Lex Fridman Podcast - #303 – Steve Keen: Marxism, Capitalism, and Economics

Episode Date: July 17, 2022

Steve Keen is a heterodox economist and author. Please support this podcast by checking out our sponsors: - Weights & Biases: https://lexfridman.com/wnb - Skiff: https://skiff.org/lex - Indeed: https:...//indeed.com/lex to get $75 credit - NetSuite: http://netsuite.com/lex to get free product tour - InsideTracker: https://insidetracker.com/lex to get 20% off EPISODE LINKS: Steve's Twitter: https://twitter.com/profstevekeen The New Economics (book): https://amzn.to/3zb4eg4 PODCAST INFO: Podcast website: https://lexfridman.com/podcast Apple Podcasts: https://apple.co/2lwqZIr Spotify: https://spoti.fi/2nEwCF8 RSS: https://lexfridman.com/feed/podcast/ YouTube Full Episodes: https://youtube.com/lexfridman YouTube Clips: https://youtube.com/lexclips SUPPORT & CONNECT: - Check out the sponsors above, it's the best way to support this podcast - Support on Patreon: https://www.patreon.com/lexfridman - Twitter: https://twitter.com/lexfridman - Instagram: https://www.instagram.com/lexfridman - LinkedIn: https://www.linkedin.com/in/lexfridman - Facebook: https://www.facebook.com/lexfridman - Medium: https://medium.com/@lexfridman OUTLINE: Here's the timestamps for the episode. On some podcast players you should be able to click the timestamp to jump to that time. (00:00) - Introduction (07:26) - Defining economics (14:26) - Schools of economics (38:45) - Karl Marx (57:00) - Labor theory of value (1:16:45) - Socialism (1:31:48) - Soviet Union (1:45:08) - China (2:05:00) - Climate change (2:27:03) - Economics vs Politics (2:35:06) - Minsky's model (2:49:50) - Financial crisis (2:55:07) - Inflation (3:08:21) - Marxism (3:15:42) - Space and AI (3:21:47) - Advice for young people (3:25:38) - Depression (3:30:10) - Love (3:34:11) - Mortality

Transcript
Discussion (0)
Starting point is 00:00:00 The following is a conversation with Steve Keane, a brilliant economist that criticizes much of modern economics and proposes new theories and models that integrate some ideas and ditch others from very thinkers, from Karl Marx to John Maynard Keynes to Hammond Minsky. In fact, a lot of our conversation is about Karl Marx and Marxian economics. He has been a scholar of Karl Marx's work for many years, so this was a fascinating exploration. He has written several books I recommend including the new economics and manifesto and the bunking economics. And now a quick few second mention of each sponsor. Check them out in the description, it's the best way to support this podcast. We got weights and biases for machine learning, skiff for email, indeed for hiring, net suite for efficiency, and inside tracker for longevity. Choose wisely my friends.
Starting point is 00:00:58 And now onto the full ad reads. As always, no ads in the middle. I try to make these things interesting, but if you skip them, if you must, please still check out the sponsors. I enjoy their stuff. Maybe you will too. This show is brought to you by a new sponsor, Wates and Biasis, the company that helps machine learning teams build better models faster. They help you debug, compare models, reproduce models that other people put together, and that includes architectures, hyperparameters, all version through. So git commits, you can play around and visualize model weights, you can look at GPU usage, you can look at data sets, the predictions, and the evaluation sets.
Starting point is 00:01:43 So all of those different aspects involved in building a real world, or a large scale, or an effective machine learning model, you could do all of that together with the team and they can version it like you would a piece of code. But there are also huge supporters of the machine learning research community. There are tools that are free to use for personal use
Starting point is 00:02:01 and their team's feature is available for free to academic researchers. Companies like OpenAI, Nvidia, IROBOT use it. They do it for all the machine learning model building that they do. Our weights and buys it gives you a better way to stay organized and be more productive, join over 200,000 machine learning engineers
Starting point is 00:02:21 and data scientists when they sign up at lexfreedman.com slash wnb This show is also brought to you by skiff a private end-to-end encrypted email First thing to say is that it's actually really difficult to build a compelling accessible almost enjoyable Graph graphic user interface for email. I mean, so much of email is about the efficiency of reading, of organizing, of filtering through emails, the good ones, the bad ones, of replying, all that kind of stuff. So, skiff masters this.
Starting point is 00:03:01 They do an incredible job of building an intuitive, easy to use, clear interface. Now, all of that is on top of an end-to-end encrypted email, so nobody can track your email, not even skip, so it's just between you and the recipient. And they have a bunch of different features. First of all, fast and effective search. You can do custom domains for your email. You can easily migrate from other email services like Gmail, Pro-Tamail, and Outlook. You can do all of this if you sign up at skiff.com slash Lex. That's skif.com slash Lex. This shows also brought to you by indeed a hiring website. I've used them as part of many hiring efforts I've done for the teams I've led in the past. They have tools I can deed instant match,
Starting point is 00:03:48 giving you quality candidates whose resumes and indeed fit your job description immediately. There are very few things in life and I will not shut up about this as important as the people you surround yourself with. That includes your friends, your family and the people you work with. And some of the coolest, some of the most difficult things you do in life is at work. Whatever that is, hopefully it's something that you're really passionate about. So that means you're spending a huge amount of hours at work. You're doing something that's truly challenging. You're doing something that's hopefully truly fulfilling. And the people around you will define your growth, will define how successful you are, will define how much meaning you get from that thing.
Starting point is 00:04:28 So hiring is really, really important. So you have to use the best tools for the job, and indeed is one of the greatest out there. They have a special offer for listeners, only available for a limited time. Check it out at indeed.com slash Lex. This show is brought to you by NetSuite. available for a limited time, check it out at Indeed.com slash Lex. This show is brought to you by NetSuite.
Starting point is 00:04:49 NetSuite allows you to manage financials, HR, inventory, e-commerce, and many more business-related details all in one place, running a company, which is something that I hope to do in the future. I'm talking about a large company, like one that has HR and a financial person who I should really probably get very soon. So, if you're running a company like that, all of the mess of that is not fun and it's so critical to the success of a company. Like, the thing I love doing is the design, the engineering, the building, the idea stage,
Starting point is 00:05:23 the idea development, all that kind of stuff. But in order to make an actual business run, especially if you're doing e-commerce and inventory management, you have to have the best tools for the job. NetSuite does just that. It makes all those messy, painful things easy for you to do. You can go to NetSuite.com slash Lex to access their one-of-a-kind financing program. This show is also brought to you by Inside Tracker. Service I used to track biological data. They have a bunch of plans, most of which include blood tests that give you a lot of information that you can use to make decisions about your health.
Starting point is 00:06:00 They have algorithms, sexy machine learning algorithms that analyze your blood data, DNA data, and fitness tracker data to provide you with a clear picture of what's going on inside you. And to offer you science-backed recommendations for positive diet and lifestyle changes. I love this idea. This is the future. It's obvious that the decisions, lifestyle decisions, health decisions, medical decisions that you make about your body should be based on data from your body and not just instantaneous snapshots but longitudinal data. So, across time, instead, most of medicine, most health, lifestyle, advice is given based
Starting point is 00:06:38 on population data and very minimal investigation what actually is going on inside your body and what is actually best for you. So inside track is a giant leap into the direction of using data to give you personalized advice. Go to inside tracker.com slash Lex. For a limited time, you get special savings for being a listener of this very podcast. This is the Lex Freepin podcast to support it. Please check out our sponsors in the description and now dear friends, here's Steve Keane. Let's start with a big question. What is economics or maybe what is or should be the goal of economics?
Starting point is 00:07:35 Well, it should be, I understand how human civilization comes about and how it can be maintained. And that's not what it's been at all. So we have a discipline which has the right name and the wrong soul. What is the soul of economics? The soul of economics really is to explain how do we manage to build a civilization that elevates us so far above the energy and consumption and knowledge levels of the base environment of the earth. Because if you think about, and this is actually working
Starting point is 00:08:08 from a work I've learned from Tim Garrett, who's one of my research colleagues as an atmospheric physicist, and his idea is that we exploit these high-grade energy sources from the sun itself to coal, nuclear, et cetera, et cetera, which means we can maintain a level of human civilization well above what we'd have if we were just still running around with rocks
Starting point is 00:08:28 and stones and spears. So it's that elevation above the base level of the planet, which is human civilization. And if we didn't have this energy we were exploiting, if we didn't use the environment to elevate ourselves above what's possible in the background, then you and I wouldn't be talking into microphones. We might be doing drum beats and stuff like this, but we wouldn't be having the sort of conversation we have. So we'd explain how they came about. That was the economic should be doing, and it's not. So this is the greatest thing that there is ever created, is what you're saying, this conversation.
Starting point is 00:09:02 Yeah, we're the most elaborate construction on the planet. And like, that's not what we've done. We've denigrated the planet itself. We don't have respect for the fact that life itself is an incredible creation. And I, my ultimate, if I had to see how humanity is going to survive what we're putting ourselves through, then it would, we'd have to come out of it as a species which sees its role as preserving and respecting life. I like how you took my silly incredible statement and made it into a serious one about how amazing life is.
Starting point is 00:09:37 Life is incredible and humans don't respect it enough. We trash it. And that's what's economics. I think it's played a huge role in that. So I actually regard my discipline, I would never call it a profession little owner science. My discipline has probably helped bring about the termination potential, the feasible termination of human civilisation. Strong words. Okay, let's return to the basics of economics. So what is the soul and the practice of economics?
Starting point is 00:10:07 What should what should be the goal of it? Because you're speaking very poetically, but we'll also speak pragmatically about the tools of economics, the variables of economics, the metrics, the goals, the models, practically speaking, what are the goals of economic? Well, in terms of the tools we use, we should be using the tools that engineers use, frankly. And that sounds ridiculously simple, because you would expect that economists are using up-to-date techniques that are common in other sciences where you're dealing with similar ideas of stocks and flows and interactions between the environment and a system and so on. And that's fundamentally systems engineering. And that's what we should be using as the tools of economics.
Starting point is 00:10:53 Now, if you look at what economists actually do, the sophisticated stuff involves difference equations. And like, difference equations, you know, if you've done enough mathematics, as you have, you know, different equations are useful for like individual level processes. If you're talking about a autonomous one, it'll go from state T to T plus one, T plus two, and so on. But not when you're talking at the aggregate level, they're used differential equations to measure it all, economists have been using different equations. So there's like a book, I think it's by Sargent and one other, a called Advanced Methods in Economics
Starting point is 00:11:27 using Python, two volume set. It's about close to 2,000 pages, and four of those pages are on differential equations. The rest is all different equations. So, they're using entirely the wrong mathematics to start with. For people listening, what is difference equations versus differential equations? The difference equation is like you can do in a spreadsheet. You'll have, this is without even
Starting point is 00:11:49 90, this is without even 91, 92, 93, 94. So you have discrete jumps in time. Whereas the differential equation says there's a process moving through time. And you will have a rate of change of the variable, is a function of the state of itself and other variables and rates of change of those variables. And that is what you use when you're doing an aggregate model. So if you're modeling water, for example, or fluid dynamics, you have a set of differential equations describing the entire body of fluid moving through a time, you don't try to model the discrete motion motion of each molecule of H2O. So at the aggregate level you use differential
Starting point is 00:12:30 equations for processes that occur through time and that's economics. It occurs through time. You should be using that particular technology but some economists do learn differential equations but they don't learn stability analysis. So they simply assume equilibrium is stable and they work in equilibrium terms all the time and that it is the technical level it's an incredibly complicated way of modeling the world using entirely the wrong tools. Okay, we'll talk about that because it's unclear what the right tools are. Maybe it's more clear to you, but I've got to make a clear to an audience.
Starting point is 00:13:12 Well, so this is a very complicated world. It's a complex world to talk about their, some of the most complex systems on earth are the human mind, the economy and the biosphere. Yep. So we'll, we'll go, you know, I'm, we'll go to that place. I'm fascinated by complex systems. I'm humbled by them, even at their simplest level of like cellular automata. I'm not sure what the right tools are to understand that, especially when part. Uh, part of the complex system is like a hierarchy of other complex systems. So you said the economy is a fascinating complex system, but it's made up of human minds. And those are interesting. Those are interesting, perhaps impossible
Starting point is 00:13:58 to model, but we can try and we can try to figure out how to approximate them. And maybe that's the challenge of economics. Okay, we'll keep returning to the basics. Let us try to learn something from history. I also see as part of economics, as us trying to figure out stuff and there's a few smart folks that write books, throughout human history, and sometimes they name schools of economics after them.
Starting point is 00:14:25 So let us take a stroll through history. Can you describe at a high level what are the different schools of economics, perhaps ones that are interesting to you, perhaps ones that the difference between which reveals something useful or insightful for our conversation. So, you know, you could, you know, classical post-cansian, Austrian, I like the biophysical economics and so on. Other heterodox economics schools that you find interesting. Okay. I actually find interesting a school which went extinct about 250 years ago. That's where I'd like to start from. And they're called the Physigocrats. And the name itself implies where their knowledge came from because if you go back far enough in history, we didn't do autopsies. But when you started doing autopsies, they found wires, they found
Starting point is 00:15:22 tubes, et cetera, et cetera., they found tubes, etc., etc. And they started seeing the body as a circulation system, and they played the same sort of logic to the economy. And they became out of an agricultural economy, which is France, and they saw that the wealth came effectively from the sun. So they saw all wealth comes from, they said the soil, but what they really mean is the sun, the soil absorbs the energy of the sun. One seed plants, a thousand leaves seeds come back. There is no surplus. We are simply mining
Starting point is 00:15:50 what we can find out of the natural economy. That's what we should have stayed and developed from that forward. We then went through the classical school of economics, which comes out of Adam Smith. Smith, coming from Scotland, looked at what the Physiocrats said, and what the Physiocrats argued was that agriculture is the source of all wealth, and the manufacturing sector is sterile. That's literally the term they use to describe the manufacturing sector. What does sterile mean? Sterile means you don't extract value, you simply change the shape of value. So the value comes from the soil?
Starting point is 00:16:24 Yeah, it comes from the soil. That's the free gift of nature. That's literally the phrase of value. So the value comes from the soil? Yeah, it comes from the soil. That's the free gift of nature. That's literally the phrase they used. And we then distribute the free gift of nature around. And we need carriages, which was the manufacturing turn they used at the time, as well as wheat. So to make the carriages, we take what's been taken from the soil.
Starting point is 00:16:44 And we convert it to a different form, but there is no value added in manufacturing. So Smith looked at that and said, well, I'm from Scotland. And we've got loose industries. You know, we make stuff when it's our scenery. And he said, no, it's not land that gives us the source of value. It's labor. Yeah.
Starting point is 00:17:01 Now, that led to the classical school of thought and that said that all value comes from labor. That value is objective, so it's the amount of effort you put in, that the price to things will exchange for reflects the relative effort that's involved in the manufacturing. So this computer takes two hours to make and this bottle takes two minutes to make, then there's, this is worth 60 times as much as that. Okay. They didn't talk about marginal cost. It was absolute cost effectively. They didn't talk about utility as a subjective thing. They ridiculed subjective utility theory. That led to Marx and Marx is probably the most brilliant mind in the history of economics. The only other competitor I'd see is Schumpeter, possibly Cain's, but then my turns of ranking of intellects of you, Marx, Schumpeter Cain, since in terms of the outstanding capacities to think. But Marx then turned that
Starting point is 00:17:55 classical school, which was pro-capitalism and anti-futal, into a critique of capitalism, which led to the neoclassical school coming along as a defensive capitalism, but they defended it using the ideas of the subjective theory of value, so that value does not reflect effort, it's the satisfaction individuals get from different objects that determines their value, marginal utility. It's the marginal cost that determines how much they sell for. Capitalism equilibrates marginal cost and marginal utility. And the concepts of equilibrium and marginal this and marginal that became the neoclassical school. And that's still the dominant school now 150 years later. So that's the one that everybody learns. And when you first learn economics,
Starting point is 00:18:42 if you don't have the critical background that I manage to acquire, that's what you think is economics. The marginal utility equilibrium oriented analysis of mainstream economics. And for example, they ignore money. People think economists, you must be an expert on money because you're an economist. Well, in fact, economists learn literally in the first few weeks at university that money is irrelevant. They say money illusion. So they represent people's Tastes using what they call indifference curves and they're like consequence on a on a weather map If you look at an iso-quantit shows you all the points of the same pressure So you can be you can be here or you can be in Denver and the air pressure can be the same if you're in the same whether you and it So you just draw a cell that links together.
Starting point is 00:19:26 Well, they do the same thing with utility and say lots of bananas and very few coconuts can give you the same utility as lots of coconuts and very few bananas and you draw basically a high pervola running down and linking the two. And they'll say, well, that's your utility. That describes your tastes. And then we have your income and there's given your income, you can buy that many bananas completely, or that many coconuts, or a straight line combination of the two. And then if we double the price, nominal price of coconuts, and double the nominal price
Starting point is 00:19:57 of bananas, and double your income, what happens? And the correct answer is, oh, nothing, sir. You know, you stay at the same point of tangency between what your budget is and Which particular Utility curve gives you the maximum satisfaction So that gets ingrained into them and they think anybody who worries about money suffers from money illusion You know you were therefore Ignorant of the deep insights of economics if you think money actually matters
Starting point is 00:20:23 So you have an entire theory of economics which presumes we exchange through data. Like I'll swap you that Microsoft surface for, I'll take two of those for one of these. We do this bartering type arrangement. In fact, that only works if money plays no creative role in the economy. And that's where you find reading shumpader, the insight that's the school of thought that I come from, that says money is essential. Money actually adds to demand, and I'll talk about that later on.
Starting point is 00:20:54 So that's the neoclassical school, that ends up being subjective theory of value. Non-monitry, as though everything happens in butter, and focusing on equilibrium, as though everything happens in equilibrium, or if you get disturbed from equilibrium, you return back to it again. And that mindset describes capitalism as most interesting feature is that it reaches equilibrium. Now, what planet are we on to believe that? Because if you look at the real world, the real exciting world of capitalism in which we live, change is by far the most
Starting point is 00:21:33 obvious characteristic of it. There's no equilibrium. There's no equilibrium. It's unstable. And as a mathematician, it's easy to, you work with stability analysis. You work out what the It's easy to work with stability analysis. You work out what the Jacobian is. You work out the up and up exponents in a complex system. You're used to the idea that equilibrium is unstable. But economists get schooled and believing that everything happens in equilibrium and they don't learn stability analysis.
Starting point is 00:21:58 So all that stuff is missing. So under the schools of thought, the treating the economy as an equilibrium system, which was what the Clasnico classical school did, is what Cain's disturbed. And he really disturbed it by talking about fundamentally that uncertainty determines our decisions about the future. So, when we consume, you know, you know, if you like Pfizer or whatever you, in particular, drink we want to have, you know, the current situation. But to invest, you must be making guesses about the future.
Starting point is 00:22:29 But you don't know the future. So what do you do? You extrapolate what you currently know. And this is a terrible basis on which to plan for the future. But there's the only thing you can do when there is no possibility of solid calculation. So investment is therefore subject to uncertainty. And therefore you will get volatility out of investment.
Starting point is 00:22:53 You will get fads of course, berms and slumps coming out of that. Because people extrapolate forward the current conditions. And that's the normal state of a capitalist economy. And Schumpeter argued that that's what gives it its creativity as well. The fact that you can perceive a potential demand. But you don't, first of all, you don't know whether that demand's going to work. Secondly, you don't know who your competitor is going to be,
Starting point is 00:23:15 whether somebody's going to be ahead of you or behind. If there's a fragile over-invest, OK? All this stuff is the real nature of capitalism. And that's what we're trying to capture. The dynamic, non-equilibrium, monetary, violence and creativity of capitalism. That's what we should be analyzing. And the post-cansigan school has gone in that orientation. There have been, in my opinion, inhibited by learning their mathematics from the classical economists, so they don't have enough of the technology of complex systems.
Starting point is 00:23:48 It's only a really tiny handful of people working in complex systems analysis in post-cansion economics, but that is to me the most interesting area. So there are tools maybe lacking, but they fundamentally accept the instability of things. That's right. And so that's what makes them interesting. So let me try to summarize what you said And then you say, how stupid I am. Okay. So then there was the physio crats that thought value came from the land. Yep. Then there's Adam Smith who said, nah, value comes from human labor. That was, that was the classical school. And then
Starting point is 00:24:28 neoclassical is value comes from like bananas and coconuts. The preference, human preference is like human happiness. How happy, how happy a banana makes you. And then the Kenzian and the post-kansian were like, yeah, you can't, you can't, you can't, you can never, the moment you try to put value to a banana and a coconut, you're already working in the past. Yeah, it's always going to be chaos and stability and then you just, you're, you're fishing in uncertain waters and that that's where to embrace that and come up with tools that model that well. And also Joseph Shampaiter, what school would you put him under? Is the Acanzian or is the Austrian economics?
Starting point is 00:25:16 He's an Austrian. The Austrian was denied. Okay. That's the intriguing piece from Austria, but he's not an Austrian economist. There are elements of the Austrian school to thought which are worthwhile. What is Austrian economics in this beautiful whirlwind picture that you painted? Okay. Austrian economics grew out of the, that of the rebellion against the classical school.
Starting point is 00:25:39 So you had three intellects who mainly led the growth of the neoclassical school back in the 1870s, as William Jevons from England, Menga, who's from Austria, and Valras from France. And Valras tried to work out a set of equations to describe a multi-product economy, where there's numerous producers and numerous consumers. Everybody's both a producer and numerous consumers, everybody's both a producer and a consumer, and you try to work out a vector of prices that will give you equilibrium in all markets instantaneously. And that's his equilibrium orientation.
Starting point is 00:26:15 Jevons is also in about equilibrium, but he worked more at the aggregate level. So this is supply, curve and demand, curve, and that's what gave him a martial ultimately codified. Menga was pretty much saying that, well, yes, there might be an equilibrium, but you're going to get disturbed from it all the time. You'll be above or below the equilibrium. Why came out of the Austrian school was an acceptance of that sort of vision that the market should reach equilibrium, but then said, well, you get disturbed away from the equilibrium.
Starting point is 00:26:41 And that's what gives you the vitality of capitalism because an entrepreneur will see an arbitrage advantage and try to close that gap and that will give you innovation over time. And Shumpeta went beyond that and saw the role of money and said that an entrepreneur, an entrepreneur, somebody with a great idea and no money. Yeah. Okay. So to become a capitalist, you've got to get money. And therefore, you've got to approach the finance sector to get the money and the finance sector creates money and also creates a debt for the entrepreneur. And so you get this financial engine turning up as well. And you will get movements away from equilibrium out of that. You won't necessarily head back towards the equilibrium. So, Shumpeta has a rich vision of capitalism in which money plays an essential role, in which you will be disturbed from equilibrium
Starting point is 00:27:32 all the time. And that is really, I think, a much closer vision of actual capitalism than anything by even the industrial living Austrian, you know, Hayek, etc., etc. They, and certainly Ron Bartow, I find totally like reading a cardboard cutout version of the wealth of nations. It's, I find his worth trivial. But Sean Pater was rich, well, with the same foundations as the Austrians. But because he talked about the importance of money that took him away from the Austrian vision, which is very much based on a hard
Starting point is 00:28:08 money idea of capitalism, Shumpeta said, you needed the capacity of the financial sector to create money to empower entrepreneurs. And that's a very important vision. So Shumpeta is the deviation from equilibrium, that's where all the fun happens, that's all the magic happens, that's where all the magic happens. That's the magic of capitalism. And like the Austrians, because they focus on the deviation from equilibrium a biter than their classicals, but they still have this belief in the, you know, your reach equilibrium ultimately, or your head back towards it.
Starting point is 00:28:38 Whereas they don't have an explanation of capitalism that gives you cycles apart from having the wrong rate of interest. Okay. So there's no role for an explanation of capitalism that gives you cycles apart from having the wrong rate of interest. So, there's no role for an accumulation of debt over time. So what Shumpeda gave us was a vision of the creativity of capitalism being driven by entrepreneurs who are funded by money creation by the finance sector. And that's fundamentally the world in which we live. So there's also the kids these days are all into modern monetary theory and that about. Okay. Modern monetary theory is accounting.
Starting point is 00:29:14 When I summarize it bluntly, it's simply saying, let's do the accounting because what money is is a creature of double entry bookkeeping. Okay. What's double entry bookkeeping? Bank, so this was invented back on the 1500s in Italy. I forgot in the particular merchant who did it based on some Arabic ideas as well.
Starting point is 00:29:33 But the thing is, if you want to keep track of your financial flows, then you divide what you, all the financial claims on you, you divide into claims you have on somebody else, which your assets claim somebody else has on you, all the financial claims on you, you divide into, claims you haven't somebody else, which your assets, claims somebody else has on you, which your liabilities, and the gap between you, the two is your equity. So you record every transaction twice on one row. Okay, so for example, if you and I do a financial transfer, you have a bank account, I have a bank account. Your bank account will go down, mine goes up. And there's some of the operation as zero.
Starting point is 00:30:10 But on the other hand, if I go to a bank and borrow money, then my account goes up, they put money in my deposit account, the bank's assets go up. And they're still the same sum applies. Assets minus liabilities minus equity equals zero. Now that's simply saying money is a counting, a creature of accounting, it's not a creature of a commodity. So if you think about how Austrian think about money
Starting point is 00:30:32 and how gold bugs think about money and Bitcoin enthusiasts, if they're any left, think about money, what they see is money is an object, okay? And you and I can both have more gold. If we're both willing to go to this, you know, a mine, a mine somewhere and dig a few holes and get a few specs of gold out. So there's no competition or no interaction between you and me if money is gold. And I think money should be an object, a commodity. But money fundamentally is not a commodity. It's a claim on somebody else.
Starting point is 00:31:03 That's money is an essence. So when you do it, you must use double and triple keeping to do it. And then when you do, you find all the answers that come out of thinking as money is a commodity, you're wrong. So for example, and I've got Elon on this one. So I want to get this rid of Elon because I saw him making a comment about this a few weeks ago on Twitter. He said that it's wrong for the government. Effectively, it seems wrong for the government to always be in deficit. OK? Now, when you look at it and say, well, how is money created? How does money come about when it's not a commodity-like gold when you dig up out of the ground, when it's actually
Starting point is 00:31:36 social relations between people that create money? Well, money is the fundamentally the liabilities of the banking sector. When you, if we make a transfer between us, your deposit account goes down, might as a deposit account goes up. Those are exchanges on the liability side of the banking sector. But if we have a transaction with the bank, then if the bank lends us money, its loans go up, its deposits go up. Again, that same balance. So you've got to look and say money, therefore, is fundamentally the liabilities of the banking
Starting point is 00:32:12 sector. So how do you create additional liabilities? You must have an operation which occurs both on the liability side and the asset side of the banking sector. So if you and I make a transaction, no money is created. Existing money is redistributed. But if you go to a bank and I take out a bank loan, then money is created by the bank loan. So the liabilities of the banking sector rise, the assets rise, their balance, but more liabilities means the banking sector means more money.
Starting point is 00:32:41 So that's how private banks create money. And that's what I first started working on when I became an academic about, well, 35 years ago, the actual dynamics of private money creation. But the government has the same sort of story. If the government runs a deficit, it spends more money on the individuals in the economy than it taxes them, which means their bank accounts increase. So a government deficit creates money for the private sector. Okay, so that's when money creation occurs from the government. So it puts more money into people's bank accounts by spending, by welfare payments, then it takes out by taxation.
Starting point is 00:33:24 So that's creating new money, and then on the other side on the bank, the money turns up in the reserve accounts of the banks, which are basically the private banks bank accounts at the central bank. So rather than the asset of private money creation being loans, the asset of government money creation as reserves. Okay. Right. Money creation. being loans, the asset of government money creation as reserves. Okay. Right. Money creation. Money creation. It's a good thing. So you mentioned about this stuff like private money creation with the liabilities and the banks and then the government is doing the reserves. Boba Blah, at the end of the day, there's a bunch of
Starting point is 00:34:01 printers that are printing money. And then you also said something interesting, which is social relations between humans is what creates money. I think my mind has blown several times over the past minute. So it's difficult for me to reconstruct the pieces of my mind back together. But basic question is money creation a good thing or a bad thing money creation is a good thing Because money creation is what allows comments to happen. Isn't there a conservation of no there isn't I had to have arguments with this is a stover this and it took me a long time to answer They thought the sum total of all money is zero. Yeah, okay It's the sum time of total of all assets and liabilities is zero. If you
Starting point is 00:34:46 mention your assets minus your liabilities as your equity and your asset is somebody else's liability and your liability is somebody else's asset. When we're talking about financial assets and this is another mind blowing thing that I've just recently solved myself. So the sumtile of all financial assets and liabilities is zero. Okay, wait, I'm going to interrupt you rudely. What are assets? What are liabilities? Assets are your claims on somebody else. So specific. Give me an example of an asset. Okay, do you have a mortgage for this house? No, I'm renting. You're renting. There you go. Well,
Starting point is 00:35:24 if you had a mortgage, that would be your liability. That would be my liability. Okay. The mortgage with a bank's asset. Right. Okay, if you add the two together, you get zero. Okay, so that's zero. That's zero.
Starting point is 00:35:36 The money is the liability side of the banking sector. Okay, assets are the assets on the other side can be either created by the banking sector which is where you get bank loans or created by the government where you get reserves. But money is the liability. If you think about protons and anti-protons in that sense, money is like the anti-proton. It's the negative, the liability. But wait, wait, the liability is the negative. How's that money? I thought money is the positive. What is the liability for the banking sector is an asset for you and me. An asset includes money.
Starting point is 00:36:15 Yeah. If you have a bank account, you'd have a bank account and you'd have some cash. Those are your assets. But the bank account is a liability, the banking sector, and the cash is a liability, the Federal Reserve. Okay, so what's money? Well, money is the promise of a third party that we both accept to close our transaction. And this is the bank. That's a bank. Yeah, this is one of the most important works I've ever read is a work by a wonderful, now unfortunately deceased, tiny Italian economist, called Augusto Graziani. And he's the most wonderful personality. Augusto, I met him in a few occasions, is one of the few human beings who can speak
Starting point is 00:37:01 in perfectly formed paragraphs, okay, superbly eloquent. And what he did was write a paper called the monetary theory of production. And you can find it downloaded on the web. It's a pretty much open source now. And what he said is what distinguishes a monetary economy from a barter economy. So I said in a barter economy, what we do is, I'll give you two of these for one of those. Yeah, okay, barter. Just working at a relative price,
Starting point is 00:37:30 there are two of us involved, and there are two commodities. So, with money, money is a triangular transaction. There is one commodity, I wanna buy that kind of drink off here. Two people, and the price that's worked out ends up being in a transfer from the promises to pay the bank that the buyer has to the promises to pay
Starting point is 00:37:52 the bank that the seller has. So if I, we saw what you have is a monetary transaction in a capitalist economy involves three agents, the buyer, the seller, and the bank. So the bank goes, that's a bit part of it bank. So the bank goes as a part of it. Well, the bank has to be part of it. What, when I hand you the money, you accept that as you've now got rather than it's a bank promising to pay me something, it's now the bank promising to pay you
Starting point is 00:38:16 something. And we exchange the promises of banks. And that's fundamentally money. So money is fundamentally a threereesome and everybody gets fucked. Is that a good way to put it? No, it leads to the good for the text like, oh, now I can use French in this conversation. That's good. That's not French. That's a different language.
Starting point is 00:38:35 I'll explain it to you one day. That's you as Charlie's would never understand. Okay. If I can return to it, we'll jump around if it's okay. That's fine. So you mentioned Karl Marx as one of the great intellects, economic thinkers. Ever. Yeah. He's, he might be number one, you study him quite a bit, you disagree with him quite a bit. Yeah. But you still think it's a powerful, a powerful mind. So first of all, let's just explore the human. Why do you say so? What's interesting in that mind? In the way he saw the world, what are
Starting point is 00:39:16 the insights that you find brilliant? The Marx once described his major workers towards a critical examination of everything existing. So he's a modest bastard. So he wanted to understand and criticize everything. And even he wasn't trained directly by Hagel, but his teachers were Hageali and philosophers. And what Hagel developed was a concept called dialectics. And dialectics is a philosophy of change. And when most people hear the word dialectics, they come up with this unpronounceable
Starting point is 00:39:56 trio of words called thesis, antithesis, synthesis. I can barely get the words out myself. And that actually is not Hagell at all. That's another German philosopher. I can't. I've got to think. I thought it was the words out myself. Yeah. And that actually is not haggle at all. That's another German philosopher. Come on, Fick. Oh, Fick. I thought it was Kant. No, Fick.
Starting point is 00:40:09 Well, I'm not sure. I mix them up, while Germans are saying to me. Yeah, yeah, yeah, yeah. So, but if you look, there's a beautiful book called Marx and Contradiction. You want to find it a great explanation for Marxist philosophy. I've forgotten the author.
Starting point is 00:40:22 I think it's Wild, W-I-L-D-A, Marx and Contradiction. And he points out the actual origins of Marx's philosophy. I've forgotten the author. I think it's Wild, WILDA, Marx in contradiction, and he points out the actual origins of Marxist philosophy. I didn't know that when I first read Marx. I became exposed to Marx when I was a student at Sydney University, and we'd had a strike at the University over the teaching of philosophy. And what happened was the philosophy department had a lot of radical philosophers in it and a conservative chief philosopher. And the radicals wanted to have, of course, what they called feminist aspects of philosophical, philosophical aspects of feminist thought. And the staff voted in favor of it. This is back in the days when university departments were democratic. The professor opposed it. He got it blocked it to high level. The staff leapt, frogged over that and then finally the vash
Starting point is 00:41:08 chancellor blocked it. So that led to a strike over the teaching of philosophy at Sydney University, which at one stage over, pretty over half the students were on strike. Economics had began out of that. Over teaching of the philosophy of feminism. Yes, that's good. That's such a different life to what we're living now. That's the academic milieu in which I developed all my ideas. And I had become a critic. I've gone from being a believer of mainstream economics when I was a first-year student to disbelieving
Starting point is 00:41:40 at halfway through first year. And I then spent a long time trying to change it, getting nowhere. And then this philosophy strike happened and we took it on in economics and we formed what's called the political, political economy movement. And had a successful strike,
Starting point is 00:41:55 we actually managed to pressure the university into establishing a department of political economy at Sydney University as well as a department of economics. What was the foundational ideas? Were you resistant to the whole censorship of why can't you have a philosophy of anything kind of course? Well, it was much more libertarian in the genuine sense of the word period of time at the end of the 60s, beginning of the 70s than the word libertarian has been corrupted since then. But it really was about free thought.
Starting point is 00:42:27 And you went to university to learn, it was about education. I remember having a fight with my father once, where dad was angry about the marks I was getting for some of my courses. And he said, if you don't get a decent result, you won't get a decent job. And I said, I'm not here to get a job,
Starting point is 00:42:41 I'm here to get an education. Oh wow. I can now, the thing is, ultimately, it's been a pretty good job for me as well. This is in Sydney, by the way, and Sydney in summer is absolutely gorgeous. And what are our Spongebob lefties to decide to do during summer, but read Karl Marx? Yeah. On the beach or?
Starting point is 00:42:57 Actually, inside the room of the philosophy department at the University of Sydney in the main quadrangle. And it is sandstone all around us, and we've bunch of about 20 or 30 just reading our way through marks. Capital, which is one of, volume one capital. And I remember walking off to that meeting with one of my friends who's the law student. And this was a period of a huge construction boom in Sydney. So the whole skyline which we could see from the campus was full of what they call kangaroo cranes which
Starting point is 00:43:30 were an Australian invention that are cranes that can be leapfrogged over each other to build a skyscraper. So here you are reading Karl Marx looking at the mechanisms of capital and I looked at those mechanisms and I knew Marx argued that labor was the only source of value. Yeah. And he said, Machinery doesn't add value. So the creams are worthless. I'm looking at these creams and thinking, I want a very good explanation by Marx, as to why these creams don't add value. So reading through the first seven chapters of capital, what you found was Marx applying this dialectic. And like the fictitious stuff is bullshit, that is not how Marx thought it all.
Starting point is 00:44:05 I was reading, trying to find the thesis and the thesis and it's not there at all in any of Marx's works. I read everything is ever written on economics from 1844 to 1894 and his last books were published. There's not one word of the engine of that. what he does talk about is foreground and background, intention. And his idea of a dialectic is that there is a unity will exist in society. And that unity can be an individual, there can be a commodity, anything at all. The unity will be understood by that society. One particular aspect will be focused upon. So if you think about the human being in capitalism, the focus on the human being as an object,
Starting point is 00:44:48 is their capacity to work. You're a worker, okay? That puts in a foreground. The fact that you're human and you wanna play a guitar and go surfing and make love and all the other things that humans do is pushed into the background. There's a tension between the two of those, and that can transform that unity over time.
Starting point is 00:45:08 That's a beautiful dynamic vision of change. Dialectics is a philosophy of change. Synthesis and synthesis is what does every idea have a counter argument? There's a positive and negative, and you bring them together somehow. Then Marx has this foreground background intention. foreground is all what we think of as economics and backgrounds, all the love making we do as humans. That sort of thing.
Starting point is 00:45:34 And why is there attention? Well, because you've been mentioned, if you mention the unity, like if you take a human in a preve, because you go back to Chrome Agnan days and when we're living in caves and we've got to go hunting and cook food and stuff like that, but there's no social hierarchy as we've become used to. So you don't get labored as a worker or a capitalist, you're just a human in that situation, then you've got more an integrated view of who you are. And I think that's one of the appeals of a genuine tribal culture that you get treated for the whole of who you are. And I think that's one of the appeals of a genuine tribal culture that you get treated for the whole of who you are. You've certainly categorized your
Starting point is 00:46:09 male, your female, your young, your old, your a hunter, your a tool maker, etc., etc., but you're treated as more integrated objects. When you get put in a complex society like a capitalist society, then one side if you emphasize, then the others are de-emphasized. So is it fair to say that the background is like our basic fundamental humanity and the foreground is the machine of capitalism? Effectively, and when you look at it in terms of a human, but what marks it is applied this to a commodity? So you said, what is the essential unity in a capitalist economy?
Starting point is 00:46:41 And the essential unity is a commodity. That's the essential unit. The essential unity was the unity. Unity is an object in society. Okay, so he started from the point if you were trying to understand what a how exchange occurs. How do we set prices? And he's starting vision was to say that a commodity is a unity in a capitalist economy. The part of the unity that we focus upon is the exchange value. A capitalist produces a commodity, not because of its qualitative characteristics, but because it be sold for a profit.
Starting point is 00:47:18 So the foreground aspect of a commodity is its exchange value. The background aspect of it, it won't succeed as a commodity unless it has a use value. So the background is the utility thing? Yeah, see, if you made something which didn't work, then it might be able to sell it, but it has no utility. That can't make that into a commodity. A broken thing can't be sold. So that has the subjective side. So people enjoy it? commodity, a broken thing can't be solved. So have the subjective side. Yeah, it has to have the subjective side.
Starting point is 00:47:45 So people enjoy the objective. So the objective is what capitalists worry about. I'll give you my favorite counter example of that. I took a bunch of Australian journalists to chime away back on the period when the gang of four was being on trial. And we did a tour of the Fibidin city in Beijing. And at that stage, all the artifacts of the royal family,
Starting point is 00:48:07 the Emperor, were actually in the building still. We walked past one of them and it was this gold, solid gold bar about this long, shaped like a fist, turned over like this and on this side there were Ruby's Emeralds diamonds. You'd never seen gemstones. I mean, gems that big. And one of the journalists asked me what I thought it was, and I said, oh, it's obvious. Jane is the back scratcher. Ha, ha, ha. I walked away.
Starting point is 00:48:31 She caught up with me about 20 minutes later. I asked one of the guards, it is a back scratcher. Well, so here's a back scratcher for the emperor, made of solid gold, with diamonds and rubies and Emeralds during the scratching. Now, that's a commodity in a feudal society. The cost doesn't matter. You want the most elaborate, beautiful thing
Starting point is 00:48:50 because you are the emperor. So in that in a feudal society, the commodity, what's focused upon is the utility. And the cost of production, when you're the emperor, is immaterial. Capitalism reverses that. So the commodity in a capitalist economy is a plastic $2 scratchy you can get from Kmart or Target. And so the use value is necessary, but irrelevant
Starting point is 00:49:16 to forming the price. Now that was a completely different vision of exchange in capitalism, to what I found in the neoclassical theory, because that says it's the marginal utility and the marginal cost of everything that determines the exchange ratio. And the crazy thing about that is not so much the marginal utility, but the argument in the neoclassical theory is that the price ratio, the price will, when there's an exchange going on, there's two-person, two person, two commodity exchange of two commodities between two people. The price will change until such time as the ratio of the marginal utilities is equal to the ratio of the marginal costs. That's supposed to be the
Starting point is 00:50:00 equilibrium. And Marx says, that's bullshit. That's a previous society where you exchange stuff that you happen to have, the stuff somebody else happened to have, without any real production mechanism being involved. And he said, that's like when you have an eight-to-engine tribe, or two tribes meeting for the very first time, and one tribe can make something the other tribe can't make. And they will therefore, the price they were willing to pay, reflect how unique this other object is that this one tribe can make and the other can't. So for example, the story of Manhattan being sold for 40 glass beads, it's actually 40 glass trading beads. I believe it is a true story, but the thing is, the Indians couldn't make glass beads.
Starting point is 00:50:42 So they valued the glass beads and the island of Manhattan, which is a utility-based comparison. What Mark said, that's the very initial contact. Over time, even if you don't know the technology, over time you start to realize how much work goes involved in making what they're selling you versus what you're selling to them. And you start making stuff specifically for sale.
Starting point is 00:51:10 So, you know, Elon's not losing personal utility each time a Model 3 goes out the door. There's no, he might get utility out of the fact that he's created that vehicle, that concept and manufacturers it and so on, but he's not losing utility each time a Model T 4 goes out the door for going back for the ancient commodity there. So, the utility plays no role in setting price in Marxist model. Whereas it's essential in the neo-classical model. What's the difference between utility and marginal utility? What does the word marginal mean? And why is this such a problem?
Starting point is 00:51:41 It turns marginal utility, or utility itself has different meanings than the two schools of thought. If you take the classical school of thought, which when Marx comes from, utility is effectively objective. So the utility of a chair is that you consider it. Okay, not how comfortable it makes you feel. Yeah.
Starting point is 00:52:00 Now, if you think about the utility of the chairs, we're both sitting and they're identical from a classical point of view, we're both sitting. But from a neoclassical point of view, it's how comfortable it makes you feel. And that depends upon your subjective feelings of comfort. You might be far more comfortable in the identical chair that I'm sitting in than I am.
Starting point is 00:52:17 And therefore, the comparison is difficult. And therefore, working out a ratio involves you've got to decline in your each time you give away a chair in exchange for a iPhone, you have a fall in your utility. But and then therefore you want a higher return because you're losing more utility each time. The more chairs you give away the less utility you're getting from chairs, there's a decline in your utility. That's your marginal utility. So it's including your subjective valuation in setting the price.
Starting point is 00:52:50 And what Mark's pointed out is this is a caricature of actual change in a capitalist economy. Because we have an in a capitalist economy, huge factories, turning out huge quantities, specifically for sale. They've got no utility to the seller unless they're sold. So it's a very different vision of how prices set and Marx used that to explain where profit comes from, but he made a mistake.
Starting point is 00:53:18 And his argument was that talking about a worker as an all-year unity, this is a foreground background tension thing. The foreground is that you hire a worker for their cost of production. And the cost of production is a subsistence wage. Okay. The utility to the buyer is the fact that they can work in a factory. Now it might take six hours,
Starting point is 00:53:44 let's say, to make the means of subsistence. And that's the exchange value and that's what the capitalist pays as a factory. Now it might take six hours, let's say, to make the means of subsistence. And that's the exchange value, and that's what the capitalist pays as a wage to the worker. But they can work in the factory for 12 hours. That's the utility. 12 minus 6 is 6 surplus of value hours, and that's where profit comes from. And that was Marx's argument. And I thought it was brilliant, but it also applied to machinery. Right. Let's just get on that.
Starting point is 00:54:10 No, no, deep is good. Just wanted to find terms. Don't take that statement out of context. The internet, please. OK. You said buyer, seller, worker, in a factory, who's the seller, who's the buyer, why is the worker the buyer?
Starting point is 00:54:31 The worker is the commodity in this case. Because if you're going to make stuff in a factory, you've got a higher workers. Yes. And what Mark's saying, the buyer and that situation is a capitalist. So what does a buyer pay? He says he pays the exchange value. That's, if we get we have back to the commodity thing that, that's the starting point. You said the essential unity in a capitalist economy is the commodity. A commodity has two characteristics, exchange value and use value.
Starting point is 00:54:56 Okay. Exchange value of a commodity in a capitalist economy will be its cost of production. The use value is what you do with it. Okay, once you purchased it. But labor is a commodity. In this case, when a worker is being hired for a job, yes. So the worker's labor has an exchange value and a use value as well. Yeah. Use value. Use value of a worker's labor. exchange value. Let me think about that. So the hours they put in is the use value. Interesting. So what, what is the worker want in this? What are the motivations? Are we not considering the worker in this context as a human being? Well, you come and that's actually, that's the next layer.
Starting point is 00:55:49 What marks it was just like a layered cake starting from a foundation of saying straight commodity exchange and then saying, well, you're treating the workers of commodity. Now, commodity is something like this. Okay, that has so far as I'm aware, no soul. Okay. Yeah. Not going to be complaining if I turn it upside down, it'll fall over, but it, yeah. So that's, there's no soul there. Whereas a human is both a commodity and a non-commodity. Yeah. And therefore, there'll be attention in the person. I'm being treated as a commodity here. I'm being paid just enough to stay alive. You know, I've got a wife and kids back at
Starting point is 00:56:22 home. Yeah. So that So that is another layer of thinking in Marx. And on that lay he then says, well, workers will therefore demand more than their value. So that's when you get like political, you get political and you get money coming above that and so on. But the basic idea starts from the commodities, the fundamental unity and capitalism. The important commodity in Marx is thinking was the worker because that's where he said profit came from. And then that explains the motivation of the capitalist. And that ultimately is the labor theory of value. And Marx is arguments about how capitalism will come to an end.
Starting point is 00:56:58 Okay. Okay. So first of all, what is the labor theory of value? And actually before that, what is value? Is that, this is like me asking, what's happiness? Is there something interesting to say about trying to define value? Very, and this is a huge problem in economics, is arguments of what does value mean? And the neoclassicals came down as that it's subjective,, its value is whatever you get
Starting point is 00:57:26 out of it, but it's your personal evaluation of something, your personal feelings. So they've got that very subjective idea of value. Whereas the Marxists being inherited to the classical school, talking to us as an objective value. So the value is the number of hours it takes to make something. Or the effort, the value is the effort that goes into making something in the classical school. Well, that's just one measure of objective. Where do you fall? Where do you fall? I fall on subjective versus subjective versus objective spectrum. I think you have to have the capacity to move between one and the other in a structured
Starting point is 00:58:05 model of value. Yeah, my base model is the objective. But above that, as soon as you start talking, you did about the worker, for example, then you get involved in the subjectivity, because a worker will be angry and justify up with so about being treated as a commodity. Because I'm not a commodity, I'm a human being. And that's where Marx or political organisation coming from. So, and that's subjective now. And then when you get to money itself, Marx actually said, well, what's the value of money? Now, if you use an objective theory of value, you were so old that the cost of money, the value of money, is its cost of production. What's the cost of producing a dollar?
Starting point is 00:58:48 It's about two cents. So he said, it can't be the value of a money, cannot be its cost of production. Or the most value, I think if we remember the phrase properly, or is value here as it must mean the effectively uncertain expectations or subjective valuation. Uncertain expectation or subjective evaluation. Okay, but he's okay with that. He was okay with that because he could move between different levels because he's had a structured foundation of this dialectical vision of foreground background tension. Commodity having used value value, and a gap between
Starting point is 00:59:26 the two when you're talking about machines, when you're buying stuff for production. And then the next level, you could look at workers, worker organization and say that's driven by being treated as a commodity when you're a non-commodity. So the basic labor theory of value that is described to Karl Marx is that value at the base layer fundamentally comes from the labor you put into something. Yeah, and You say well, there's some deep truth there except he misses one fundamental point, which is machines can also bring value to the world. He was saying they don't.
Starting point is 01:00:09 The only thing that matters is human labor, not labor. How do you measure what's the role of the whatever value machines bring to the world? This is another intriguing history because Mark'smany first started what you can call an exclusive explanation for why Labour created value. That was said that the Labour is the only commodity with both what he called commodity and commodity power. So you have Labour and labor power. Labor is the, and I get fuzzy about this, so I haven't read it for something like 30 years, but labor has both commodity and commodity power. The commodity is, you can buy labor,
Starting point is 01:00:55 which is the means of subsistence. Labor power is the capacity to work inside a factory. There's a difference between the two. Therefore, that difference will give rise to surplus, and there's no other commodity that has this essence of commodity and commodity power. So that was his exclusive for Stargum and in the middle of the 1857, he was visited by a guy called Otto Brow in his home in Chelsea. And Otto returned to Marx, a copy of Hegel's phenomenal, I think it's called Phenomenology
Starting point is 01:01:26 of Right, I haven't read it, but that's the book. And Marx was then at this stage reading through all the classical theorists again. And he was suddenly he read Hegel again. And if you know, Hunter-S Thompson, okay. You could, doesn't know, Hunter-S Thompson. Somebody who hasn't had enough drugs, obviously. Yeah, but Hunter-S Thompson, he comes to you in a dream after you take your first deposit or whatever. And you can, you know, your drugs will, and if you can tell,
Starting point is 01:01:51 okay, you've stoned, okay, he's on cocaine, you know, well, Mark suddenly, his writing style in the middle of a book called the Gondrissa completely changed. He switched from weed to cocaine. He switched from Ricardo to Hagle. Okay. And what, in Ricardo, he had this exclusive astagumid about labor, and suddenly Hagel is back talking in terms of dialectics, not actually using a word, but foreground and background and tension. And then he, that's where this used value, exchange value, attention thing came from, is rereading Hagel. 13 years after he stopped reading philosophy, because made made in 44 he was reading just the
Starting point is 01:02:27 economists. So you're saying Karl Marx is human after all. He's human. He could be in joy. I would love to have a beer with Karl. What a one. For Karl? He's Karl too. He's Mr. Marx to me. Maybe Karl to me I'm afraid after all this. Yeah, you've had quite a journey together. So that's where after his interpretation of the dialogues, it comes in the form of background, foreground and background. And then on page 267 of the Penguin edition of the Granger S.
Starting point is 01:02:55 So what really your memory, one and a half pages long footnote, it's pretty hard to forget because what I, when I did this, when I first read Marx way, way back when I was, how old was I, 20? Okay. I tried to explain my explanation of Marx's use value exchange value stuff to my colleagues in this philosophy discussion room at Sydney University during a beautiful summer that we are inside concrete, San Stone walls discussing Marx. And I went to say, let the use value exchange value argument can be applied to a machine, look, the use value exchange value argument can be applied to a machine. What's the exchange value of a machine?
Starting point is 01:03:29 It's cost of manufacturing it. What's its use value? It's capacity to produce goods for sale. No relation between the two, there'll be a gap. A machine can be a source of profit. Now, I said that, and I got laughed at. I'm quite literally laughed at. So when I went back to university 13 years later
Starting point is 01:03:45 to do a master's degree, I chose to read through and find in Marx where he first came across this insight. So I made, I'm a first master's thesis failed by the way and justifiably so, okay. I was learning, I didn't know the level of academic discourse necessary. I had an advisor who didn't understand the level of academic discourse necessary. I had an advisor who didn't understand what I was writing.
Starting point is 01:04:08 He got me to write for his new Keynesian audience and it was a mess and it got failed. So I got rid of him. Did it get failed because, like, why do you think? It wasn't a good thesis. I didn't know the level. He was written for an audience, my supervisor thought that I should be writing for.
Starting point is 01:04:26 And it was a mess. And so I met another guy, Jeff Fischburn, as a lecturer at New South Wales University, and Jeff was open-minded. He was not a conventional neoclassical thinker. And I realised I'd throw out the half that Bill had got me to do, focused just on Marx. And so I decided to read Marx in chronological sequence from his very first works of economics, which are called the Economic and Philosophical Manuscripts of 1844. And he wrote those in a garret in Paris after he'd been expelled from Prussia. And so he decided to read the having been an expert on philosophy and read Goddard as the towering intellects of Higali and philosophy and in Prussia, but driven out because he was a radical.
Starting point is 01:05:11 He ended up writing a, running a newspaper or being writing for a newspaper, and he was reporting about the eviction of peasants from the forests, taking away their futile rights. And so this is where his passion for economics and humanity came from. And he was a poet as well. I mean, he wrote Love Power to the Journey von West, West Haaland. That's his first published works for pretty much in poetry. He was a rouse about. He was, you know, a wild character. We'd probably fight, fight like crazy, I imagine, if we met. I was over the beers. I'm slightly, even though I can be, I can get involved in an argument like nobody's business. No, really? No, really. But I'm a bit more peaceful with personality.
Starting point is 01:05:56 Are you think Marx is face-tier than you? He was Foshtee, but Foshtee was, he could be arrogant. I'm like, I've got an intellectual arrogance, so come to accept that. But there's like a fundamental humility to you. You're saying Marx is like, as ego that's hard to control. It's a big ego, yeah. I'm guessing I'm never gonna meet him.
Starting point is 01:06:16 Well the beard says ego, the beard is here, yeah. That's that's it. That's it. Okay, so this is interesting. You went chronologically into his work. The development of the human being through his works. Yeah, and I was trying to find the point at which he discovered this use value exchange value idea.
Starting point is 01:06:32 And it occurs in a footnote on page 267 to 268 of the Penguin edition of the Grondresse, which his notes he was taking, literally, not meant for publication, literally sitting at a stall inside the British Museum, I think, reading all the classical authors in chronological sequence, and then somebody throws Hagel-Aidham, and suddenly he's talking in a galley in terms. And he suddenly says, is not, because it's whole value issues, what is value? Is it exchange value, use value? How do they relate to each other? That's what he was thinking about. He said, is not use value, which was left out of the classical school, a fundamental aspect of the commodity? Is there not a tension between the use value and exchange value?
Starting point is 01:07:15 Just so we're clear in that context, use value is kind of the subjective thing, exchange values, the objective thing. And Marx was found a way to integrate the two where he was focused on labor being the only thing that can generate both the use value and the exchange value. But now, if you look at the classical school, they focused on exchange value objective. Look at the neo classical. They faces upon use value subjective, or they call it utility. So Mark's coming from the Ricardian tradition basically dismissed the role of utility. And then when he reads Heygall, he's suddenly starting to think in terms of unities and exchange
Starting point is 01:07:56 value and use value is the unity of the commodity. And he thinks, well, I can't ignore use value. So rather than leaving it out completely, which is what Ricardo and Smith does, I've got to somehow bring it in and this galley and insight occurs to him. And it's remarkable. I really recommend taking a look at the book, even just to look at that particular page, because what it would have been as shown as a footnote, but it would have been saying, oh wow, an asteristh, asterisk, is not, you know, use value, a fundamental aspect of the unity of a commodity.
Starting point is 01:08:29 So in the notes, you see the discovery of an idea in the human life. And it's beautiful. The integration of an idea. And he actually writes, does this have significance in economics question mark? And then he probably went home that night and like that, that idea changed. Yeah, it changed him completely. And from that point on, his writing was completely different, but he still had this idea from the Ricardian days of saying that labor is the only source of value
Starting point is 01:08:52 using an exclusive argument to say there's something unique about labor that explains why it's a source of value. But suddenly this insight occurs to him and he thinks, I can get a positive derivation. I can use the use value and exchange value, and the fact they're not related to each other as a dialectical tension to explain surplus value. And that's what he does. So he goes from a negative explanation
Starting point is 01:09:13 of where value comes from to a positive explanation on that page of the Gondrasa. And he then triumphantly uses it to explain why labor is a source of value. You buy it for its exchange value, you use its use value, the unrelated, the use value will be bigger, that's where profit comes from. Then he does exactly the same thing for machinery, about 30 pages on. He says it also has to be contemplated, which was not done before. This is right
Starting point is 01:09:42 nice to himself, by the way, it's written in really in a colloquial style, that the use value of a machine significantly greater than its exchange value. He actually left out the word is, it's used, it's obviously to be a translation into English of the German, I'm sure, I don't know, I haven't seen the original notes, I'd love to see them. But he says, he leaves out the word is, he also has to be contemplated that the used value significantly greater than its exchange value. IE, that the contribution of the machine to production exceeds its depreciation. And that was an insight which undermined his explanation for revolution. Okay, can you say that again?
Starting point is 01:10:26 The cost of production exceeds his depreciation? Yeah. Okay, can you linger on that? Well, what marks are argued, and you read this in capital, and I read this in capital when I first saw the contradiction in his own thought. He said that no matter how useful the machine is, whether it has took a hundred hours to make or cost 150 pounds, it cannot, under any circumstances,
Starting point is 01:10:52 add more to production than 150 pounds. Which, in his old exclusivist logic, he could justify, and which in his modern, his post 1857 argument is bullshit. Can you steal man his case? Can we go to the mine and Marx and thinking if a machine costs 100 bucks, he can't be ever more, bring more value than 100 bucks. But that contradicts his previous logic. Because what he said is, you'd have a commodities, the essential unity in capitalism. Capitalism focuses upon the exchange value. That pushes the use value into the background, and there's attention between the two. What that means is the exchange value of a commodity sets its price. The use value is independent. He called them
Starting point is 01:11:42 incommensurable. He literally used the word incommensurability between exchange value and a use value, whereas neoclassicals make them commensurable. So saying exchange value and use value in incommensurable. And that normally means that exchange value is objective. Like the number of hours it takes to make something. Use value is subjective.
Starting point is 01:12:01 How comfortable the chair is, the fact you consider in a chair. So that's in commensurability. But when you apply it in production, the exchange value of something is objective. It's how many hours it takes to make a machine or how many hours it takes to make the means of subsistence for a worker. The use value is also objective. You're making commodities for sale. And the worker does six hours, six hours of work, or the means of subsistence for the worker, but the worker will work a 12 hour day, and the six hours becomes a gap. Now, that's in commensurability between use, value, and exchange value of labour.
Starting point is 01:12:40 But when you look at what he said about, no matter how long it takes to make a machine or how many pounds at costs, he's saying they're identical. And that's contradicting his own logic. What's the youth value of a machine? The fact that it can produce goods for sale. Exactly the same as the worker. Now, what I've, in my modern reinterpretation of Marx, which brings in my work on energy,
Starting point is 01:13:04 I see both labour and machinery as a means to harness energy and produce useful work. And they can both do that. In fact, they do it together. It's a collective enterprise. Okay. So, and we'll go to that. So there's no there's no fundamental difference from exchange value and use value, respectively value respectively was human in a machine. And therefore they're using the same logic that can both be a source of surplus. Yeah, which is what marks contradicted because his explanation for where socialism would come from is that only profit comes from late profit comes only from labor.
Starting point is 01:13:39 Over time, it'll add more machinery than labor. That will mean a falling rate of profit and therefore a tendency towards socialism. And what he did in that insight in 1857 is contradict his own idea about what it would lead to socialism. And he couldn't cope with it. Okay, what's the difference between Marxian economics and Marxist political ideology, the gap between the two, the overlap, the differences. The real foundation of Marxist political philosophy was the economic argument that there would be a tendency for the rate of profit to fall. And that tendency for the rate of profit to fall would lead to capitalists batting down on workers harder, paying them less than the subsistence. I'll revolt by workers against this and then you would get socialism
Starting point is 01:14:32 on the other side. So what he called the tendency for the rate of profit to fall played a critical role in his explanation for why socialism would have to come about. He was saying it would have to come about or is that a good thing for it to come about? He had a short, but he was trying to say it must. So if you look at Marx in the history of radical thought, he was preceded by what were called utopian socialists, St. Simone, even the Cadbury's company, came out of utopian socialists, and they had an idea about a perfect society in the future where people were properly rewarded, which treated as human beings rather than cogs in a machine, and all this sort of stuff. And they said socialism should come about because it treats humans better than capitalism does. Mark said, I can prove that socialism must come about. So he preferred, he had a utopian vision of a future society, but he thought he could
Starting point is 01:15:28 prove that it had to come about, and the proof relied critically upon tendency for the rate of profit to fall, and that relied upon labour being the only source of profit. What was his utopian view? So this idea from each according to his ability to eat your according to his needs. Yeah. Is that the utopian? I think it's utopian in the context of our modern world.
Starting point is 01:15:55 It says that you rather than being rewarded, like Jeff Bezos gets an enormous fortune, you get what you need, not what you want, necessarily. All needs is fulfilled. It was a vision of Utopia where you could be a fisherman in the morning, a poet in the afternoon, and a chef at night, okay? This paraphrasing one of his phrases. So he did have a Utopian vision of a future society, and he did think human creativity would be much, much greater under socialism than it was under capitalism. He was wrong.
Starting point is 01:16:29 So let's explore in different ways where he was wrong. You're saying there's a fundamental flaw in the logic, but also if we can, if we can explore a high level philosophical concepts of socialism too, like the dreams of Eutopia. So, first of all, what is socialism? That's another loaded term. It is a particular, particularly in America, is a very loaded term. I'm what Americans call socialist is a large amount of provision of services by the state, which is commonplace in Europe. It's still moderately commonplace in my own home country of Australia. And that Americans will call public education socialist.
Starting point is 01:17:13 It's a total parody of the word. Strictly speaking, what Socialism meant is the public ownership of the means of production, no private ownership of the means of production. What is the means of production? What is the means of production? What is the means of factories? Exactly. So, are the goods that are produced in factories? No, the means of producing the goods are owned by a centralized entity.
Starting point is 01:17:37 Yeah. Centrally planned, this is what actually was done under GOSPlan under the Soviets. And even with a collective farm as well, you no longer own your land, the state owns your, the land you worked on the land, and this was supposed to be utopia. Right, so that's-
Starting point is 01:17:53 So that's- And we'll talk about maybe your ideas are why it didn't turn out to be one. So the fascists did the same. So the fascism also, so- So- So- So- So- So-Socialism. It's also a kind of socialism. So it was just fascism also, so called national socialism. It's also a kind of social.
Starting point is 01:18:08 So yeah, but there was no, there wasn't public only, there was public direction. So the state would tell factories what to do with a still private profit. And a large part of why the Nazis succeeded was the extent to which they managed to co-opt, major manufacturers in Germany. So it's, you know, it's a direction versus ownership. It's a dictatorial, I mean, that's a very particular implementation. So you have to consider the full details of the implementation, but it's basically dictator-guided. Yeah. If you want to take a proper vision, then you have to say it's the ownership of the means of production by the state. Okay, versus the ownership by private. That rules out the Nazi period. They use the word that they're getting their bastardizing as much as Americans do
Starting point is 01:18:55 in the opposite direction. Well, what does ownership exactly mean? Well, it's, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, it, Well, it's... It became incredibly complicated. And this is actually the best work on this is done by recently, the C.S. Hungarian economist called Janos Kornai. And Kornai tried to explain why socialism failed. Because why did socialism fail in your view? In his view, in Janos' view, in your view? I think Janos is 100% correct and it's what brilliant piece of work. So I'm going to be really paraphrasing your view. In his view, in Yarnos' view, in your view. I think Yarnos' 100% correct, and it's a brilliant piece of work, so I'm going to be really
Starting point is 01:19:27 paraphrasing his view. And he imagined a ideal socialist society, and there wasn't a Stalin, there weren't Persians, and you lived after all the ideals that Marx had for socialism. So he said, but you do it in a context of an economy which is impregnally primitive, Russia. Because if you look at Marx's own vision of the revolution, it was going to happen in England. The advanced economies would be first to go through the revolution. The socialist, the primitive economies would have to go through a capitalist transition. And this is the difference when the Mensheviks and the Bolsheviks. So the Mensheviks, when the Haiman Minskie came out of the Menschiviks family. The Menschiviks
Starting point is 01:20:06 believed you had to go through a capitalist phase. Russia had to go through a capitalist period before it become socialist. The Bolsheviks believed they could get there in one go. Bypass the capitalist phase, do the development under socialism rather than under capitalism. And this is what Janos was actually analyzing. She started from a primitive, feudal economy, very little industrialization, and you wanna jump to an advanced industrial society from that foundation. So he said what you have then for is a whole range
Starting point is 01:20:43 of industries, all of which need as much resources as you can get for them. Okay, so you want to develop agriculture, mining industry, every little division of it, they all have legitimate demands on the resources of the country and the state. That means that all your resources are fully employed and are probably over employed. So you have a resource constraint in that society. The easiest way to cope with a resource constraint is to produce last-use commodity, not to innovate, not to make change. So what they will give you is, as you start to add, you know, you invest so you now have a beginnings of a steel industry, beginnings of a car industry and so on. You start investing, but you continue producing
Starting point is 01:21:27 the same product you made last year. And I have a perfect personal example of that, which I'll throw in now if you like, with any good heavy conversation. One of my first major girlfriend had a brother who wanted to get a motorbike, but he couldn't afford a Honda or a Kawasaki. At the time, they cost about $3,000 for a 650cc Japanese motorbike. He found he could buy a KOSAC
Starting point is 01:21:54 for $650, $1 per CC. So I was there when they got this. This is in This is in suburban Silvania waters in Sydney. So this crater rives with the Kossak motorbike inside it. So we take it apart and then got all these wooden palings. We have to pull off the welding palings to open it up. Then there's oil-sake rag over this thing which is tied on a wooden base. We take the oil-sake rag off and we stare in all its glory and are not in 42 BMW. It was exactly the same as Steve McQueen and Radiscope. So the Russians for 30 years were making the same bloody motorbike. It had a bicycle seat. And this is how they coped. They just made the same damage in every year. They said,
Starting point is 01:22:42 so that's the outcome. You actually want the best possible world. You're trying to build as fast as possible. You're paying workers as high wages as you possibly can. And that leads to a world where you don't innovate. You said capitalism on the other hand, pure capitalist economy. You're trying to pay workers as little as possible. You have competitive industries. You're trying to take demand away from your rivals. You have Kawasaki versus Honda versus BMW, etc., etc.
Starting point is 01:23:12 The way you get demand away from your competitors is by innovating. So what you will get is cycles and burns and slumps, but you will innovate and change over time. So what you found was this huge gap between socialist volume production with no innovation and capitalism with innovation. So that was the fundamental failing that John Os' Corn I saw. So what did socialists not innovate? Because if you go back to, if it's famous historical incident,
Starting point is 01:23:41 we're Christian in the United Nations, bang, sex off his shoe and bang as the United Nations, bangs takes up his shoe and bangs the desk as, we will bury you. He literally meant we're going to bury you in commodities. We're going to produce more output than you are. And he was wrong. Because fundamentally in a long term to bury somebody in commodity production, you have to innovate.
Starting point is 01:24:02 Yeah. And like there's also, there's another remarkable Soviet engineer who has given the job of interpreting Marx's ideas of industrial sectors. So he had the commodity sphere, the industry sphere, sector one, sector two, sector three, sector one producing consumer goods, sector two producing capital goods, sector three producing luxury goods for capitalists. And so he had a three-sector model of the economy, and he was talking about the dynamics between them.
Starting point is 01:24:29 And what Feldman did was reinterpret this as an engineer would reinterpret it, which was brilliant work. So what he said was, you need to produce the means of production. If you want to grow quickly, you focus on producing the means of production rather than commodities. So you don't make cars, you make car factories.
Starting point is 01:24:48 Okay, you make a few cars, but most of the effort goes into expanding how many factories you have. And what he did was do a mathematical model where you start off with very low levels of consumer good output, but then you would just go exponential. Okay, now I took a look at that back when I was doing my master's degree and the training and mathematics I took Feldman's equations and then looked at what was actually driving it was. He was imagining correctly a huge pool of unemployed labour. If you go back to the earliest stages of Soviet industrialisation back in 1917, post the Second World, post the First World War, you had all these unemployed
Starting point is 01:25:25 workers, you had all these peasants you could take off the land and put into factories. So you had a huge supply of workers. What you had to do was build the factories. See, building the factories, but at a certain point you exhaust the supply of lowly employed or unemployed labor. And so, rather than having this exponential take off, you hit a ceiling. And then you can only grow as fast as the population because you're not innovating. Okay. So that's what actually hit the Soviet system. And it's why they never buried the Western consumer goods. And instead why Western consumers looked in envy that the goods being purchased by their Western people.
Starting point is 01:26:05 They said, if that's exploitation, we want exploitation. So okay, this is a lot of interesting stuff to ask here, which is, so Marx's vision for the socialists, utopia is you have to go through capitalism. And then should be expatr true to Marx's original idea? Right. So, is there a case to be made that in the long arc of human history on human civilization on Earth that we're going to live out Marx's vision for utopia, which is like, will we run into a wall with capitalism? I think we are running into a wall with capitalism.
Starting point is 01:26:44 In fact, I think we've already gone through the wall and we haven't yet realized we're smashed out of schools. Okay. Okay. But on the other side, we're bleeding and everything like that, is, does Marx have any insights on what the other side of capitalists are? I think that beautiful phrase of from each
Starting point is 01:27:03 according to his ability to each recording to his needs describes what we should end up with. And I think that's actually, if I think about, you know, I'm a Elon Musk fan, that's what I think is partially going to be the nature of society, if we build one that functions on Mars, because then I've actually seen the interview with his, the Italian who's involved in designing what the future colony will look like, he was actually asked this question, can there be enormous inequality in Martian civilization? The guy said absolutely not because the resources, we get in resource constraint applies.
Starting point is 01:27:41 You simply can't give somebody a underground bunker bunker 100 times the size of somebody else's 100 underground bunker. There's the scarcity of resources imposes a need for a quality overall. Is that always, that's interesting. I mean the scarcity of resources, wait, but I feel like that's the contradiction. I thought, what are you thinking of classical about scarcity? Yeah, I'm barely thinking at all. So wait, I thought scarcity, the best way to build on top of scarcity is a capitalist type of machine. Now, this is this is where again, our vision of what scarcity is wrong, because in Ricardo said
Starting point is 01:28:28 this bet is actually better than Marx, because Ricardo said there are some products whose value is determined entirely by their scarcity, paintings, rare wines, et cetera, et cetera. They are things you cannot reproduce in a factory. So, the essence of capitalism is what you can make in a factory. Therefore, for these unique objects, these rare objects, Picasso painting, a beautiful bottle of wine, etc. etc. Then the utility can't be reproduced easily. So it's price will be determined by subjective valuation. If you said what we're talking about in capitalism is the stuff you can make on mass. And that is the true focus of the capitalist economy. And that is not about scarcity. That is about the only scarcity applies when you don't have the resources to make them anymore. Or you can't use the energy involved because you'll damage the biosphere, which we've already done.
Starting point is 01:29:26 But fundamentally, the scarcity that neoclassicals have made us think about, and Austrians think about as well, is non-reproducible. But the essence of capitalism is the commodity, the back scratcher, the two-buck back scratcher, anybody can, you know, their cheapest chips to make, and that's why I can make a profit out of them. Not the elaborate goal thing with diamonds and rubies that only the king gets. So we think our vision of scarcity has been perverted by neoclassicals, analyzing the exception to capitalism and calling it capitalism. Okay, fair enough. So, let's put Mars aside because I think there's a lot of strange factors that have to do with the whole another planet
Starting point is 01:30:08 civilization That we don't quite understand like how economics works with With different geographical occasions one of which have new challenges Which is what essentially this is I don't I don't know if you can apply the same economic here. No, I'm not saying you're a question. I think we'll be forced into that, ultimately, by having to make a compromise with the ecology. And we've been ruthless about the ecology
Starting point is 01:30:36 of this planet, and we're going to pay the price for it. So if you have a planet where you can't be ruthless, okay? Well, yeah, okay. You have to mind it as carefully as possible. Then those that utopian might be imposed upon you for the needs of survival on that planet. Back here, Marx's utopia was still a one that ignored the ecology. And I think if I have a vision of a utopia in future, it's got bugger all to do about what humans get out of it.
Starting point is 01:31:09 It's what humans respect. They have to respect life. So I don't see that as a one-eyed utopia. Utopia for a single species, as if it can exist on a zone which we should know it can't. Quick bathroom break? Yeah, and about it know that would be great. We took a little bit of a break and now we're back. We needed to take a break as my brain broke
Starting point is 01:31:31 and I'm piecing it back together. You mentioned ecology and life and the value of all of that. We'll return to it if we can. But first, we said why this kind of This idea of why socialism fails. Can we linger on this a little bit longer? And how did the ideas of Karl Marx lead to Stalinism? So this particular implementation. Yeah Is there something fundamental to these ideas that leads to a dictator and that leads to atrocities?
Starting point is 01:32:12 There's something about the mechanism of the bureaucracy that's built that leads to a human being that's able to attain, integrate absolute power and then start abusing that power, all that kind of stuff. Like some of the history of the 20th century, is that inextricably connected to the ideas of Karl Marx? I think of some extended ideas, but I'm going to also say that if it hadn't been for the Bolsheviks interpreting Marx and saying we can reach socialism without going through capitalism, then it might not have happened. So if you look at the, like the Mensheviks were a rival political group in Russia, and
Starting point is 01:32:57 that's where Haiman Minsky, who's a huge inspiration for me. So he's an economist who was maybe, can we take a little danger who was Homin Minsky? Yeah, Homin Minsky was the person who developed analysis of capitalism based on financial instability and he was actually the PhD student of Joseph Schumpeter and an Austrian economist as well his name I've forgotten temporarily and he asked him he his parents were both refugees from Russia during the Stalinist period, because the Mensheviks were being wiped out in Russia, just like any other opponents to
Starting point is 01:33:39 the Bolsheviks were being eliminated. So I think he's parents met in Chicago, still remain socialist, still remain politically active, and he was educated in a family that was just imbued with Marx as his vision. He ended up fighting on the Second World War on the American side, coming back to America and studying mathematics, and then also doing an
Starting point is 01:34:07 economics degree leading to a PhD. And the question he posed for himself is what causes great depressions. And he put it beautifully, said, can it happen again? It being the Great Depression. And if it can't happen, then what has changed between the society before the first second World War and after that makes a depression impossible? Let's answer those two questions. His answer was yes it can happen again. There was prevented happening by the time he started writing about it, which was the late 50s to the mid 80s, late 80s. We met once, but only once. Over a beer? No, we gave a seminar at New South Uni and a bit of an obstreparous bastard. What? What? It means arguing, mentative and likely to dismiss you. So like a good mate of mine was
Starting point is 01:35:03 the guy who brought him out to Australia, go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go go Australian a question and he'll give you an answer which is the opposite of what he means and you've got to work out the rest for yourself. Yeah. This is he goes up to another Aboriginal maintenance says, good day mate, he said, how are you saying? Oh, not bad. What have you been doing recently? Oh, not much. When are we going? It's not not not not too far, not too soon. Whereas it's not too far away. Yeah. All negative. And he's a beautiful, beautiful, indition. Yeah. That's the cool thing about the internet culture. That's that's they appreciate that ironic side. Like for example, the best compliment you can give is an Aboriginal to somebody else's that's deadly. That's deadly. That's a compliment. That's deadly. Okay. Yeah. One another made of mine. This comes to you straight in language. By calling you a bastard, that's a compliment. Yeah. Depending on how I insinate the word bastard.
Starting point is 01:36:01 I call you a bosh to that's a compliment. Yeah, depending on how I internet the word bosh to bosh to bosh to that's deadly. Yeah, I love that. And there's something unfortunately, there's something about the British accent that makes people sound maybe brilliant, maybe sophisticated, but actually watch.
Starting point is 01:36:24 Yeah, no, that's unfortunately the downside of that as you can sound pompous. There's something about Australian accent that you just can't sound brilliant. It, it, it humbles you. It, you sound like you're having a lot of fun. There's wit. There's all that stuff. Yeah that stuff. But you just can't be like Karl Marx and Australian accent was just not come off. That is a very good point. You would not be able to pull off the beard. That's right.
Starting point is 01:36:52 I mean, I just, yeah, it's fascinating that the accent determines, you know, something about the person. Maybe it's the chicken and the egg too. It drives the way of the discourse. Obviously, there's a lot of brilliance. there's a lot of brilliance in your work, but it sounds like you're always having fun. Yeah, and look, this, the pot show's got a lot of Australian mates here.
Starting point is 01:37:13 Yeah. He spent, what about, how long you're going to stray? You're in a half, and he's got all these mates who replace Aussie Rills football in Austin. You should join them one day. A world, it's actually rough. It's a very creative sport, it's. A world. It's actually it's a very creative sport. It's much more fun. It's different than rugby. Oh very rugby is a bit hopeless rugby is two more on smashing their bodies against each
Starting point is 01:37:33 now. Easy now. Sorry. Sorry. We need to offend the rugby fans and the audience. Well, okay, what's a so simplistic? It's too simplistic. It's I mean, there's skill in it.
Starting point is 01:37:45 I've seen some really skillful rugby union and rugby league plays in my day. But it fundamentally, if you hit somebody hard enough, they go down. Yeah. Whereas in Aussie rules, it's about catching the ball and then kicking the ball and asking a lot more skill. And the bodies of the athletes,
Starting point is 01:38:04 I can actually get off me and measure what a sport is like by the bodies it creates. And you get these incredibly elegant, life muscular forms out of Aussie rules. It says beautiful words, you have in your vocabulary, like that, I don't know. But I'll assume you know what it means, and maybe somebody in the audience. Okay, so. All right, fine. We should also mention that you've in your youth, you know, like last year have had Olympic weight lifting as part of your life. So you're long time ago. And like you said, tennis, I also play tennis for many, many, many, many years. Okay. Yeah, it's a fascinating game. It's a wonderful game. Yeah.
Starting point is 01:38:46 That's my favorite game. Karl Marx and Stalin. Yeah. So, how do we get onto Aussie football and Australian and the accent? I'm not really sure. You talked about the way I said something about Karl Marx and would Karl Marx. Anyway, we got there. We got there, and now we've returned. He will go there, but now we return.
Starting point is 01:39:07 But back to Marx, I think that's not the destination. I think Marx, the failure of socialism with Janos Korni captured beautifully. This idea already called demand constrained versus resource constrained economies. And capitalism is demand constrained. And this is again where neoclassical theory is completely wrong, empirically, completely wrong. So the neoclassicals have a vision of capitalism being resource constrained. And it's about maximizing your usage of resources subject to constraints.
Starting point is 01:39:38 And as Corn I said, that's really what happened to socialism. What happens under capitalism is that you have 15, 20 companies producing automobiles. They are all trying to capture as much of the market as they can. If you add up their marketing plans, you're going to get 120, 130% of the actual market. So they're all going to have excess capacity. When you build a factory, you're building it with a plan for it to exist for 5, 10, 15 years. You have to have excess capacity in the factory. So that means that capitalism has far greater productive capacity than it actually uses.
Starting point is 01:40:11 And then the way that you manage to get to manage into your factory is to innovate and produce something nobody else does. Or you're producing in volume, and when somebody produces like a bung tire, comes out of fast-done, then good year is ready to expand its production and take advantage of that. So that's the actual nature of competition in capitalism. And that means that we get a cornyocopia of goods, even if we're lowly workers. The variety of goods in capitalism is overwhelming. And that just doesn't happen in socialism.
Starting point is 01:40:40 You get your 1942 costacres, your motorbike. That's it. When you put your money down a buy refrigerator It'll arrive in 10 years Because the factory is already fully constrained So all these resource constraints mean that people aren't happy under socialism and if you got a whole bunch of people That aren't happy
Starting point is 01:41:00 Then the best way to control them is to suppress them So I think in that sense ultimately yes it does lead to something like Stalinism. So it's easier to give happy people freedom. Yeah I mean happy people get pretty silly outside. I'm not particularly the extent to which Americans I've used and distort the word freedom draws me behind me. Well you know all of these words can be distorted but they all at the core have some fundamental power and beauty, and then we just distort on the surface for the fun of it, just start
Starting point is 01:41:32 battles on Twitter and so on. But what citizens of the Soviet world didn't feel was freedom, not just in, first of all, it wasn't freedom to buy commodities. The commodities were supposed to be on the shops weren't there. The volume couldn't be produced. And what you then got out of that as well was the classic Soviet joke, they pretend to pay us and we pretend to work. So you're not motivated. Oh, I went to Cuba about eight years ago. Yep, invited to give a talk then. And staying in a hotel, it's self, the hotels of story. There's one day my meetings were cancelled. So I thought I might go down to the beach. And they had
Starting point is 01:42:09 to, in the hotel, they had a wing, which is the tourist office and there were three women working inside the office. So I thought I just got up and asked them, you know, how do I get to the beach. And one of them says to me, and I stood there, just stood in the room, waiting to see if they'd make eye contact with me. Three women, nobody else in the room, waiting to see if they'd make eye contact with me. Three women, nobody else in the place, none of them looked at me. So I finally went up to one of them and said, I want to go to the beach and do some surfing, where, shit, I can get a taxi outside. Now, fundamentally, she was saying, I'm being paid shit money here. I'm not going to, I don't want to work. I'm not going to do anything,
Starting point is 01:42:48 apart from sit here and qualify for my time. And as much as there are reasons the Cubans have suffered from American embargoes and all that sort of stuff, you've still got that fundamental shortage economy that Corn I spoke about coming out of the structure of central ownership and central control of distribution and investment. Based my heart because I think some of the effects of that persist throughout time, they become part of the culture too. Yeah, it's very interesting. Negative culture. Yeah, well, from the Western perspective. Well, even from the people living through it.
Starting point is 01:43:20 I mean, I had enough conversation with Cubans, you know, meeting them on the street, hopping in a cab. And I was just one guy I was talking to, he was an industrial chemist and he's got a better money being a cab driver. Of course, he could make money out of taking foreign tourists from the airport to the city. By the way, this episode is brought to you by delicious Coca-Cola. That's why I didn't want to have it on camera but anyway. No, maybe they'll actually sponsor you might want to make sure you rotate the label to show this is Capitalism. What are we talking about here? Even though it's red
Starting point is 01:43:56 Yeah, but it's actually anarchist I should tell you I don't know if you know who Michael Malas? Michael Malice. He's an anarchist and he lives next door. He's a... I've lost touch with anarchist philosophy. I actually used to read, you know, Kropot, Koonan, Bakunan and so on. And I enjoyed their philosophy and then I helped organize an anarchist conference once. And that was the biggest antidote possible to being an anarchist. That sounds like an entry point to a joke.
Starting point is 01:44:26 Yeah. Help the organists. It is anarchist party. It is, I mean, we literally spent three days arguing over whether they're short or should not be a chairperson for conversations. Yeah. Well, that may be that... Money, money, life of Brian was lived outlawed.
Starting point is 01:44:47 Uh, look at the bright side of life. All right. So part of that explains why, for example, even to this day and some of those parts of the world, entrepreneurship does not, does not flourish. There's not a spirit in the people to start businesses to launch new endeavors and all those kinds of things. We're just taking all kinds of strange little strolls, but how do you explain the mechanisms of China today where there's quite a bit
Starting point is 01:45:20 of sort of flourishing of businesses and so on. It's a very peculiar kind of entrepreneurship. They got away from central control, but they still manage central political control with diversified economic control. So you could, it is possible to draw a line between power and technology. It is possible, and I think in some way it's trying to more like it is survivors of society
Starting point is 01:45:42 going into the future than Western capitalist societies are. So if we do the Karl Marx, the foreground and the background, you can centralize the politics, the humanity, the subjective stuff, and then distribute the objectives. You've got to have the goods. And that's the big change for a mouth is Don't Shelfing, was the characterizing that little saying that, I don't care where you have a black cat or a white cat, so long as it catches mice. And there was a level of pragmatism to the Don'toping revolution over Mao and Madame Mao in particular.
Starting point is 01:46:26 And that was manifest in the desire to get as much of those Western goods as possible. And I was actually in China in 81 to group of journalists there, so I mentioned earlier. For a tour, we ended up going to the Sichuan Free Trade Zone. And that gave us an idea of why China was going to succeed because they had a rule that you couldn't just come in and exploit the cheap wages. You had to also have a Chinese partner. And within five years, the Chinese partner had to own 50% of the business, which is huge. And it gives you an idea of the reduction in wages. These American corporations are looking at, they'd shut of the reduction in wages. These American corporations
Starting point is 01:47:05 are looking at, they'd shut down the factory in the, what's now the rust-billed of America. They might be paying somebody there, you know, at that time maybe $2 an hour, and they come across to China and they're paying to a sense an hour. So they were the enormous amount of wages that they dropped. They were willing to forgo half the profits and the ownership of the firm. So what the Chinese were doing wasn't just exploiting their labor force, it was also building a capitalist class.
Starting point is 01:47:35 And that meant that you had this, that's where all the Chinese corporations have come from. So they were building a capitalist system within a socialist command, a political system. And that worked. And it's still working. So it was the centralisation of the economic stuff, the GOZ plan approach. I think that was where the Soviets failed.
Starting point is 01:47:57 And what the Chinese realised after what they went through under mail was you have to have that capitalist period, but they weren't going to abandon the communist control politically, the country at the same time. And that worked out brilliantly, and there's a huge amount of innovation taking place in China today. And they also will do gigantic infrastructure projects, you know, breathtaking planning going into that. If you would have seen videos of building a skyscraper in a day, the planning that has to go into that, the pre-preparation of those necessary is enormous. So there's a real respect for engineers
Starting point is 01:48:31 as well in that society, which does not apply on the West. What do you think about the, from the Western perspective, the destructive effects of centralized control, the populace of the ideas of the discourse, of the censorship and the surveillance and all the other things. And it's a bit like we were talking about Russia to some extent beforehand with centralized versus decentralized corruption. And when you had the centralized political stuff, means you know you can't criticize within China, but so long as you don't criticize, you can do what you like.
Starting point is 01:49:06 And how destructive is that to the human spirit? From the American perspective, I found some pretty... I've been to China quite a few times over my life, a lot in the last... Not for about four years, but for the six years before that a few visits. And I'm staying in second and third and fourth tier cities. So, you know, populations of only four million people, which is quite small on China standards. And I had a lot of happy people that I was interacting with, my girlfriend at the time, her social circle.
Starting point is 01:49:41 And like you can feel when people can't discuss a political issue, for example, in Thailand, you can't discuss the king. They still have less measures to laws, so you can actually be jailed for discussing the king. And you can feel that, to some extent, and it's political issue in Thailand now. But in China, what I got back from most people, it was a bit like a big, big, big brother. But then when you get things out like the lockdown, which has applied recently, then you get the failings of the Soviet system is still there in the Chinese system, in that the
Starting point is 01:50:17 easiest way to avoid criticism as the underling carrying out instructions of people above you is to carry those instructions out to the letter beyond what the people actually want you to do at the top. So we had a classic illustration of that when I took these journalists, there was a news report saying that China's output of light industry had grown by 17% in the previous year, but heavy industry had fallen by 7%. We just didn't compute. So we kept on asking why did this happen? Every time we asked a question, this is back in 81.
Starting point is 01:50:52 The answer would be the initial answer. We followed the directive as a central committee, the Communist Party of China. We finally got a guide to elaborate and say what that was. He said, well, the central committee sent out a directive to promote light industry. So what did you do? Quite unquote, we stripped heavy industry factories and turned them into light industry. Now, that's destructive of everything. And that's the overlay that you've still got sitting over the top of China, but a huge part of the industrialisation was simply saying, produce whatever you can make goods market them seldom.
Starting point is 01:51:29 You get that innovative component of humanity is respected and the goods turn up and everybody's well fed food and a Russian are as far better than food in America. So, in terms of the material satisfaction and freedom, still, for example, enjoy dancing. I mean, we went to, I think for somewhere in Shanghai and there's this line of people involving a woman who would have been close to her nides and a kid who was about six or four,
Starting point is 01:51:59 partying it up, partying it up in the open air and doing this Chinese collective dance. You have to be really careful about that kind of thing. So in terms of measuring the flourishing of a people by looking at their happiness. I have so many thoughts on this, but I'm imagining North Korea. And if you talk to people in North Korea, I think they would say they're happy. No. Well, let me, let me, let me try to complete this argument. Not an argument, but a sort of challenge to your thought, which, especially in the bigger cities, because they don't know the alternative.
Starting point is 01:52:48 So what else do you need? There's enough food on the table. We have a leader that loves us and we love him. We're full of our hearts are full of love. Our table is full of food, they would say, because it's enough food. What else do you want from life? No, I think, okay, like that's sort of, because like that's an alternative. I mean, one time in Romania. So let me sort of complete that, sorry, because I'm taking the most challenging aspect. When there's centralized control of information information that you don't know the alternative that you don't know how green the grass is on the other side and so your idea of happiness might be very constrained so you know you could also argue that is happiness if you don't know like a ignorance is bliss ignorance is bliss and then so is
Starting point is 01:53:44 happiness really the correct measure. It's not for for the flourishing. It's not. But I mean, there's actually a classic book and movie as well, we called mouse last answer. Okay. And that is a young man explaining his progression from being a dancer in the cultural revolution through to a leading dancer in American and ultimately Australian ballet. And he explicitly says at one point that he's told that the Chinese people have the highest standard living in the world. And the reaction of him and these kids, like his fellow six year olds, is, God, it must be miserable elsewhere in the world then.
Starting point is 01:54:22 So they knew they still know. They still know there's no such thing as that complete ignorance. But what I'm talking about is experiences in trying to say back in about 2016, 2014, there was a feeling of freedom within limits that you didn't want to transgress because the system was working. So if you like marriage, it's kind of like marriage. Hey, that's a good example. There's limits. There's limits. You can have fun within those limits.
Starting point is 01:54:53 That's right. And people did have fun and they did feel free, but they didn't want to go and get divorced. But that dilemma was accommodated because the boundaries until you started hitting restrictions were wide. And like when you look at it, I mean, look at the, again, with the Chinese Communist Party, the administrators of that are often highly qualified engineers who can then make intelligent decisions about what should be done as infrastructure and so on. And you go to China and you've got an incredible high speed rail. Fantastic infrastructure, internet telecommunications and so on. Rapidly evolving solar.
Starting point is 01:55:36 There's a range of things there that are so well done, that reflect the fact that the selection process that gives you your political elite is partially focused upon sucking up, et cetera, et cetera, it's still there, but it's also focused upon your skill levels. And you get people making decisions who damn well know what they're talking about. Like Australia's got a classic example, the Internet Australia sucks.
Starting point is 01:56:00 The reason it sucks is that the Labor Party, which is our version of the Democrats was in control during the global financial crisis and as part of that they wanted to bring in optical fiber connections to the house. See, they have an optical fiber backbone and an optical fiber, you know, right to your C100 output from your home. And the Liberal Party fought that and said that's going to be too expensive. It's like too long to do. We're going to do cable to the node and then have a copper network linking from a node on a street to all the houses in the street. It's going to be cheaper and faster, have it more soon, blah, blah, blah, blah.
Starting point is 01:56:42 It was a total technical fuck up. Okay. And Australia now has an internet that's about 50 or 60 years faster in the world. It's dreadful for the internet. Two political figures made that decision, Tony Abbott and Malcolm Turnbull. Rivals and leaders of the conservative party we call liberal over there. Now that was shitty decisions that wouldn't happen in a country like China because you've got actual engineers making the decisions. They say
Starting point is 01:57:12 you can't get decent speed if you link optical fiber to copper. It's going to, so what you get is even though you can't make the decisions yourself, a vast majority of the decisions are made intelligently. And therefore you expect it. It's interesting, but don't you worry about the corrupting aspects of power? Oh yeah. That you start, you know, you're having engineers making intelligent decisions,
Starting point is 01:57:40 but at which point does the fat king start saying, are these engineers are annoying? I have good internet. I don't understand. Bring me the grapes. Well, that's the thing. You know, you get your collegular effects. That can happen.
Starting point is 01:57:54 I like Z from what I've seen has got elements of that. So friends of mine who are core cautions can get away with it. They have a game that they play at conferences, scoring how often people use with Z's name in a presentation and giving extra points for the number of photographs of Z that turn up in the whole thing. So you've got this sort of personality cult coming along as well. But at the same time, the planning for the infrastructure that's being built, the social services, the general freedom that exists is so great. And like any Chinese person alive today,
Starting point is 01:58:27 like somebody who's trying to my age would have been an adult under the early period of, but the late period of mal and God almighty that changed the improvement that's been in their lives, they, that's what they think about. So, but it's the, if you just look at the history of the 20th century, your intuition would say that some of the mechanisms we see in China now will get you into trouble in a long term.
Starting point is 01:58:55 So it seems to be working really well in many ways in terms of improving the quality of life of the average citizen in China, but you start to get worried about how does this go wrong? Well, yeah, but at the same time maybe, I mean often people will say, you know, what's your vision for the future? And what they mean is, what vision for the future do you have that I'm going to like? Right, okay. Now, what if you have a vision of the future you don't like? It's dreadful. Well, that's the ecological crisis. I think we're walking blindfolded into. Well, that's, right, that that that that part of the picture will have to we'll have to talk about how fundamental of a problem that is, okay, but what does that have to do with the
Starting point is 01:59:37 future? What that has to do is that if you wish to impose dramatic controls on the consumption of the rich, which would be necessary to reduce our consumption burden so that we can get closer to the ecological envelope we've destroyed already. Then you're going to make more likely successful doing that with a centralized system, where people accept centralized political control. Then you are in a country where it's all diversified, and you
Starting point is 02:00:03 scream freedom between every point and a tennis match. And I'm double literally seeing that when I was in Philadelphia sometime back. So the ideology, the accepts a collectivist attitude, maybe more successful in controlling our reducing human consumption levels. When we talk about democracy, I mean, who's voting here? How many horses and elephants and birds get to vote? Okay. It's very...
Starting point is 02:00:32 What's a bird? Yeah. What? You don't say them around here. It's a very human-centric vision we have of this planet. Yeah. And we're going to pay a price for that. Okay.
Starting point is 02:00:43 So you're saying to deal with global catastrophic events of centralized planning might be, you know. I think will work at a period. I mean, I like, but again. But there's some centralized stuff in the United States, for example. Oh, you're military. Yeah, I know.
Starting point is 02:00:59 No, no, okay. All right. Now, now's that, now there's that feisty Australian. Yeah. So besides the military, that's the ideal of the federal government in the United States is that there is some centralized infrastructure building. There's some big job project.
Starting point is 02:01:17 Yeah. But there's some. There's some. The question is, when you deal with greater and greater global catastrophic events, like the pandemic that we were just living through, that the government would be able to step up and impose enough centralized planning to allow us to deal, sort of enable and power the citizen rate to deal with these catastrophic events. In the case of the pandemic, a lot of people argue that the first of all, the world, but also in the United States failed to effectively deal with the pandemic on the medical side, social side, and the financial side, the supply chain,
Starting point is 02:01:56 everything in terms of communication, in terms of inspiring the populace with the power of science and all the Yeah, yeah, they they failed, but the the ideal is that we'd be able to succeed. You would have to have a small efficient, the ideal, the American ideal, you have a small efficient government that's able to take on tasks precisely like the pandemic. But the thing is maybe it shouldn't have been as small as it was. I mean, my favorite instance of that actually involves the UK because the whole neoliberal approach is about small efficient government.
Starting point is 02:02:29 Well, small efficient government works when you face small efficient challenges. When you face something systemic, rather than episodic, then it's gonna break down. And like this is, I mean, one of the things I greatly respect is telebs idea of anti-fragrantial. You want a society which is anti-Franjol not easily broken. Whereas neoliberalism has pushed us towards this vision of efficiency, but it's easily
Starting point is 02:02:51 snapped. Like in the UK, I've forgotten the government minister involved, but she asked her expert committee, how many, this is before, well, before the pandemic, how many masks should we have on hand in case of a pandemic? And the answer from the experts was about a billion. Okay, that's 50 masks. That's 20 masks per person. Okay. Oh, that's too many. Let's just make 50 million masks. That's one mask per person. It was gone in a matter of a day. Okay. And therefore that's why they told us, well, masks don't work, you know, what they meant was we don't have enough masks for our health people, let alone for you in the public. So we're going to bullshit you until you lose, mask don't really work.
Starting point is 02:03:33 And then people don't wear masks and then we've got enough masks, we rush up the production job. And by the time it comes along, people have got the skepticism about masks. So who does the library, who does the blame in that case gone to blame comes down to the philosophy that says government should always be small. But do you really think that bigger government would be the solution to the mask issue? No, let me let me push back sort of as possible that that's capitalism solves that problem. Well, not if there's no money in really long-term planning and capitalism. There's money in... Oh, you're sharing this. Isn't it possible to construct, isn't possible for capitalism to construct a system
Starting point is 02:04:15 that ensures against catastrophic events? Not when they're systemic. You can ensure against episodic events if you occasionally have a really bad storm, but in general, the weather is not so bad that all the infrastructure is being destroyed, then you can share that around on a percentage basis. If you have a Gaussian distribution for your events and you don't, the mean doesn't move around too much, and the standard deviation doesn't change all that much, then insurance works fine. But if you have an, if that's episodic, if you have systemic stuff where the climate is changing completely and you're going to wipe out your agricultural capabilities, you simply can't do insurance on that front. You can't make a
Starting point is 02:04:56 profit out of catastrophe and capitalism. Okay, so that example of climate change. Let's talk about it. Okay. So you mentioned that the human brain, the economy and the biosphere are three of the most complex systems we know. Okay. And you also criticize the economics community for economics community for looking at the effects of climate change when measured as the effect on the GDP. So you're saying it's a catastrophic thing that the biggest challenge our society, our world is facing. Why? If the economy is disagree with you, the effects on the GDP will be minor. So we'll deal with it when it comes.
Starting point is 02:05:49 That's the argument against that's the devil's advocate. You're saying no is a thing that will change our world forever in ways that we should really, really, really be thinking about. Make the case of why this would be really simple. Economists have made up their own numbers to say that it's trivial and you didn't. I know I haven't even tried to make the numbers. I'm reading what the scientists write. Okay. Okay. And what the economists have done, and like this is William Nordhausen particular, no ball prize winner, ex-president of the American Economic Association, literally assume assume that a roof will protect you from climate change. He didn't say it in those words.
Starting point is 02:06:30 What he said was, 87% of American industry occurs in carefully controlled environments, which will not be subject to climate change. Now, the only things that all of manufacturing, all of services, he included mining as well, forgetting about open-cut mining, government activities and the finance sector. all of the services, he included mining as well, forgetting about open-cut mining, government activities and the finance sector, all they have in common is they happen beneath a roof. So he's basically saying climate affects the weather, climate is weather, okay? Okay, now that is not at all what is meant by climate change, it's mean changing the entire pattern
Starting point is 02:07:01 what is meant by climate change. It's mean changing the entire pattern of the, of the, of the weather system of the planet. For example, the most extreme form of climate change would be a breakdown in the three circulation cells that exist in each hemisphere. The Hadley cell, the Ferrocell, I think it's called on the polar cell, zero to 30, 30 to 60, 60 to 90.
Starting point is 02:07:21 Those are the main bubbles, if you like, in the atmosphere. Now, if we 90, those are the main bubbles if you like in the atmosphere. Now if we get enough increase in the energy in the atmosphere, that like just like you turn the temperature up on a stove and you have nice bubbles occurring in a pot of soup and then turn the temperature up and they all break down and you've got bubbles everywhere. That's called the Equipal Climate. If that happens, then most of the rainfall is going to occur between 0 and 20 and 70 and 90 and the middle is going to be dry, except for extreme storms. We would, we, we built our societies in a period of extreme stability of the climate. And when you look at the long term temperature records, it's up and down like a sea saw, like a sore tooth blade, between say one degree warmer than now and four degrees or six degrees
Starting point is 02:08:10 cooler over the last million years. And when you look at where we evolved, it's just the determining point on the peak of one of those ups and downs. So those, I've forgotten the name of the cycles, but the cycles caused by changes in the earth rotation around the sun. And so we evolved our civilization just at the top. So coming up from a cold period, and then we're going to head down to another cold period. And that's when human civilization came along. It's about a period of about 12,000 years. So across that period, the temperature has changed by not
Starting point is 02:08:45 much more than half the degree up and down. Now, we're blasting it well and truly out of those confines. And my way of interpreting what climate change means is the stability of that climate that enables to build sedentary civilizations and not be an aromatic species is being destroyed. So the challenge, and by the way, I'm playing devil's advocate. Right here. The question is, is there something fundamentally different now about human civilization that we're able to build technology that alleviates some of the destructive effects that we have on the climate. We don't know. We're going to find out the hard way. And the uncertainty you think
Starting point is 02:09:33 will be very costly. Extremely. Like many of the trajectories that we might take will be much more costly than they're profitable. Yeah. And like we've seen some of the storms that are happening now in Europe, the ones that you know, washed away village in Germany some time ago, the firestorm that hit Canada of all places, I've forgotten the name of the town that was burnt down, but enormous temperatures in Canada. Again, the storms are really happening back in Australia. These are all manifestations of a complete shift in the weather patterns of the planet. And they can wipe out like, you know, a village just disappears, it's wiped out by, you know, unprecedented rains.
Starting point is 02:10:11 And this keeps on happening. We're still living in a sedentary lifestyle when we're in a pneumatic species. Okay. So, to be able to maintain that sedentary lifestyle, we do need to engineer the planet. We need to keep it within that range of plus one, plus half a degree Celsius, minus half a degree, which is really what has been like for the last 10, 12,000 years, instead we're blasting it right out of that range.
Starting point is 02:10:38 And we know some of the past climates that have existed then, we can model what they imply for our food production systems for example not the only example but obviously crucial. So when you look at what they call global climate models produced by scientists one of the examples and it was published by the OECD last year 2021 in the chapter on what happened if we lose what's called the Atlantic meridional overturning circulation or AMOC and people would colloquially know that as a Gulf Stream and that's what distributes heat or around all the
Starting point is 02:11:14 oceans of the planet as he was part of a huge chain called the Thermaholine Circulation but the part that goes across from the the equator to the North Atlantic that's called the AMOC and Gulf Stream for colloquial way. If that disappears in the context of a two and a half degree Celsius increase in average global temperature, then the proportion of the Earth's surface, which is suitable for producing wheat, will fall from 20% to 7%. Proportion for corn, similar sort of fall, the proportion suitable for rice will fall from 20% to 7%. Proportion for corn, similar sort of fall. The proportion suitable for rice will go from 2% to 3%.
Starting point is 02:11:51 Now, that means a catastrophic, and that's the word used in the report, catastrophic collapse in food production. So that's what we're touring with. And we are one and a half. We've actually less than, we're about halfway there to that 2 degrees, 2.5. And economists, on the other hand, this is Richard Tull. Okay, published a paper, 2016,
Starting point is 02:12:15 claiming using what he calls an integrated assessment model, that economists developed, that losing the Gulf Stream would increase global GDP by 1.1%. Now, his model, this is what really pisses me off about these people, it's the worst work I've read in 50 years of being a critic of neoclassical economics. The GCM, the one percentist produce, of course, include precipitation as well as temperature.
Starting point is 02:12:42 The IAMs that the economists produce, and this is stated yet again in the paper in 2021, do not include precipitation. They simply have temperature. So they assume that if temperature improves by moving towards the temperature, which is better for producing aquaculture, then so will precipitation. Now, that's completely wrong. They've left out a crucial, a mentioned trun a model to climate while ignoring the fact that there's rainfall. That's what they've
Starting point is 02:13:09 done. So their work is so bad, so dreadfully bad, it should never have been public. So they overs, okay. I'm going to go for them. Sorry. This is one 100% as they deserve it. So it's an oversimplification, but I also want you to steal man, people you disagree with and criticize people you agree with, if possible, to be intellectually honest here. You do say, to push back on the catastrophic thinking about climate change, that the ecology, the biosphere is a complex system. Yeah. Economics, the economy is a complex system. So how can we make predictions about complex systems?
Starting point is 02:13:57 How can we make a hope of having a semi-confident predictions about the complex system. So the scientific communities is very confident about the complex system that is the biosphere and the crisis that's before us on the horizon. And then the economists are as a community, I don't know what percentage, but too much. It's that part of the community is very confident, looking at the economics complex system in saying that no, this system we have of labor, money and capital and so on would be able to deal
Starting point is 02:14:44 with that crisis and any other crisis. And they kind of construct simplified models that justify their confidence. So how do we know who to believe? For start, if you believe the economists, you need your head read because when you... It's not an argument. And that's not an argument. It's a summary of an argument.
Starting point is 02:15:05 And that is a lot like an opinion and an emotional. I know, I know. I'm so angry about it. Listen, I'll tell you where I stand. Yeah. And I've begun looking, studying the climate change. Yeah. Much more.
Starting point is 02:15:19 I used to be on things I don't understand. have not spent time on, I have so many colleagues that are scientists that I deeply respect and I trust their opinion. I have seen the lesser angels of my colleagues on the pandemic side, on the side, the confidence, the arrogance that in part blinded, I believe, the jump between basic scientific research to the public policy. And then that, so I've become a little bit more cautious in my trust on climate change. I'm still in the same place. And I don't mean climate change.
Starting point is 02:16:11 And anything scientific to say, I've become a little bit, wait a minute. How does the basic scientific facts of our reality map to what we should do as a human civilization. There, I want to be a little bit careful. So whenever now, I see arrogance and confidence, I become suspicious. Well, I'm the same. And that's why I'm being angry about the economists, because there's unergoned. Incredible arrogance, incredible stupidity that the arrogance, assumptions which you look at it and think how did anybody let that get published? That's what the economic analysis of the effects of climate change are poor.
Starting point is 02:16:53 Very many kids. Incredibly poor. And this is like, but Bjorn Lombog stars himself as the skeptical environmentalist and criticizes the environmental models. He doesn't take a look. He doesn't criticize the work come up by economists. You look at it, it's so bad. Is it possible to do good economics modeling of the effects of climate change?
Starting point is 02:17:15 Yeah, it is possible, very difficult. Or is it like one complex system's tech? It's true, no. Then that case, yeah, I mean, like to me, the what you should be looking at is saying, what are the scientists saying are the consequences, probable consequences, not guaranteed, but probable consequences of increasing the energy level of the atmosphere
Starting point is 02:17:37 by the amount we're doing. What can the scientists say in terms of like the effects, because it's so complicated, the effects of sort of shifting resources. So basically, what are the effects of climate change? How can we really model that? Because it's basically, you're looking through the fog of uncertainty, because they're rising sea levels. How can we know what effect that has?
Starting point is 02:18:01 Well, yeah, there'll be a lot of change. Yeah, I don't actually, I think think the sea level one is a poor argument, and I don't focus on it. What I mainly focus upon is the weather patterns. Okay, and if you look at, like we've got the wheat belt in America goes through what Idaho and countries, places like that. And you've got incredibly deep top soil.
Starting point is 02:18:23 Ukraine is another classic example. The depth that the topsoil in Ukraine is remarkable, and that's the wheat bowl of Europe. And that requires both right temperature for growing wheat and the right rainfall for growing wheat. Now, when we look at the models that climate scientists are building of that, you have pretty much your ultimate foundation is the Lorenz model of turbulent flow. And of course, that's the first model which we saw chaos theory, complexity, that beautiful, simple model, three
Starting point is 02:18:55 variables, three parameters, an incredible complexity out of the system. But what that meant was you also had an exponential decay in the accuracy of your model over time. So, if you have, if you'd accurate to a thousand decimal places, then in a thousand days, you'll have no data whatsoever, because each time you're losing an order of magnitude of accuracy. Okay.
Starting point is 02:19:20 So, that's the point about the inability to predict for the very long future. But what you can just say, well, there's a prediction horizon. If we're close enough to the, if our statistical measurement of where we are, is close enough to where we actually are, and our forecast horizon is narrow enough to not extrapolate too far, then for this jix and forward, we can make a reasonable fister predicting what the weather's going to be. And that's the foundation of meteorological, the stuff we watch on TV, you know, most of the time the forecast are going to be correct these days.
Starting point is 02:19:52 40, 50 years ago, most of the time the forecast were wrong. So that's the background foundation to these GCMs. But even they've got a massively simplified world. So you have this enormous fear of where they might divide it down to 100 kilometer by 100 kilometer by 10 kilometer, you know, cube, rectangles, whatever, oblongs. That's how they're modeling the transition of where they're from one location to another.
Starting point is 02:20:21 So they've got a chunky vision of the plant, which they have to, they can't model it now, down to the last molecule. So they've got a chunky vision of the plant, which they have to. They can't model, now down to the last molecule. So you're losing it. No, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no,
Starting point is 02:20:37 no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no, no 100 kilometres, I think about 10 kilometres grids now, I don't know. But so the processing powers let us get more and more precise that way. I do know that the models now include chemical mixing that occurs above cities, they've added that complexity to them over time. So you're looking at the increasingly accurate models, the weather patterns, the effect they have on agriculture, on food.
Starting point is 02:21:01 And you're saying that there's a lot of possibilities in which that's going to be really destructive to society and the food production side. And if you have that increase in temperature, you're going to go to change in precipitation. And it could mean that where the rainfall and the sunshine are adequate for growing wheat is an area where there's no topsoil. It's like a huge part of the models, the models the economists use, which only use temperature, don't include precipitation. They predict that a large amount of the weight of the weight output of the world is going to occur in Siberia, in the frozen tundra.
Starting point is 02:21:35 What about, so that that's a straightforward criticism of oversimplified models? What about the idea models. What about the idea that we innovate our way out of it? So there's totally new, what is the, there's a silly poor example at this time perhaps, but lab-grown meat sort of engineered food. So a completely shifting source of food for civilization. So therefore alleviating some of the pressure on agriculture. That comes down to the difference that Elon makes between producing a prototype and mass producing the prototype.
Starting point is 02:22:17 You can develop the idea very rapidly to put that into production on the scale that's necessary to replace what we're currently doing in six years. Yeah, and we haven't got years. We might have decades. We certainly haven't got centuries. So in the timeframe we've got, I can't see that engineering going from prototype to production levels to produce what we're currently doing in the stable environment, they're currently destroying. What do you think about the sort of the catastrophic predictions that people that have thought,
Starting point is 02:22:49 have written about climate have made in the past that haven't come to the people? Mainly, unfortunately, involving Paul Alec and the population bomb, and the predictions, Paul, was made. Well, a few individuals or the one individual in that case. Yeah. So I'm mostly playing Devils Adidas conversation
Starting point is 02:23:04 and you join doing so. I do think I'm an agreement with the majority of the scientific community, but you still say that argument might. I still see the argument made. And I also am a little bit worried about the arrogance and the ineffectiveness of the arrogance. This is the problem is ineffective. ineffective. And that's what worries me because it's all been put into the sort of sea level rise, temperature changes. It's not put into the fragility of the system in which we currently live. And the earth will survive.
Starting point is 02:23:45 And there's a wonderful science victim book called The Earth of Bards about a world in which humans get wiped out. There's only a tiny little band left and then the earth re-asserts itself. So the earth's going to survive us. Will we survive what we do at The Earth? That's the question. And my feeling is that we have underplayed the extent to which the civilisations were built have depended upon a relatively stable climate. And as thin as that turning point in the maximum in the global average temperature, that we evolved right on the top of it. And if we had done nothing,
Starting point is 02:24:19 we could find that heading back down towards another ice age could equally destroy the possibility of sedentary life. But we, for example, we'd never developed fossil fuel based industries. We'd never built a super phosphate. So our population would never have reached one billion people. And we were still living like fairly sophisticated animals,
Starting point is 02:24:40 but you know, like 17th century level of load on the planet, then we would have gone down that decline. And the approaching ice age would have started to wipe out our farming areas, the glaciers would have encroached, and we would have been driven out of an agricultural sedentary civilization by that change. So it's just the fact that we evolved on this stable period in the overall temperature cycle of the planet.
Starting point is 02:25:06 That stability is something which just reflects the turning point in a regular cycle of malachivic cycle, I think it's called. I've forgotten the actual name, but it's a cycle caused by changing the earth or orbit around the sun, reflectivity and so on. That cycle, it's just that tiny top bit that we evolved in. So what we should have done is, well, that's really useful for us, we should stay at that level. Now, if we hadn't done it, we'd go back down here and that at the end of our civilization by an ice age, instead we're going up here really rapidly. And we're causing a change in temperature compared to the long-term cycle,
Starting point is 02:25:47 100,000 times faster. So, yeah, my biggest worry is even subtle changes in climate might result in geopolitical pressures that then lead to a nuclear war. And that's, yeah, I mean, there's an argument that's actually behind, to some extent, not the Ukraine war so much, but the Arab Spring, the walls in Syria, which partially has led to what's happening in Ukraine. So, and our weapons are getting more and more powerful, more and more destructive, more and more nations are having these destructive weapons. more destructive, more and more nations are having these destructive weapons. And now we're entering cyber space where it's even easier to be destructive. I'm happy that Eric weapons, which didn't exist in the Second World War. So, you know, you don't need nuclear weapons to have catastrophic attacks on each other.
Starting point is 02:26:38 So yeah, it's incredibly scary that the war like side of human nature could be extremely enhanced by climate breakdown. So, in this world, I don't know how we went from Marxism and Stalinism to ecology, but all those are beautiful complex systems. What is the best form of government would you say? We talked about the economics at things. You ran for office, so you care about politics too. How can politics, what political systems can help us here? I think we first of all have to appreciate where one species is on a planet out of millions. And as the intelligent species, we should be enabling a harmonious life for those other species as well.
Starting point is 02:27:33 Can we actually linger on that? What is, you mentioned that we need to acknowledge the value of life on Earth. Can we integrate the labor theory of value? Can we integrate into that the value of life? So there's human life. I think if you take like that structure that I talked about, Marx's use value exchange value, dialectic, the foreground background, that only exists that only works because we're exploiting the free energy we find in the universe. There could be no production system without free energy, which is the first law of thermodynamics
Starting point is 02:28:17 to exist. There is free lunch after all, and it's grounded in the energy that's provided to us. Well, yeah, that's the free lunch. That's what we could exploit. It's the only free lunch we have. You know, Ginsburg summary of the laws of thermodynamics, don't you? Alan Ginsburg, we'll see.
Starting point is 02:28:31 The first, the laws of thermodynamics are summarized, you can't win. B, you can't break even. Yep. So you can't leave the game. Nice. Beautiful summary. Beautiful summary. But the fact that exists in the first. Nice, yeah, beautiful summary. Beautiful summary, okay.
Starting point is 02:28:45 But the fact that exists in the first place is the free lunch, okay. So we're exploring the free lunch. But to be able to do it, we can't put waste back into that system so much that it undermines the free lunch. And that's what we've been doing. And once you respect the fact that we have to,
Starting point is 02:29:03 living on the biosphere, the planet we're actually on, we have to enable that biosphere to survive us because if it doesn't survive us, we won't survive it disappearing. And there's not that realization in humanity in general. And when you say the value of life, you know, all the different living organisms on earth are part of that biosphere. Yeah. So in order to maintain the biosphere, we have to respect, like, pragmatically speaking what that means is actually respecting all of life on earth, even the mosquitoes. I've got some of, no.
Starting point is 02:29:40 So I personally, I mean that we are a parasite when you look at it We're the mosquitoes of the human of the the large Organizations you if you're a fan of the matrix movies at all, okay, you know the state where I look what I'm wearing absolutely Wondering what the inspiration what I was thinking about really is the inspiration We are living in a simulation. Okay, And I have a conversation offline to have with you about that. Okay, well, it's behaving and we're going to have to put you back in line. So what's agent Smith says when he's got Morpheus in his possession, he said, I've been trying to classify your species and for decided you're a virus. Okay. Now there's truth that we have
Starting point is 02:30:21 intruded into everything. Okay. We've taken over every element of the biosphere, and we think we can continue doing that. The thing is we're exporting it so much, we're breaking it down. I think I see O'Willson, who argued for the 50% rule, he believed that we should reserve 50% of the planet for non-human species. In other words, we make 50% of it off limits. Humans cannot go there. And we just let that evolve as it does, and then we control the other 50%.
Starting point is 02:30:55 I think it's probably giving us how much to us. I think we should actually say it's like 20%, 25% max. And the rest of the planet, we let life go on and evolve as it does without our interference, without our dominance. Now, that's neither a democratic system nor an authoritarian one. It's one which starts off with saying the first thing humans have to do is respect life itself. Okay, so would we do that? We haven't done it, obviously.
Starting point is 02:31:27 I don't think the Soviets would have done it if we had a generally Soviet system. We haven't done it under a capitalist. We continue intruding. So we, I think we have to go through something like a Star Trek, a Star Trek, you know, catastrophic 200 years to realize that ultimately if we're going to survive as a species, we have to respect life in general. And then that means we parts of the planet, we can no longer touch. While we also try to maintain the planet at the temperature that we found in what we now call the Anthropocene. So politically, we have to have, like in many ways what native societies often have, a vision
Starting point is 02:32:09 of the cycle of life, not this exponential progression we've developed over the last 250 years. And again, I'll use another movie, The Avatar type respect for the cycle of life. We need to have that as part of our innate nature. And then on top of that, the political system comes out. Now, that political system has to be one that lets us feel like we have a say in the direction of society while that part is sacrosanct. Okay, we can't touch it. But we also, because we are now living in so many challenges created by our own civilization, I mean, the main threat to the existence of human civilization
Starting point is 02:32:50 is the existence of human civilization. Is both the feature and the bug? Yeah. And therefore, we need to have people who can understand complex systems making those decisions. Now, that means it isn't a political system as much as it is an appreciation that the world is a complex system and therefore effects which we think a direct effects will actually come through in a bleak fashion and we cannot is no simple linear progression from where we are to where we want to be. So you have to see how everything feeds together in a systemic way and that's why I want to reason I designed the software I'm wearing the T-shirt for now. Minskie is to have, it's nowhere nearer to the scale. I hope it one way will be.
Starting point is 02:33:32 But something which means we can bring together all that complexity, all those systems and perceive them on an enormous screen where we have all the various intracts and we can see what are potential futures. And that then guides us. So it isn't a case of democracy and our side wins a vote. And therefore we ban abortion or whatever else happens. It's seeing what the, respecting the fact that we're in a complex system and being uncertain
Starting point is 02:34:01 about the consequences and not making the bold, expansionary ideas that we've been doing. So like being a little bit more humble. Humble is a good word, but wouldn't you like to apply that same humility both to the considerations of the pros of capitalism and to the catastrophic view of the effects of climate change? Yeah. And also, I think we can afford to be bold in space. And that's one reason I respect the practical vision of masks and so far, in practical vision of basals, that if we're going, we look for the very far future, the only way we can continue expanding our knowledge of the universe is to move
Starting point is 02:34:55 our civilization, the productive side of off the planet. Offside back up. Yeah. So can you actually linger on this? So let's actually talk about this. So first of all, you have the new book, humbly named, the new economics, a manifesto.
Starting point is 02:35:13 A publisher chose the title. Yes, no, but I'm joking, but maybe I will ask you about why manifesto, but we'll go through some of the ideas. And this book we have been already, so some of it is embracing the fact that the economy, our world, our mind is a complex system. So this t-shirt that you're wearing,
Starting point is 02:35:36 yep, like an out, yeah. Is a software. I'll do that, do you like it? There you go, you're wearing a book. I can look like an information. So there's a t shirt that says min ski. After not not not my min ski, it's your min ski. I'm not a min ski. Not a Marvin min ski. Not Marvin min ski. Right. So I'm not Marvin. Not Marvin. Yeah.
Starting point is 02:36:02 Yeah. So that's so AI min skis is marron and then harron it all rhymes. So stability is free open source system dynamics software invented by Mr. Steve Keene, coated by Russell Sandish. It's on source forage. It's destabilizing. The ability to do stipulage. So that's sort of embracing the complex aspect of it. Yeah.
Starting point is 02:36:34 So how can you model the economy? What are some of the interesting, were there detailed or high level big picture ideas behind your efforts of Minsky? Okay, Minsky, meaning the software, the modeling software, that models the dynamics of the MEDID. That's basically what Minsky is doing is system dynamics modeling. So if anybody's used Stella or Vensim or Simulink, then they've used exactly the same family of software that Minsky is part of. So I didn't invent that.
Starting point is 02:37:04 That was invented by Jay Forresto, one of the great intellects, one exactly the same family, the software that Minsk is part of. So I didn't invent that. That was invented by J. Fyrastos, one of the great intellects, one of the great engineers in American history. And the idea of Fyrastos system was complex interactions. So he was doing his work in the 50s. People don't know Fyrastos work. He actually built the models of the mathematics for the gun turrets on American warships and the second world war mechanical systems obviously.
Starting point is 02:37:33 So he had to work out how to give a feedback system that meant when the boat rolled in one direction, the turret did not roll the other way, all that stuff was his work. So marvelous engineering. And then he realized if you want to look at it, even like a factory, a factory is a complex system. And so you get cycles generated out of the interaction between different components of the factory that he was first involved in taming, that he built the software to model complex interactive systems.
Starting point is 02:37:59 So Minski is that, the thing at Minski ads, which is unique, is the godly table, and that's the double entry book keeping, so you can model the financial system. Godly the economist. Godly the economist, WinGodling, another great man. So there's this, you're modeling a state diagram. Yeah, fundamentally. Actually, it's circuit diagrams. It's exactly what engineers have been using for decades, almost a century. So you're using a circuit diagram to model
Starting point is 02:38:26 the economy. And that's the other packs we've done it, what they haven't had in the circuit diagram is a way of handling the dynamics of the financial system. So what the Godly Table does is bring it, financial flows has been, everything goes from somewhere and ends up somewhere. So you have a positive and negative if you're looking on the liability side, a positive and a positive or negative and a negative if you're looking at assets and liability side and Minsk gets the accounting right for that. So you can do an enormous complex model looking at the economy financially from the point of view of a dozen different actors in the economy
Starting point is 02:39:05 and know that the mathematics is right, even though what you're building is set of differential equations, which might be 50 differential equations with 350 terms in them. If you get the godly tables right, you know the mathematics is correct. So that's the main innovation that Minskia adds. And you're operating there at the macroeconomics level? Yeah, it's definitely macro. It's top down. It's not it's not agent based. And then this I'm just open on random pages. I think it's very relevant here. The process this is referring to Minskia not the software. Maybe the software. I don't know. The process can be captured in an extremely simple causal chain capital determines output, output determines employment, the rate of employment
Starting point is 02:39:44 determines the rate of change of wages, output minus wages and interest capital determines output, output determines employment, the rate of employment determines the rate of change of wages, output minus wages, and interest payments determines profit, the profit rate determines the, there's a very nice circuit here. The profit rate determines the level of investment, which is the change in capital, which takes us back to the beginning of this causal chain
Starting point is 02:40:01 and the difference between investment and profits determines the change in private debt. And there's some nice, the Keynes-Minsky model and the Intermittent Route to Chaos on page 86 of your book. These are, do these come from the software? Yeah, I mean, I first did that in Mathematica back in 1992, August 1992. Mathematica is another amazing piece of software. Yeah, I find it, it's very much a program is approached to mathematics.
Starting point is 02:40:30 I prefer like a program called MathCAD, which is what I'm using for all my, when I do my mathematics on the computer, I run MathCAD. CAD, or CAD. CAD. Okay. It's been ruined by a bad management.
Starting point is 02:40:44 They chucked out all the good engineers and I'm still using a version which is 12 years old. If only engineers ruled the world. If only engineers are other than this particular case, there was a bunch of marketers for CAD software. I'm definitely a fan of engineers. What are the plots that we're looking at here? Growth rate, private debt ratio, employment versus wages, employment versus debt, income distribution. So this is across years, like different trade-offs. Yeah, is there something interesting to say about the plots and the insights from those plots that are very great? Yeah, yeah, the software.
Starting point is 02:41:16 That's a particular parameter value to give that outcome. But what happened when I first simulated the model? I took a model by Garkord Richard Goodwin, who's one of the great neglected economists, American Marxist, mathematical Marxist. And what he did was build a model of cycles. And he actually wrote a paper called, it's only about a five-page paper,
Starting point is 02:41:40 published in a book and a very, very obscure conference paper. And what he was doing was trying to build a model of Marx. So if you wrote it in 1967 and it was putting it in a mathematical form, a model that Marx came up with in 1867. So it was a centenary birthday present to Marx. And what Marx had argued in chapter 25, I think, of Volume 1 of Capital, section 3, he built a verbal model of a cyclical system. And it's quite out of character with the rest of the book. So when you read Volume 1 of Capital, people think Marx has got a commodity money, view of money.
Starting point is 02:42:23 He doesn't at all. He simply did, he, the idea was he had like an onion. You start off on the middle level and you ignore the outer layer then you bring the outer layer and so on and so on and so forth. Anyway, in this model, in volume one of capital, he normally just to see and work has got a subsistence wage. That's it. But in this little chapter, he said that if the economy is,
Starting point is 02:42:44 effectively he said, economy is booming, then workers will demand wage rises. And the wage rises will cut into the profit so that capitalists will not get the level of profit they're expecting. Therefore, they will invest less and the economy will slump. And the slump will mean workers become unemployed and have to accept wage cuts. And it was a model of a cyclical economy. And as it happens, Mark's been his later years trying to learn enough calculus to be able
Starting point is 02:43:11 to model as himself mathematically. And he never managed. There's Marx's mathematical notes on calculus, which are quite fun to read. And if you have a mathematical background, did he get far? Or no, he got too caught up in the whole philosophy and never really got to build the model. But what Goodman Meritlis was a predator prey model. Okay, the Lok de Volterra model was the basis of the idea. You say what the idea is you have a prey,
Starting point is 02:43:35 like the very example that Lok de actually used initially, was grass, grass is the prey. And then you have a predator and the predator were cows. So you start off with a very few cows and lots of grass. And then because lots of grass, the numbers of cows grow. And then because the cows grow, they start to eat the grass. So the grass runs out, so the cows starve. And you get a cycle.
Starting point is 02:44:01 And what Lector was amazed by was that the cycles were persistent. They didn't die out. So Goodwin got that vision and he then built a predator-pray model. And I, first of all, read Goodwin and really found it really hard to follow his writing. He's not a very good writer, but a guy called John Blatt, who was a professor of mathematics at New South Wales University, wrote a brilliant explanation of Goodwin's model in a book called Dynamic Economic Systems. And I read that, it was superb.
Starting point is 02:44:27 And you said, away you could extend this, was to include finance. So I thought, well, okay, what I'm going to have is that what Goodman presumed is capitalist invest all their profits. So you get boom when there's a high rate of profit because they invest all that money. And then a slump when there's low profit, because depreciation will wipe away capital and you'll go boom and slump. So I simply added in, well, capitalists will invest more than their profits during a boom, but less than their profits during a slump. And that therefore means they had to borrow money to finance the gap and pay interest on the debt. So I ended up with a model with
Starting point is 02:45:04 just three system states, the income share, the wages, distribution of income from workers, capitalists and bankers, the level of employment and the level of private debt. And those three equations are fundamentally like going from the Lotte de Voltaire model with just two equations and therefore you get a fixed cycle to the Lorenz model where you have three. And therefore, what I got out of it was the chaotic outcomes. So what you're seeing is a manifestation of chaos, complexity in those plots. But the fascinating, one of the many fascinating parts
Starting point is 02:45:38 about it was that as the level of private debt rose, I, in my model, I had capitalists being the only ones who borrowed, but the people who paid for the high level of private debt rose, in my model, I had capitalists being the only ones who borrowed, but the people who paid for the high level of private debt were the workers. The rising bankers share, corresponded exactly to a falling workers' share. So you can infer from that that the workers are the ones paying? Effectively, the workers end up paying for it. They get a lower level of wages.
Starting point is 02:46:05 And the basic dynamic is that when you have a three social class system, your income goes between workers, capitalists, and bankers. Now, in the system, the good one did, they're just workers and capitalists. So if workers share rows, capital, share had default. But when you have three social classes,
Starting point is 02:46:22 then capitalists share can remain constant while workers fall in bankers, workers falls and bankers rise. So that's what actually happened, because capitalists, the simple way I modeled it was there's a certain amount of profit at which capitalists invest all their profits. Above that they borrow more, below that they pay off debt. So what would happen is when you got back to that point, then the level of investment would be a precise share of GDP. And therefore, you'd get a precise rate of economic growth. But if there was a higher percentage going to bankers and offset by a lower share going to workers, it didn't affect the capitalists. So what you get is the cycles sort of diminish
Starting point is 02:47:00 for a while because there's, or there's the other, the income distribution effect is important. So the workers pay for the increasing level of debt. But the other side of it was that the cycles were diminished for a while. Now what you get is a period of diminishing cycles, then leading to rising cycles. And technically this is known as the Pomer Manerville route to chaos. And it's one particular element of Florens' equations and fluid dynamics. So what they found was in examining laminar flow and a fluid, you have a period where the laminar flow got more laminar, and then suddenly it has started to get less laminar and go turbulent. And this is what actually goes on in the model.
Starting point is 02:47:48 So in my model of Minsk, so what you have is a period where there's big berms and cycles, and then as the debt level rises, the berms and slums get smaller, and that looks like what neo-classical economists call the great moderation. So when I first model this in 1982, I finished up my paper, which is published in 1995, what I thought was an ice rhetorical flourish, saying the chaotic dynamics of this paper should warn us against regarding a period
Starting point is 02:48:16 of relative stability in a capitalist economy as anything more than a lull before the storm. Now I thought it was a grace period of rhetoric, I didn't think it was gonna fucking happen, but it did because you had this period from 1990 through to 2007 where there were diminishing cycles and the neoclassicals labeled that the great moderation and they took the credit for it. They thought that the economy was being managed by them to allow a rate of inflation, lower level of unemployment, less instability over time, and they literally took credit for it. And I was watching that and thinking, that's like my model running,
Starting point is 02:48:49 and I'm scared of shit, that there'll be a breakdown. I ended up not working in the area for a while because I wrote debunking economics, and I got involved in a fight over the modeling of competition in near classical theory. That took me away for about four or five years. And then I got asked to do a court case in 2005, end of 2005. And I used Minsk as my framework for arguing that somebody who was involved in predatory lending should be able to get out of the debt they were in.
Starting point is 02:49:22 And I explained Minsk's theory. And I used this throwaway line of saying debt levels have been private debt if you're rising exponentially. And then I thought, well, I can't, as an expert, just make a claim like that. I've got to check the data. And the debt ratio was rising exponentially. And I thought, holy shit, we're in for a financial crisis. And somebody has to warn about it.
Starting point is 02:49:43 At least in Australia, I was that somebody. So can you given this chaotic dynamics idea, can you talk about the crisis is ahead of us in the future? So one of the things, I mean, it's a fundamental question of economics, is economics about understanding the past or predicting the future? because you can construct models that do poetic like a 95 poetic illusion. Yeah, and then you can watch years come fly by and some of the predictions in retrospect that you make turn out to be true. But you know, you can all kinds of gurus throughout history have done that kind of thing. And you can call yourself right and forget all the many times you've been wrong. Let's talk about the future, what kind of stuff you mentioned about the importance of the biosphere, but what are the crises that are ahead of us? That the chaotic dynamics view
Starting point is 02:50:44 allows us to protect it. What really I saw coming out of it, leaving us ideacological, wasn't a crisis. It was stagnation because what we got out of the crisis was caused by a rising level of private debt. Now you reach a peak level where the willing is to take on debt collapses. And so you go to a period where debt is rising all the time. So credit, which is the annual change in debt, and that's
Starting point is 02:51:12 credit is part of aggregate demand and aggregate income. So credit goes from positive to negative, and that causes a slump. So can you describe why that causes a slump? Okay. When credit goes to negative, if you ask Paul Krugman, you'll tell you credit applies no role in aggregate demand. Okay. Give me a second. Uh, credit plays no role in aggregate demand. So the vision, the vision that the NAO classicles have for the banking system is what they
Starting point is 02:51:37 call learnable funds. It's Paul Krugman, by the way, the, uh, the, the night at the front of the army that is the neoclassical economist. Yeah, fundamentally. Sure. Okay. He's he's politically reasonable, which makes him more dangerous than those that aren't. He's politically, yeah, there's quite a lot of people that would disagree with that characterization of Paul Krugman as he's politically reasonable.
Starting point is 02:52:03 You could say you should say the people, but the alternatives. Okay. Fair enough. Okay. That's not a negative opus. There's a statement that's just he can be feisty as well. Oh, he can. He can. But he's like the human feist of neoclassical economics. It doesn't deserve having a human feist.
Starting point is 02:52:18 It's anti-human theory. But he's the real thing. I got you. All right. So, so, but the credit does not have any effect on aggregate demand in their model. And you're saying that's not the case at all. It's absolutely crucial to aggregate demand. So what they model is, again, the example of you lending to me or Varsavirsa, if I lend
Starting point is 02:52:39 money to you, I can spend less, you can spend more. Okay. So credit credit is the change in debt. So if there's, if I've been money to you, then there's a level of private debt rises. Okay. So there's an increase in credit, but that increase in credit comes at an expense of my spending power. So you can spend what I've lent you, but I can't spend what I've lent you. So credit cancels out. But when you look at, that's learnable funds. But in the real world, and the Bank of England has said this is the real world, and the six books are wrong, categorically, in 2014, when the bank lens, it adds to its asset side,
Starting point is 02:53:17 and it says, you owe us more money, and it adds to its liability side, and says, here's the money in your bank account. Now, you spend that money. So what happens when you do your sums, credit is part of aggregate demand and aggregate income. And that's something I first solved in 2019, I think, 2000. It's only recently proved it mathematically. So what that means is credit is a component of aggregate demand and credit is also very volatile. So like consumption demand never goes negative. Investment demand never goes negative, but credit can go from positive to negative. When you take a look at the long run of American history after the Second World War, there was no period until 2007 where credit was negative.
Starting point is 02:54:02 It was a positive component of your positive number. And therefore, when you do it as a percentage of GDP, it was a positive percentage of GDP. It piqued at 16% of GDP in 2006, 2007. It fell to minus 5% in 2008, 2009. So you had a 20% of GDP turn around an aggregate demand. Now when you plot that against unemployment, the correlation of credit to unemployment across the period from about 1990 to 2010 is about minus point nine. Okay. An enormous negative correlation.
Starting point is 02:54:45 Now according to the classical circuit to be slow to zero, empirically, it's bleedingly obvious it's not, and it applies to every country in the world that had a financial crisis at that period. So it's bleedingly obvious in the data, and they ignore it because credit's not part of their model. And you're saying it's causation.
Starting point is 02:55:04 Of course I guess. It's causal. Today we sit there as extremely high inflation. What does inflation, what role does inflation play in this picture? It's a little bit of inflation good. Yeah. We talked about money creation at the beginning.
Starting point is 02:55:23 What's a little bit of inflation good or bad, a lot of inflation good or bad, how concerned are you about? A little bit is good for a simple reason. Like again, it's taken me while I get my head around this. But if you think about how people say, what are the functions of money? They say money, it's a unit of count, account, it's a measuring.
Starting point is 02:55:40 It's a means of exchange, and it's a store of value. Now, yes, okay, it has those three roles, but the last one is contradictory to the previous two. This is where you see this with a Bitcoin phenomenon. If you want to hang on to money as a store of value, then if prices are falling, the value of money is rising. And it's actually in your interest, there's a store of value to hang onto it and not spend it.
Starting point is 02:56:10 So that contradicts its role as a means of exchange. Now, if you have money which depreciates, and this was actually tried in the Austrian town of Wargold during the second, before the during the Great Depression, if you have money that depreciates, then if you don't use it, you'll lose it fundamentally. So it has a high rate of circulation. So there's a monetary theorist called Silvio Gazelle, and he wrote this proposal that money should depreciate. And he was ridiculed and opposed and derided by Cain said he was a great intellect. And the mayor of town of Wargall in Austria during the Great Depression was facing an
Starting point is 02:56:51 unemployment rate now 25% pretty much. Germany had the worst experience in the Great Depression in the world, because as bad as America is slightly worse than America. And so he thought, how can I stimulate demand here? So he produced a script which could only be used for buying goods and services in Wargall. America. And so you thought, how can I stimulate demand here? So if you're used to script, which could only be used for buying goods and services in Walgill and could be used to pay your local rights, but it was depreciated by putting a stamp on the money if you didn't use it. So what happened was people would pay their rights, they needed to pay the rights
Starting point is 02:57:20 using this money, so the script, so they used the script. And because it depreciated, you'd use it rapidly. So people were using that money, this alternative to the Austrian shelling. And the economic activity in town took off, and unemployment fell to zero. And it was an absolute miracle, and maybe it loved a wargall experiment, and the Austrian Central Bank sued them for establishing an alternative form of money and shut it down. I'm going back up to 25% again and Austria voted, you know, not 99.6% for the Nazis, something crazy number like that when Hitler marched in.
Starting point is 02:57:58 So the wargill experiment showed that a depreciating currency led to a high rate of circulation, but of course we're not talking via our republic levels of inflation. So when you get that much inflation, and that's normally caused by, as the one-hour inflation was caused by, the reparation terms imposed on Germany, fundamentally by France, at the Treaty of Versailles, they paid a large part of that with just basically printing the notes, and you went into this crazy period of hyperinflation.
Starting point is 02:58:30 So hyperinflation almost always occurs when there's a massive destruction of physical resources. And the monetary authority tries to paper literally over it, and then you get hyperinflation at total social breakdown. So a moderate level of inflation inspires the means of exchange uses your money, but undermines the store of value usage of money. And that dilemma is why we have this antagonistic attitude towards inflation. Carming is attention, but it's nevertheless is like money is the store value and it means of exchange.
Starting point is 02:59:08 And I don't, you know, to push back, it's not necessarily that there's attention. It's just that depending on the dynamics of this beautiful economic system of ours, it's used as one more than the other. If there's inflation, you're using it more for the means of exchange, it's deflation using more for store value, but that doesn't, I don't see there's a tension, that's just how much you use it for those different. The bid ends up saying the overall level of effective corners, a bit of inflation is a good thing because that's depreciating the money slightly and encourages use.
Starting point is 02:59:47 Yeah, but so the argument that it's a Bitcoin folks use or gold standard. Hotels. Yeah. The hot. Yeah. The hot again, hotels not an argument. Is that having an inflation of zero is actually achieving that balance. Yeah, so like, yeah, but if they're actually in favor of negative, they wanted to appreciate rapidly. There's a particularly negative inflation,
Starting point is 03:00:13 that the value of the money rising relative to commodities, that's what they want, that's the huddle philosophy. Well, that's more of like an investment. I don't know if that philosophy. Well, that's more of like an investment. I don't know if that, yeah, that's more of investment philosophy than the fundamental principles of why they believe in cryptocurrency and enforce scarcity. So model the concern there is that when you print money, the public policies detach from the actual from value. Yeah, well, you get, I mean, this is where again, it matters to get money creation right, because the government's not the only money creator banks are as well, private banks. And if we obsess too much about limiting government money creation, what we end up getting, if there is money creation going, that's private banks doing it, and you get an increase in private debt,
Starting point is 03:01:05 and fundamentally private debt and its collapse. It collapse of credit when it stops growing. That's the fundamental cause of financial crises. So here, but the question is, what's the cost of the collapse of the... Well, I think this is like the Austrian thinking leaves out the debt deflation. And that's like, I think one of the most important papers ever written was by Irving Fischer, called the debt deflation theory of great depressions.
Starting point is 03:01:35 Fischer was somebody who accepted the Neoclassical Vision. He wrote the pre-efficiency market hypothesis, of market hypothesis, Ephesians market hypothesis, he had his own PhD called the Theory of Interest. And in that he argued, effectively for a supply and demand analysis of the financial system. And he argued for equilibrium. He said, when you're working with a commodity market, then the sale and the transaction and the exchange occur at the same point in time. When you're working with the financial market, then the exchange occurs through time.
Starting point is 03:02:15 So he said he assumed that debts are repaid, all debts are repaid, and he assumed that equilibrium through time was an essential part of his assumption. And then the great depression comes along and he has become a major shareholder in Rank Zerox because he invented the Rolladex. He's a tinkerer. And so he had taken out shares on margin and he was worth about 100 million in modern terms when the great depression hit and 90% of that was share market valuation he'd taken out margin debt just like everybody else and with margin debt you could put down a hundred thousand dollars and buy a million dollars worth of shares. huge leverage into debt. Now that when the financial crisis hit the level of margin debt in America had risen from half a percent of GDP in 1920 to 13 percent of GDP in 1929. It then fell
Starting point is 03:03:14 to zero again. That's why the stock market crash in 1929 was so devastating. That's scale of margin lending. And everybody's being wiped out. They were selling roles, roosters for 20 quid. You know, that would literally have photographed showing people doing that because a margin call comes in, you've got to liquidate everything. Okay, so you said the danger is of a debt deflation is what we have to avoid. Okay, and that means you don't want too much private debt to accumulate and you don't want falling prices because the falling prices will amplify the impact of being in solvent to begin with.
Starting point is 03:03:50 And that's what we saw in the Great Depression, it's partially what we saw in 2007, but we didn't have anything like the level of margin debt. Margin debt was reduced from 90% to 50% ratio after the Great Depression. So there were limits on how bad it was in 2007. But the danger is still the period of deflation amplifies your debts. I call it fissures paradox. He didn't write those terms himself, but he wrote a line saying, the more debt is pay, the more they owe. This is because you're liquidating to try to meet your own debts. When you liquidate the price level falls, you will end up having a lower level of monetary
Starting point is 03:04:33 debt, but a higher level of debt when you deflate it using the price level. So the biggest danger in capitalism is the debt deflation, far more dangerous than inflation. And the cause of debt deflation is too much lending, too much bank lending, too much private money creation. And if you take a look at the 1920s, Calvin Coolidge explained the boom of the 1920s on his surplus. He said, my government running a surplus of 1% of GDP, pretty much from 1922 through to 1930, is the foundation of our stability.
Starting point is 03:05:06 It should be continued. What he didn't look at was that over that same time period, on average, Americans were borrowing 5 percent of GDP per year from the private banks. So you had a housing bubble at the beginning of the 1920s, which Richard vague covers beautifully in the brief history of Doom. And then you had this huge rise in margin debt as well, gigantic increase in margin debt. So all this borrowed money was being spent into the economy. And this is where credit becomes part of aggregate demand. And it's both not just for goods and services, it's also for shares and houses
Starting point is 03:05:40 and so on. So a huge valuation effect. But then when the margin debt turned around, I mean, people would not take out margin debt anymore, the demand from margin debt disappeared, and then it was a, you know, what we call badly a positive feedback loop is actually an amplifying feedback loop. And that caused a collapse. So what elements of that DC today that we need to fix and how do we fix it? We have to regard the level of private debt as a target of economic policy, just as much as the rate of inflation or the rate of unemployment. How do what is the moderate amount of private debt that's good?
Starting point is 03:06:16 I would say something of you, anywhere between 30 and 70% of GDP. What is it currently? In America it's 170%. Nice. Of GDP. Of GDP. Oh, it currently? In America, it's 170% of GDP. Object, E.P. Oh, earth for nice. I've got the data in this, and it's just this huge increase in private debt. First of all, it caused the boom, but then financing the credit causes, ultimately causes the slump. And so if we remove the rate level at which debt can reach and we stop speculative lending
Starting point is 03:06:51 and base-have-a-lending for both innovation, invest investment and essential consumption items, we won't have the slump on the other side. We can get rid of financial instability. We can't stop financial cycles, but we can stop financial breakdown. So we should really be focused on the stability of getting can we can get rid of financial instability we can't stop financial cycles but we can stop financial breakdown. So we should really be focusing on the stability and getting that up to control. By the way as you point to your laptop my laptops have a lot of how many computers do I have by the lot of them but my little surface whatever the heck this thing is is getting definite size envy is your laptop you said is 18 something
Starting point is 03:07:25 I didn't point for inches 18 point four inches you know I don't think I've ever seen one that big and I'll give the internet that one all right that's for the graphics so it's the gaming laptop it's just the desktop probably weighs like 40 pounds. You have to... Eight kilos? Eight kilos. Let's see if you reckon eight or... Oh wow, okay, yeah. Eight kilos, that's... You're pushing the power supply forward? So over there somewhere.
Starting point is 03:07:53 The power supply weighs about twice as much as your laptop. Yeah, and you have to power it on with the crank. Pretty close to like pull. Is it gas powered or is it cold? Oh, well, it's a nuclear power station and the power. Nuclear, yeah, nuclear, the dominant in the back then. Okay, so let me before I forget, just let me ask you about, we've covered brilliantly the, the nuance, disagreements you have and the wisdom you've drawn from Karl Marx, but there's also,
Starting point is 03:08:27 you've drawn from Karl Marx, but there's also, like you mentioned in popular discourse, a kind of distorted use of different terms. And one of them is Marxism today. Is there something you could just speak to about increased use of that word? And is it misused? Does it concern you that there's a lot of actually young people that say they're sort of proudly Marxist? Yeah. Are they misusing the term?
Starting point is 03:08:51 They are definitely misusing the term if they don't understand the use value, exchange value, dialectic, or went through earlier. So, if I could... And they don't. If I could just pause, the idea of socialism and Marxism is used in sort of popular effectage. And nice, John. And nice. And nice, John. Effective pause. The idea of socialism and Marxism is used in sort of popular lingo. Yeah. It's basically, you know, a lot of people have a disproportionately hard life.
Starting point is 03:09:16 Why can't we help them out? Why can't we be kind to our fellow man kind of that's a short embodiment of an idea as opposed to some super complicated, elaborate model of the economy and politics. We could do that by using the insights that come out of modern monetary theory, which I've confirmed just using my simple miniskie models. That is to use the term, you use the feature not a bug, a government running a deficit is a feature of a well functioning mixed, fee, fee it, credit economy, not a bug. The government should normally run a deficit because that's how the government creates money. Now, because we've had this obsession from mainstream
Starting point is 03:09:59 economists of running a surplus, which is what caused the Great Depression, the Calvin Kool is doing it for eight years, because of that obsession with cutback on social services, with cutback on health, with cutback on education, with cutback on infrastructure. Now, all that stuff predominantly affects the poor, because the rich can afford to buy it themselves. So, if we had a son of a bitch realised the government should run a deficit, it's a feature, not a bug, a fee-at-money system. And that's where Eons made one mistake recently.
Starting point is 03:10:28 I'm not going back to the first principles. That deficit enables you to provide enough of a decent standard of living for those who don't come out on top of the capitalist game. And with that, you wouldn't have the angst of the young people. Now, we still have the climate parameters within which we have to survive. But a decent level of government funding would mean the angst that you get, people say, I want to be a Marxist, and they've got what I call a cardboard cutout version of Marx in their minds, that wouldn't be happening. So it's
Starting point is 03:11:01 it's potential to have a good society where the government runs a deficit that finances the needs of the poor, where the rich get enough to, you know, and dollars will take care of themselves. And you don't get this breakdown. If you try to cause the government running a surplus, then the burden of that is borne by the poor, middle class and poor, and that will lead to the angst we're now saying. Beautiful. That was a beautiful world-wind exploration of all of economics and economics history. Let me ask you, well, you tweeted, I think. We are the opposite of ants, individually intelligent,
Starting point is 03:11:42 collectively stupid. We need to develop systems thinking fast to counter our limitations. That's really interesting. Do you really believe we're individually intelligent and collectively stupid? I do. Can you elaborate on, I mean, some of that is just cheeky tweets.
Starting point is 03:12:02 But, it's a cheeky tweet I've had from my mind for a long time. It's just, it's one that actually went moderately viral, not enough, but moderately viral for me. But nevertheless, what if you could analyze it as if it's some deep profound thing you made in a book? Well, the reason is that we are, they can credibly, individually, intelligent things like these devices we're playing with now.
Starting point is 03:12:23 That's the creation of individual minds. Create individual minds in a collective labor of a century is the leads to this level of technology. And that has to be respected. It's incredible stuff. But at the same time, I think what humans are, if you wanted to distinguish humans from other species on the planet, we don't weave webs. Okay.
Starting point is 03:12:42 We don't make bird calls. What we do is we share beliefs. Now you don't think that's a catalyst for intelligence. Yeah, it is a catalyst, but what it means is we can dilute ourselves as much as we can inform ourselves. So because we share beliefs, we can do things in a collective way. And if we believe that if we take the incantations of the witch doctors and we, and we happen to have a couple of spears and things we can go and attack the local hurt the tribe of, of, of, of, of, of
Starting point is 03:13:15 lines and drive them out, and we become the dominant species. So it worked at the stage where we were in competition with other species on the planet. Now that we're the dominant species, then our beliefs get in the way. So you agree with Einstein who said, the only, there are only two things they're infinite, the universe and human's stupidity. And he wasn't sure about the universe. And he wasn't sure about the universe. Right. That's right. He wasn't sure about the universe. Yeah, so you think that the collective, I mean, there's an affinity to the destructive and the stupid, the inhumane that's possible when we humans get together. But it feels like there's more trajectories, there's more possibility for creation.
Starting point is 03:14:00 There are. I think that's why we have to say, if we built around the idea that our role as a species is to maintain and extend life on the planet and if not find it elsewhere then see it elsewhere. Yeah. Then that is a vision which makes us creative and confines the worst elements of our capacities to share beliefs. So that's what I, my hope is, that we'll reach that stage, but I think
Starting point is 03:14:26 we've overshot it so badly that my real fear is we'll end up blaming technology for the type of world we find ourselves living in in the next 20 to 50 years. So you think technology is going to be one of the part of the solution? Part of the solution, yeah, but it's, but if we go through and blame it, which is quite possible, we will blame the technology rather than blaming too much of the technology and the too much comes down to what economists have told us, that we can just continue consuming infinitely on a finite planet. And Kenneth Bowling said that beautifully, said the, if somebody believes that you can have exponential growth on a finite planet,
Starting point is 03:15:02 they were either mad or they were an economist. So you're, you made a long journey for which I'm deeply honored from, from Sydney. There's distant places. Yeah, activities. There's myth. You've got a guy there one day. You'd enjoy it. I will. I'm afraid if I go there, I will stay forever. And so, no, it's a bit too, there's more vitality back in this economy, so you'd come back. Okay, maybe, you know, I'm not a fan of the economy or money or any of that nature calls me. Let me, so I'm out of the, you make that trip. You've also said that while you're here in Austin,
Starting point is 03:15:42 you're going to go to this American factory that makes cars here in Austin and also visit Starbase. So let me ask you about expanding out into the universe. Is that something that that excites you? Yeah. You mentioned about the economics of it. Do you think, what do you think Marx would think about this? Economically speaking, what is this? Is it a good thing? I think it's vital. We can have capitalism and outer space.
Starting point is 03:16:16 Far more successfully than we can have it on the planet. Because we don't face when we dump the waste ends up in the sun, not a problem. So it means the potential. We don't undermine our own productive capacity if we're doing it now to space. So the destructive element of waste has a lesser impact in our system? Yes, I mean, it cares that we throw a bit of our eye and back into the sun again. I take a fair bit of it to turn it into a, what would be the next stage, it would be
Starting point is 03:16:42 a red giant. And we have to get away because there's a red giant at some stage, it'll the sun will hit up past the orbit of Mars, I think, certainly past the orbit of Earth. So to have longevity of just human life, the life that evolved on this planet, we have to be able to take it off planet ultimately. So if you think in the really long term, then it's our responsibility, we're going to maintain life, is to establish life off the planet. What do you think about robots and AI as part of the expanding our entity? Oh, yeah, we have to. I mean, you can't go for it. You can't go for it, you know, you can't go for it, you know, you can't be, you can't be from here
Starting point is 03:17:25 to the asteroid built and back again for dinner with your family. So production would be entirely mechanized. There'd be, you have to be a handful of people who service the machines, but. So it's about production and automation. What about elements of consciousness that make humans so special?
Starting point is 03:17:42 What about that persisting within the machine? That, I mean, I'm still a skeptic about us ever being able to create a machine which is truly conscious. If I can throw my, it's almost too sensual. That would really piss off Karl Marx, by the way. If we create machines that are conscious. Exactly. This is actually both part of the, there's two good logical arguments against the labor theory of value. One of what it becomes machines become intelligent.
Starting point is 03:18:03 And the other was that if the, the climbing rate of profit applies in socialism, it'll apply as a rate of accumulation and sorry, in capitalism, it'll apply as a rate of socialism as well. I got co-co-co-cullied, made that argument. His argument was just unsound. But yeah, intelligent machines would completely screw marks up. But do you not like that world where machines have not only intelligence, but their soul is just this. I know that's one of your interests, one of your potential endeavors, and the cuts will
Starting point is 03:18:37 I do that there's some singularity we're approaching as we just get an increasing processing power. It's not processing power, it's imagination. And I think whatever the heck that means. Whatever the heck that means. Yeah, I mean, you would have had imaginative insights. So your papers on like in automating, motoring between the hyper intelligent machine or the machine here in interface where the standards can be lower for the machine and higher for the human. Okay, that's an insight you would have had at some point and then you've worked it further. So I've had insights like that as well and I have no idea where they come from. They just hit me in their head and I spright them down and they solve the problems that I didn't
Starting point is 03:19:16 even know my mind was working on. Okay. So how can we get a machine to do that? And I do not know the answer, but one thing I think is the potential, so I think we have to create AI that has feelings, AI that wants to survive, because if you think how our intelligence evolved, it's on this planet in a struggle between predator and prey, and intelligent became a survival technique.
Starting point is 03:19:43 I find the ideas of Ernest Bakcker with denial of death really powerful, which is that humans will not only have emotions and are trying to survive, they're able to ponder out in the distant future their mortality. And that is a driving force for even greater creation that animals are able to do. Yeah. More, more, more primitive animals. And so there is some element where I agree with you,
Starting point is 03:20:17 I think, for AI systems to have something like consciousness, they have to fear their mortality. Exactly. And I think that's, if you do it then, you can't produce an AI whose behavior you can control. I mean, when you have kids, yeah, you can't control their behavior. You know, that's the trade-off.
Starting point is 03:20:41 You give life to an anarchist. Like one of my favorite instances in my family life as a one of my fate my one of my my my I like all my nurses and and their fees but one's got a real quick to her and I was standing over her cot when she was literally like about six months old and she was gogling away to herself and a father waked his fingers and stopped making that. And this little six month old kid goes, this is the, and I said, boy, you're going to have issues with that one night. Yeah.
Starting point is 03:21:11 And she had her kiss was born. Yeah. And so you can't control this life you give birth to. And that's, I think that's the right of AI. Terrifying and exciting. It is. And I think we should take that risk at some stage. But I think to do it with what actually
Starting point is 03:21:24 let artificial intelligence involve in a environment And I think we should take that risk at some stage, but I think to do it with what actually let artificial intelligence involve in us environment in which it fears its own death. Yeah. Yeah. I think there's a lot of beauty there, but it's there's also a lot of fear, a lot of destruction that's possible. So you have to be extremely careful. But that's kind of the cutting edge of which we'll often operate as a humanity. Let me ask you for advice. Can you give advice to young people in high school and college? Maybe they're interested in economics.
Starting point is 03:21:57 Maybe they have other career ideas. What advice would you give them about a career that can have that they can be proud of or a life that can be proud of? Mainly in a career I say don't do an economics degree. Okay. I say if you can. There's a little book. Econ comics. Econ comics taking the con out of economics.
Starting point is 03:22:21 So they should start with that and then say screw it to an economics degree. Yeah, because what you learn is an obsolete technology. Learning economics at a university is like learning to all make astronomy. Okay, the Earth's centric equilibrium, you know, epipsychols being added to make your models fit the data. So it's not that economics is not a discipline worth deeply studying. It's that the university education around economics is so bad is bad.
Starting point is 03:22:50 Yeah. So I'd say learn system dynamics to a course in system dynamics, which you can apply in any field and then apply what you learn out of system dynamics to the issues of economics. That's what interests you. So get a sort of base engineering education, the base engineering education, that is far better than doing an economics degree. In terms of life, my life is pretty chaotic in many, many ways. My friends and family will tell me that every opportunity. But the thing is, I once had this, I'll tell you an example
Starting point is 03:23:22 of a really funny incident that occurred to me because I let the student revolt at Sydney University, as I mentioned, was 20 years old. And then in my, like about 28 or so, I went to a restaurant one night and I found a bunch of guys, all guys, who done accounting at the university, but also been part of the student revolt. So they hadn't seen me for about a decade and they said to what I've been doing, Steve, and I talked about what I'd done. So I've been a school teacher for a while. I then worked in overseas aid. I was doing computer programming at this time.
Starting point is 03:23:51 And I've forgotten what also I was doing at that point. So I explained it to all of them. And they were at a Bucks night, one of them having a wedding, you know, coming up the next week. And one of them said, I wish I'd done that. And there was silence around the table. It was obviously silent agreement. And I looked at them and said, hang on guys, look at the downside of my life. You know, like, you're getting married. I don't have a girlfriend right now.
Starting point is 03:24:16 You've all got secure jobs. I'm unemployed, okay. I don't know, you own a house, haven't you got a car? You know, look at the downside of my life. And the bloke was the kingpin of that group. They're very innovative bunch of guys in the student revolts. So you said, Steve, we would still all rather have done what you have done. And they did accounting because it was safe.
Starting point is 03:24:38 You always get a job. It was, it was bored shitless. Did you have a sense that the chaos you're always jumping into was dangerous or was it just the pull, pull of it that I simply couldn't not do it. Yeah. It was part of me that I couldn't swallow this economic stuff. Once I was exposed to what was so wrong, then I was on a, on a crusade to make it right. And that's been part of my natural through my life.
Starting point is 03:25:07 I don't know why. So it wasn't that I made a choice to do it is that I couldn't be true to myself without doing it. And I find a lot of people get caught in a life where they're doing it because it works for some financial or other reason, but they're not being true to themselves. And as messy as my life is,
Starting point is 03:25:23 much shit I've got myself caught up in. And there's a lot of that in my personal and financial life right now, which is a pain in the ass. I would rather have had that nature than not. You would rather take the pain in the ass. Yeah. No, it's not. Yeah. Let me ask a dark question. What's the darkest place you've ever gone to in your mind? So in all that rollercoaster of life, have there been periods or has been really... I've had to cope with depression in the last five years
Starting point is 03:25:55 since I started reading neoclassical economist on climate change. Sorry, tell me. I'll come back to that one. So that's where my wife's gonna come into this story. So I was reading Richard Tull, a paper from 2009 called The Economics of Climate Change, Journal of Economic Perspectives, I think. And I read this section where he says that one of the ways they try to calibrate what
Starting point is 03:26:18 climate change was due is they assumed that the relationship between GDP and temperature over space would apply over time as well. Yes. And I read that and thought that is so fucking stupid. What I was all it's saying is that if there's a 10 degree temperature difference between New York and Florida and a 20% difference in income, then a 10 degree increase in temperature will cause GDP by 4 by 20%.
Starting point is 03:26:43 It is so insanely stupid. So when that read that line, I just did this. I was in shock at how stupid it was. My wife who's Thai and brings in treats for me all day, walks into the room and says, and she speaks in a staccato English and says to me, why do you like this? And I said, I'm just doing this work on climate change. And she interrupts me and says, oh, why you do that stuff. Nobody is interested in climate change. You can't do anything to change it. If we die, we die. And that person, perfect Buddhist grounding. And I thought, well, I can't argue with her again. So that sort of stopped me on the
Starting point is 03:27:26 depression, but that's the darkest point when I've looked at and I thought that there's arrogance, there's stupidity, there's humbug, and the economists meant that we were potentially jeopardizing the lives of billions of people and Christ knows how many other life forms. And having that knowledge is the most depressing experience of my life. That ideas, simple models combined with arrogance can lead to the potential destruction of human civilization. That was a very heavy, and then your wife came in with the nature, nature wins in the end. Yeah, and that sort of accepts the flow of life. You should really enjoy that book, The Earth of Odds, because it's got that same beautiful sense to it. Life will survive whatever we do. I mean, they talk about the people, I was
Starting point is 03:28:20 actually talking with a good mate of mine, an ex-geologist and he's now a professor of economics, and he's there a professor of economics. And he said as a geologist, he really hated people talking about the Anthropocene epoch. And I said, well, it shouldn't be the Anthropocene epoch, it'll be the Anthropocene event. Because an epoch is millions of years and a huge period of life on the planet.
Starting point is 03:28:42 And we might be snuffed out in 10,000 years of human civilization. And that's not much slower than the meteors wiping out the dinosaurs. The dinosaurs lasted for a long time after that event. So we're like, we just be a layer in the surface of the planet with plastics and strange metals like that at some point. So we're just gonna eat, but life will abide, life will survive us. But there's so much life we're gonna take down with us in this whole period. And there's so many of our own lives we're gonna terminate
Starting point is 03:29:16 for no good reason. I'm looking at this, which your tall character, I'll definitely have to look at some of his papers. It does look like Boy is the oversimplifying and do a lot of my god. Check his one on the anthra on the how good it'll be to lose I'm okay. That said, I'm going to Approach all these topics with humility and I would like to have some conversations if people can recommend My default position is always with the scientists if people can recommend. My default position is always with the scientists, but even above that, my default position is with those who are humble versus those who are arrogant.
Starting point is 03:29:50 Yeah. This idea that because you're a quote unquote expert, you deserve to have arrogance is a silly idea to me. Again, going to the broader view of life on earth. Yeah. Nature. Nature's the only one that gets to be arrogant, and it doesn't need, it chooses not to. So, let me ask you about love. What role does love play in this whole thing? The Karl Marx of a model for that. Oh, Marx is madly in love with Genevon Westellan.
Starting point is 03:30:22 I wrote a love poetry to her, along with four-yearot, Das Kapital. And he was infatuated with her. He ended up also impregnating his housekeeper. So there's a son of Karl Marx, who was the son of the housekeeper, not the Jenny. They're numerous daughters. So he had a complicated view of love.
Starting point is 03:30:44 Oh yeah. There's a dialect view of love. Oh yeah. There's a dialectic on love there. He had an idealistic view with Jenny. And he was rejected because he wasn't not by Jenny. She was madly in love with him as well. So it was a real passionate love affair from the very outset. But then of course, you have children, lots of them die. There's a huge amount of tragedy in his life as well.
Starting point is 03:31:06 He and Jenny were forced out of Chelsea by a cholera epidemic. My vision for London back in the 1850s and 60s was Calcutta in the 1970s. That's really what life was like. So there's a lot of hardship in his life as well. And he was always poor. So, you know, only Ingalls kept him alive financially. He applied for one job outside of... He never got an academic job.
Starting point is 03:31:37 He was pushed out of Prussia as a newspaper author. But he also applied for a job as a clerk in the British Railway system, has turned out they couldn't read his handwriting. So, I think I've got a bit similar there. So, yeah, there's a lot of love and passion. But in general, what do you think is the draw of love and the human condition? It's vital.
Starting point is 03:32:01 That feeling of passion, desire and respect for somebody else, and there's perverted forms of love as well, so I'll leave that out. But somebody having a really deep bond which goes beyond just sexual attraction. I look, I've had that four or five times in my life with different women at different times, and I've stuffed up the most important one very early on. And that feeling is incredible. And you couldn't have life worth living without that. So it's an essential part of who we are.
Starting point is 03:32:39 But what we have to do is to transfer it not just to the rest of our species, but to all the species. And that's, I think, what's vital and how do we maintain that over generations? And I think that that idea that we can actually hang on to that general sense of respect and not lose it again, because the amount of life we've terminated on this planet, the warlike side of humanity, that is too much of a defining feature of our species. It's the opposite of love, it's hate, but it's pleasure and inflicting pain on others when you see people killing others in a warlike environment. They were enjoying
Starting point is 03:33:15 themselves. It's rarely, sometimes it's self-defense, but there's, when you've talked about people who've been involved in combat and being involved in riots and said When you see somebody riding bashing people up, they're enjoying themselves. It's not anger. They're feeling this pleasure Yeah, there's a dark aspect of human nature very dark, but there's also the capacity To rise above that and I think I put us on a spectrum between chimpanzees at one extreme and binobos at the other We're too close spectrum between chimpanzees that want extreme and binobos at the other. We're too close to the chimpanzees. You know.
Starting point is 03:33:48 And binobos are just having fun, having lots of sex. Every time they do anything, they fuck first and do the work later and then fuck afterwards to celebrate, you know. Fuck first, ask questions later. It's like that sense of a woman, one of my favorite films where Al Pacino gives advice to a cat. He says, one in doubt, fuck. It's good life advice for a cat especially.
Starting point is 03:34:11 We mentioned that death seems to be maybe fundamental to creating a conscious AI. All right, do you think about your own death? Do you, are you afraid of it? I'm afraid of going through it. I'm the other side. You're not afraid of being on the other side. I don't think there is another side. I'm agnostic. I'm atheist when pressed and agnostic. The one thing that I think I can understand why religion exists is that the whole thing that something exists is itself a dilemma. You have to take on faith that reality exists, whether it's a simulation or actual reality, it exists, and that itself can't be explained in any scientific manner.
Starting point is 03:34:56 I mean, you can talk about anti-protons and protons and the some being zero and so on, but why did it even happen in the first place? So there's part you simply have to take on faith. So there was darkness before? We don't know. And there's darkness after. Yeah, and I don't know if they're going to be alive on the other side of that darkness, I think individually, no. But the way you can live on is by what you do to human consciousness. How do you hope people remember you?
Starting point is 03:35:23 How do you hope people remember you? As someone who managed to integrate economics with an appreciation for life? Well I have to say, as a bit of a callback, you're one deadly bastard. It's a huge honor that you would come down and talk to me. You're a brilliant person, you would come down and talk to me. You're a brilliant person, you're a hilarious person, the humility shines through the brilliant shines through. Thank you so much. Well, thank you, Lex. So you do the same for humanity. I mean, when you, when I saw that email from you, my eyes popped out on my head. Okay. Well, you should hold your judgment. I gotta show
Starting point is 03:35:59 you the sex dungeon I have. You'll, you'll, you'll be waiting for an invitation. I'll send my wife over. Awesome. Can't wait. All right. I can't wait. Thanks for listening to this conversation with Steve Keane. To support this podcast, please check out our sponsors in the description. And now, let me leave you some words from Karl Marx. To be radical is to grasp things at their root. Thank you for listening and hope to see you next time. you

There aren't comments yet for this episode. Click on any sentence in the transcript to leave a comment.