understand what your rationale is for why you're bullish, for you to truly understand what my rationale is for why I'm bearish, for us not to try to convince each other of the other person's point of view, but to, with curiosity, understand why the person is modeling the decision that way. Because all of the increase in accuracy is going to happen in those gaps. Now, in order to do that, though, I have to know the gap exists. And the problem is if we're sort of eliciting those opinions in a group setting,
Starting point is 00:20:51 you're going to talk about how strongly you feel that this is a great market. And me over here who came into the room being bearish, I am going to be much less likely to express that opinion. Do you speak to a lot of people before you make an important decision? So if it's a really important decision, yes. Who do you speak to? So, well, I speak to people who I think are going to give me a good point of view. So I speak to my husband. And then I think about who are people that I know who have the right knowledge set to be able to actually give me good advice here.
Starting point is 00:21:27 And then here's the key, because remember this idea of, I don't want to contaminate anybody, right? I want to know what their true point of view is. When I elicit their advice, I don't tell them what I think. So this is something that I learned in poker. So obviously, if I'm coming to ask you about a hand of poker that I played, I'm asking you about something that has already occurred. So I know what my opinion was because I executed it. My opinion was I should raise or fold or call or whatever. And I also know how the hand turned out, right?
Starting point is 00:21:59 So I know both of those things. So if I come and I tell you the whole hand and then ask to rewind to ask you advice, I'm not going to get good advice for a couple of reasons. One is the resulting problem. If you know I lost the hand, you're going to tend to interpret my decisions negatively. If you know I won the hand, you're going to tend to interpret them positively. And the other thing is if you already know what I thought I should do, that's going to now infect your opinion. So the way that I would describe a hand to you is, hey, Nicola, I have a question about a hand I played. This person was in front of me. They were in first position. They raised. I would tell you things about the way that person played that you needed. Were they
Starting point is 00:22:34 aggressive? Were they not aggressive? Were they tight? Were they loose? These kinds of things. I would tell you how many chips they had. And then I would say, so now I'm in second position. I would tell you how many chips they had. And then I would say, so now I'm in second position. I look down and I have ace queen. And then that's it. I say, what would you do? What are some of the other lessons you learned from poker?
Starting point is 00:23:01 So that was a big lesson. But what's interesting in poker is that luck is your worst enemy. So let's say that we're playing chess and I lose at chess to you. This is a game that has very little luck. I can't do anything but sort of say, I've got to look back and examine my decisions because what's the explanation for why I lost, right? And if I won, I should rightly be able to say, I should look back because I think I probably made decisions well. But once we add volatility in, it becomes really hard to close a good feedback loop.
Starting point is 00:23:32 Because what I would see from players all the time, and I certainly had this urge myself, is that when they lost, it was always luck's fault. And when they won, it was always due to their skill. Of course. So one of the reasons why when I was talking to other people to get their advice, I never told them how it turned out was because I wanted to make sure I was getting their true opinion because I wanted to know win or lose. Did I play the hand well?
Starting point is 00:23:58 That's what I was really obsessed with. But it's really hard because it comes to this thing. And this is, I think, the biggest lesson that I learned from poker. And I think that Daniel Kahneman, you know, Nobel laureate, I think he also thinks this is like the biggest urge for humans that really creates a lot of decision error, is that we always want to have a positive self-narrative of our life. And there's a catch-22 in there, which is making great decisions over time and accepting your mistakes over time will, in the end, create the most positive self-narrative.
Starting point is 00:24:35 But human beings aren't that way. Human beings want to feel good about themselves now, not some future version of you who you've never even met now. So what happens when you lose a hand of poker? You feel bad, right? Oh, but you feel bad. Maybe I made mistakes. Maybe I'm a bad player.
Starting point is 00:24:59 You're not advancing that positive self-image, right, in that moment. And so what do we do? We say, oh, I got bad luck. So what should we do? What we, oh, I got bad luck. So what should we do? What we should do is say, obsessively, let me examine the decisions that I made and try to figure out win or lose, whether I maximized my expected value. Did I make the best choice every single time? Now, that's hard to do, right? I mean, that's the thing.
Starting point is 00:25:21 That's hard to do. But we can think about a two-by-two matrix, right? Where you you've got on one side, the decision quality, good decision, bad decision. And then you've got the outcome quality, good outcome, bad outcome. Right? And if you've got good, good, that would be an earned reward. If you've got good, bad, that would be bad luck. If you've got bad, good, that would be dumb luck. And if you've got bad, bad, that would be what you deserve, right? All right. So we can think about when we're thinking for ourselves, the way that we interpret the world when luck is an available explanation is everything that we're doing is trying to get back to this idea that we made a good decision. So that means that we interpret the world either as earned reward or as bad luck. This is something called self-serving bias. And boy, if you ever want to
Starting point is 00:26:13 see that in play, just go into a casino because that's all you're going to hear. I believe that Bill Gates came to the casino to watch you play. Oh, that's true. Wait, how did you know that? That's so funny. Bill Gates came to the casino to watch you play? Oh, that's true. Wait, how did you know that? That's so funny. Bill Gates kind of famously used to play very, very low stakes poker. And when I mean low stakes poker,
Starting point is 00:26:34 I mean like $3, $6 poker. So just to give you an idea, if I sat down in a $3, $6 game, I might risk $200. So Bill Gates would come in. And so this was way back in the day. Like the Bellagio Casino wasn't even open yet. It was at the Mirage. And I was playing, I remember I was playing in a game that was kind of low stakes for me. I think I was playing like an 81-60 game. And that's just
Starting point is 00:27:00 the betting limits is the maximum bet is $160. Well, this person taps me on the shoulder and says, do you mind if I sit down behind you and watch you play? And I'm about to turn around and say, no, like you're a stranger. Why would I let you watch my play? And I look up and I see it's Bill Gates. So I was like, sure, sit down and watch me play. So it's interesting. He sat down behind me and watched me play.
Starting point is 00:27:22 And he mostly asked me about bluffing. Tell me about bluffing. it was interesting. He sat down behind me and watched me play. And he mostly asked me about bluffing. Tell me about bluffing. If I'm playing a game where I can play perfectly straightforwardly, then I wouldn't really need to bluff ever, right? Because I don't, I don't need to, I wouldn't, I wouldn't really need to take that risk on. And I would only bluff in situations where I knew for a fact that I was well into positive expectancy. In other words, the bluff itself was really earning for me in that moment compared to other options that I could use that capital for, right? So imagine that I'm in a game where I know that on average, I just have a 5% edge and I can run this
Starting point is 00:27:59 bluff that is maybe, and remember this, I'm guessing at the expectancy because I can't see the other player's cards. But if I'm in a situation where playing straightforward is going to be a problem because people are going to start to be able to read me and then they're not going to pay off my good hands and that's going to reduce my earn. Now I want to bring bluffing into the equation. And the bluff itself can be 50-50 or slightly less than 50-50. I can actually be slightly negative expectancy on the bluff itself because it will earn me money later. So in other words, Nikolai, if I'm playing with you and you see that every time that I bet big, I have a good hand, at some point, you're only going to call me when you know you
Starting point is 00:28:43 have a better one. So that's going to be bad. So I'm not going to get paid point you're only gonna call me when you know you have a better one so that's gonna be bad so I'm not gonna get paid because you're only gonna call me when I'm beat so that's bad so what but if you see that sometimes when I bluff I have an eight and a three and nothing particularly good happening and you see that from me now when I do have a really good hand you're gonna not know and you're gonna have to start paint what's called paying me off. You're going to have to start calling me with weaker hands. So that's why that bluff is really important. Now, I have played in games with players who are what we would call very tight, meaning that they'll only ever bet when they know they have the best hand. In those types of games, bluffs on their own are very effective.
Starting point is 00:29:29 In other words, I'm not even using the bluff for signaling value. I'm using it just because I can push you around. Right? And then I can also play against players who are really bad, who pay you off all the time. And against those players, I would never bluff because you're already doing what I'm trying to get the bluff to do. So I would never bluff. And then in the in-between, I'll bluff depending on where I'm sitting in that spectrum. So that was really the discussion that I had with Bill Gates. It was a fun discussion. I've never seen him again since then, but he sat behind me for like an hour.
Starting point is 00:30:00 That's good. Now, general question, are you seeing big differences between men and women when it comes to risk-taking? So in general, again, you know, and these are always population differences, right? Men generally take on more risk. They're more risk-seeking. In general, again, I can take an individual woman and an individual man, and the individual woman might be much more risk-seeking, and an individual man and the individual woman might be much more risk-seeking and the individual man might be more risk-averse. But I think that that's generally true. And it's one of the reasons why if I'm thinking about a trading desk and how do you compose that desk, it's really good to have a mix. Why is that good? Because the whole point of having a team is different points of view. Remember what I said is like, let's say you're really bullish on a market. I'm really
Starting point is 00:30:50 bearish on a market. It's not so much that when we have a discussion about that, that we need Nikolai and Annie to agree. It's that we want to discover those different points of view so that whoever the ultimate decision maker is can see, well, you could model it this way and you could model it that way. So that's where we're going to learn all of the information. So we have equally informed people who have a different subjective judgment about the facts on the ground. How do you get more women into portfolio management positions, onto the trading desks and so on? You know, this is such a hard problem.
Starting point is 00:31:27 And I'll tell you, I'm just going to give an experience from poker. So the very first year that I played the main event of the World Series of Poker, this is the big world championship, 3% of the entrants were women. Wow. Now, I know, right? And it would always, like from year to year, toggle between 3% and 5%. entrance were women. Wow. Now, I know, right? And it would always, from year to year, toggle between 3% and 5%. Never above 5%, not really ever below 3%.
Starting point is 00:31:56 But this was long before poker was on television. So now poker gets on television, and there's people like me and Vanessa Selbst and Liv Bourie and Maria Ho and like a variety of women who are representing women and showing that women can do this professionally and being very successful. And in my case, I had four children. And I would talk very openly about how poker was actually a pretty good career if you have kids, because you're organizing your day where I was basically a stay at home mom. And then when my kids would go to bed, I would go play poker. Right. And so it actually,
Starting point is 00:32:39 it actually worked out pretty well in terms of my lifestyle. But anyway, we're now repping, right. We're representing women in poker. And at the time I had the intuition, and this is going back to that thing about intuition, how good is intuition? Why you want to make it explicit? I had the intuition that it was more that people didn't know it was something that you could do, right? It was more that people didn't know it was something that was totally fine for a woman to do. And so now it's been since really 2002, 2003, that women have been featured playing poker. There's been lots of success among women in poker. And last year, in the 2023 main event of the World Series of Poker, the percentage of the field that was women was
Starting point is 00:33:25 slightly over 3%. And so I look back to that first year I played, which I think was 1994, to 2023, and all that happened in the interim, and yet there aren't more women entering that event. So my answer to you is, I don't know, right? Like, I have this intuition that if you get to people early and you educate them, if you start thinking about how do you get women, like, more comfortable in these very risky, I mean, not risky in the long run, but like very risk-heavy, like volatile decision-making environments that naturally will get women to come into those fields. It's a problem that I would love to solve, but at least in poker, I didn't see it solved. So the answer is, I don't know.
Starting point is 00:34:18 At which stage in your life did you start to get interested in decision-making? So I started getting interested in decision-making actually in graduate school. So people think of me as a poker player, but they don't know I was an academic prior to that. So I was working on my PhD at Penn and I was there for five years working in cognitive science. And while my area of concentration
Starting point is 00:34:41 wasn't decision-making in particular, it was learning, in particular, it was learning in particular first language acquisition. But I also like took classes with John Barron, who's like a giant in the field of judgment and decision-making. So first language acquisition is a problem of learning under uncertainty. So right at the end of graduate school, I ended up pivoting for a variety of reasons, one of which was some health reasons. And that's when I started playing poker. And for eight years, I just dove into this problem, which as we've discussed, and we only got the tip of the iceberg, poker is just this amazing laboratory to think
Starting point is 00:35:17 about decision-making under uncertainty. What goes wrong? How can you make it go right? And then in 2002, I got asked by a hedge fund to speak to their traders about how poker might inform risk. And what I talked about was how poker and cognitive science informed this idea of risk attitudes in relationship to the path that you've gotten on to your decision. So what I talked about was if you've gotten on to your decision. So what I talked about was if you've been losing, how does that affect your risk attitude? If you've been winning, how does that affect your risk attitude? So it was that moment in 2002 that I really
Starting point is 00:35:55 realized that there was this very interesting conversation to be had between cognitive science and poker, where the cognitive science could really inform my thinking about poker and make me a better poker player. And the poker could really inform my thinking about cognitive science and make me a better cognitive scientist. What I kind of realized was that from the time I really was in college working as an assistant, actually a research assistant to a cognitive scientist, as an assistant, actually research assistant to a cognitive scientist, what I've been really obsessed with is this idea of uncertainty and what that does to the quality of your decisions. And I think because I played poker, I've been obsessed with how do you mitigate those errors, right? It's not enough for me just to identify an error. I want to know
Starting point is 00:36:42 how you mitigate it because that's really what I was obsessed with as a practitioner. And what are you curious about now? What are you thinking about? Yeah. What I'm thinking about now and what I'm curious about now is, so I think that there's a lot of talk and work in the space of, you know, misinformation and disinformation, which is really kind of coming from a premise of people are lying to you. And I actually think that people aren't mostly lying to you. I think that when people give you a data point, I think that generally the data that they're giving you is probably going to survive a fact check. And that's certainly true of data that you generate within your own life and your own business. fact check. And that's certainly true of data that you generate within your own life and your own business, right? So when someone tells you, for example, that, and this happened a couple
Starting point is 00:37:30 years ago, that in August, 58% of the people who died of COVID were vaccinated, you can go look that up and it will survive a fact check. So what I'm obsessed with is how do you model that fact? In other words, how do you take something that's true and figure out what the truth is? And that takes a checklist of understanding how to model this fact. So if we take this fact of 58% of the people who died of COVID were vaccinated, we have to go through a series of questions, the most important of which is what percentage of the population is vaccinated. Because otherwise what will happen is you'll say, oh, vaccinations don't
Starting point is 00:38:09 work because more people died who were vaccinated than were unvaccinated. But once you know that over 80% of the population in that month were vaccinated, now all of a sudden that number looks very different to you. And then you could go beyond that and you could age match. You could say, well, let's compare 70-year-olds to 70-year-olds and so on and so forth. And then you could go beyond that and you could age match. You could say, well, let's compare 70 year olds to 70 year olds and so on and so forth. And then it turns out vaccinations in that month were five times better. But somebody looking at that,
Starting point is 00:38:34 nobody's trying to lie to you, right? They're trying to give you a data point that's gonna help you decide. And if you don't understand how to model that, how can you come up with what the truth of the matter is? And I've been super obsessed with that topic recently. Well, that sounds like it's going to be a good book. Now, taking all your experiences as a poker player, as an academic, and having lived a little while, if you were to translate that into advice to young people, what would it be?
Starting point is 00:39:03 If you were to translate that into advice to young people, what would it be? Hmm. All right. So if I were to translate that into advice for young people, look, here's the fact of your life. There are only two things that are going to determine how your life turns out. One is luck, and one is the quality of your decisions. Luck you have no control over. You can't control the circumstances of your birth, for example.
Starting point is 00:39:30 And we know that people are born into different circumstances that change sort of the distribution of outcomes that are available to them. And you can't do anything about that. So first of all, embrace the luck. It is what it is, right? I can't do anything about it. But what you can do something about is the quality of your decisions. And over time, if you're making better decisions
Starting point is 00:39:51 than you otherwise would have, those gains will accrue over time. And it's going to change. That's the thing that can change the trajectory of your life. So it's this idea of while you can't control luck, you are an agent of your own decisions. And if you can become totally focused on how do I improve the quality of your decisions, that's the thing that can change your life because better decisions lead to better outcomes for individuals. And in fact, that also leads to better outcome for society because society is a collection of individuals. So really start focusing on your decisions and become an agent in your own decisions. I think that's a great place to end.
Starting point is 00:40:37 Really good advice. Big thanks to you for being on this podcast. And we look forward to reading your next book. Well, thank you so much. This was super fun.

There aren't comments yet for this episode. Click on any sentence in the transcript to leave a comment.