Planet Money - Tariffs: what are they good for?
Episode Date: April 2, 2025What are tariffs good for?For years, mainstream economists have basically said: tariffs are not good. They are an import tax paid by consumers, they've said, and they discourage free trade, and we wan...t more! Because free trade has broadly led to more global economic growth.But global trade hasn't been all positive for Americans, and in the worldview of President Trump's administration, tariffs can be used to right some of those wrongs. And the U.S. has economic leverage. So if the U.S. wants to level the playing field, it should use that leverage, and use tariffs to accomplish its policy goals.Today on the show: the case for tariffs. We talk to a lonely economist who's been sounding the alarm for years that more and free-er trade isn't always better. And we speak to economists in President Trump's orbit who make the case for how tariffs can be a potent economic and political tool.This episode was produced by Willa Rubin and edited by Meg Cramer. It was fact-checked by Sarah McClure and engineered by James Willetts. Alex Goldmark is our executive producer. Find more Planet Money: Facebook / Instagram / TikTok / Our weekly Newsletter.Listen free at these links: Apple Podcasts, Spotify, the NPR app or anywhere you get podcasts.Help support Planet Money and hear our bonus episodes by subscribing to Planet Money+ in Apple Podcasts or at plus.npr.org/planetmoney.Music: Universal Music Production: "Funky Reverie" and "With It;" Audio Network - "Slush Puppy Soul."Learn more about sponsor message choices: podcastchoices.com/adchoicesNPR Privacy Policy
Transcript
Discussion (0)
This message comes from the BBC with Good Bad Billionaire. How do the richest
people on the planet make their money? Good Bad Billionaire is back for a third
season to lift the curtain on billionaires from LeBron James to Martha
Stewart. Search for Good Bad Billionaire from BBC podcasts. This is Planet Money
from NPR. Today is a big day.
For weeks, we have been hearing about April 2nd.
The Trump administration had promised that today would be the day that they put new
tariffs on goods coming in from, I don't know, maybe every country in the world.
This is one of the most important days, in my opinion, in American history.
It's our Declaration of Economic Independence.
The looming tariffs had sent chills down the spines of many economists around the world.
Because tariffs, they're an old economic tool that many economists have disliked for a very long time.
They're basically an import tax, paid mostly by consumers.
And for centuries they've been used to make a country's population buy its own stuff,
instead of another country's stuff.
But economists generally prefer more and freer trade, because it means more competition, lower
prices, economic growth. A bedrock theory in economics is the theory of comparative advantage, that
basically countries can specialize in different things and through trade we can all, in the
aggregate, get richer.
But surely tariffs have been useful ever, or they wouldn't exist, right? Right? Hello,
and welcome to Planet Money. I'm Mary Childs.
And I'm Greg Rosalski. Today on the show, the case for tariffs. What can they be good
for?
We talk to an economist who has been making the lonely argument for protectionism for
the past 30 years.
And we hear how tariffs fit into President Trump's economic worldview from two economists
in the orbit of the Trump administration.
Support for this podcast and the following message come from Dignity Memorial.
In life, you plan for many important things like weddings, retirement, and your children's
education.
A celebration of life
is really no different. Planning and paying for your celebration of life in advance protects
your loved ones and gives you the peace of mind you deserve. It's truly one of the
best gifts you can give your family. Dignity Memorial will help you take care of every
detail with professionalism and compassion. For additional information, visit DignityMemorial.com.
So, tariffs. We have long heard from economists about how and why they are bad. Today, we
investigate what they can actually do, what they can be good for.
And yeah, economists have always acknowledged that free trade has trade-offs, that, you
know, there will be losers in the face of foreign competition. But for a long time,
the dominant voices in the profession made the case that those trade-offs were really worth it.
Top lawmakers in both parties in the US really bought into this idea that free trade would be
great for America, and they really pushed it for the rest of the world.
And through the decades of that argument, there's been an economist who argued that
the dominant voices in economics were wrong.
That free trade actually sometimes held countries back, and protectionism could help make them
richer.
Hi, I'm Ha-Joon Chang.
I'm a professor of economics at the University of London.
Ha-Joon Chang wrote a book called Kicking Away the Ladder in 2002 about how rich countries
used protectionist policies like tariffs back when they were developing and then told everyone
else they couldn't do that.
They had to do free trade.
And being a pro-tariff economist back in the early 2000s, it was kind of lonely.
Are you a fan of The Lord of the Rings?
I love Lord of the Rings.
Yeah, the second movie, there's this scene of battle at Helm's Deep.
You're a band of, I don't know, 120 super capable guys, yeah?
But then there are like half a million orcs in front of you.
What are you going to do, yeah?
A battle against half a million free trade
economists. That's how unpopular he felt. But he's got kind of the perfect example
of why tariffs can work.
My favorite example is Hyundai, the automobile company.
When Ha-Joon was a little kid growing up in South Korea, Hyundai was not yet an automobile
company. Hyundai originally was a construction company,
but sometime in the late 60s, this company decided that they wanted to build an automobile
manufacturing business. So first, Hyundai had to figure out how to make a car. Ha Joon says it
started by placing an order with Ford for something called a knockdown kit,
which is just a big wooden box full of all the parts
you could ever need to build one car.
The box arrives, you open it up,
and it's just full of car parts, large and small.
A door, a bolt, two headlights.
They assembled around 3,000 of those cars in the late 60s. And then in the mid 70s,
South Korean government said, we are going to cancel the license for automobile manufacturers
unless they come up with their own design. Yeah, the government was like, actually,
we want our car industry to be real companies, global players. Assembling a Ford car is not our end goal here. Can you
level up a little bit?
So Hyundai had to come out with their own design. In 1976, it made the Hyundai Pony.
It was the first Korean passenger car. They made around 10,000 of them in a year.
In the same year, Ford produced 1.9 million cars, General Motors produced 4.8 million cars.
So they had a ways to go and they got a lot of help.
Initially this company had to be hugely subsidized both by the government and by its own existing
business, especially construction. Because there was no way this company was going to be able to
make money without that.
So, yeah, Hyundai was losing money on this new venture.
And he's saying the government decided to pitch in, give it some
subsidies and the other parts of Hyundai that were profitable sent
over their money.
But even that wasn't enough.
Even then, it had to be protected from foreign competition because who's going to buy this
two-bit car when you could import a Cadillac or Mustang?
No way.
So import of foreign cars were completely banned.
A total import ban.
Like a tariff to infinity.
The tariff of all tariffs.
Because the South Korean government's really serious.
They want this to happen.
Yeah, they're making rules that mean South Koreans
couldn't buy foreign cars,
cars that were maybe better or cheaper or both.
Instead, they have to buy these homegrown cars,
which was great for Hyundai,
but for a Korean person trying to buy a car
and paying taxes that are used to subsidize this company, less
great. But as you can maybe guess, this gambit worked. Hyundai is now one of the biggest
car manufacturers on the planet.
And this is a canonical example of what's called infant industry protection.
So this is an idea that the government of developing nations should protect and nurture
the country's young industries until they grow up and can compete with more advanced
industries from more advanced nations. In the same way that we protect and nurture our
children until they grow up and then can compete in the other labor market.
Right. Like a country uses tariffs to support a sweet little baby industry to protect it from the harsh world so it can safely grow bigger and stronger.
And then, as we do with children when they grow up, we remove that protection. In the same way that you don't want to make your kid work
when he's six years old,
you don't want to subsidize your kid until he's 45.
So at some point you have to push the guy into the real world.
And that's what South Korea did.
It eventually took off the tariffs
and the import ban and the subsidies.
Right, the idea behind infant industry tariffs
is they have to be temporary, or you're
just propping up a company that's inefficient and can't be successful on its own, and along the way
wasting a lot of taxpayer money and societal resources that could be put to better use.
This idea was actually invented by an American, and not just any American. It was invented by an American. And not just any American. It was invented by Alexander Hamilton,
the guy on the $10 bill, your first Treasury secretary.
Alexander Hamilton, RIP, Ha-Joon Chang, and other economists say if the goal is to turn
a little baby industry into a strong, productive adult, then really, tariffs aren't enough.
You need not only to protect them from outside competition,
but you also need to nourish them and help them grow
with things like subsidies and piano lessons.
And the US has a history of doing this,
of trying to nurture little baby industries
that policymakers have believed
are the industries of the future,
like solar energy and electric vehicles.
Now, there's a big debate in economics
about the infant industry argument.
There are lots of examples of infit industry interventions going bad, like Malaysia trying
to build a car, or Brazil trying to build a computer industry.
These efforts have mostly failed, and they wasted a lot of resources in the process.
Right, because for this to work, the government has to pick the right industry to nurture
and then nurture it correctly.
And tariffs are not just for babies.
This kind of protectionism also can make sense for national security interests.
Like what if your citizens need medicines or microchips or drone batteries, and the
only people who make those things live thousands of miles away in a place with different, maybe
opposing national security goals. Even the most free trade of economists seem to agree that,
yeah, maybe paying a little bit of a premium to support a slightly uneconomic domestic industry
in these cases is a good idea. Another situation where economists think there's a case for tariffs
is when trading partners don't play by the rules. Like if a country is manipulating its currency or stealing intellectual property or egregiously
exploiting workers, that gives that country an unfair advantage in the global marketplace.
And so tariffs are a pretty common tool for competitors to level the playing field.
Over the last 10 years, more economists have come around to Ha-Joon's way of seeing tariffs
and protectionist policies.
Now things are, yeah, I wouldn't say it's going in the opposite direction, but more
complicated.
So Ha-Joon Chang's lonely argument?
It's less lonely.
A lot of economists agree now.
Infant industry, national security, sure, tariffs's less lonely. A lot of economists agree now. Infant industry, national security,
sure, tariffs can maybe help. But the Trump administration has more ideas. We get into
that after the break. Okay, so tariffs could be useful for infant industry protection, for national security
interests, and to combat unfair trade practices.
President Trump is now imposing sweeping tariffs in all sorts of areas and on all sorts of
countries.
He does talk about things like national security and unfair trade practices, but his approach to tariffs feels like it's about something bigger than that.
And it's all part of this particular worldview that seems to be shared within Trump World
and also outside of it. That the costs of free trade, they were too high.
That free trade devastated communities around America.
And the economics world has really woken up to this over the last decade or so.
There's this series of blockbuster studies on something known as the China shock.
The shock happened when China joined the World Trade Organization in 2001.
There's been a distinct drift in the academic literature that every year new stuff comes out
that the China shock was worse and worse than we thought.
That's Mark Summerlin. He's an economist, consultant, and longtime friend of Trump's Treasury Secretary.
We just basically added suddenly like a billion people to the global workforce,
and it really gutted a lot of things, and we were too slow to realize it. He says that China got a bunch of manufacturing jobs and the US got cheaper imports, but the
people who lost jobs in the United States didn't bounce back. They didn't get new
jobs. The China shock created like these mini depressions in towns around the country.
Now we have massive trade deficits with China and other countries where we're importing
way more than we export. Trump world sees this as a huge economic problem and tariffs
as a solution, one that will help correct the trade imbalances and bring back manufacturing
jobs.
The way that the Trump administration looks at it, especially with something like China, is no, it's a bad deal. And China
gets jobs and we get like bad Chinese goods that last for a year and then we throw them
out. And so you can see why people would say, you know, maybe we would prefer to have jobs
and be building assets rather than getting all this excess consumption.
One of the big goals of free trade policies has been to lower prices, but the trade-off
was a huge loss of manufacturing jobs.
And manufacturing jobs maybe have something kind of magical about them.
For example, a lot of economic research has shown that manufacturing jobs provided ladders
to the middle class for people without a college education.
So the administration's idea seems to be to choose a different trade-off, to accept higher prices with
the hope of eventually bringing back some of those good jobs. If Christmas decorations coming in from
China suddenly cost 25% more, I feel that you're going to see people suddenly rev up and start producing them here.
Judy Shelton is an economist and senior fellow at the Independent Institute, a think tank.
Because we have Etsy, we have people can sign up for Amazon.
I think Americans are quick to recognize an opportunity.
Judy has been making the case for correcting the US trade imbalance for years.
In his first term, Trump nominated her for the Federal Reserve Board of Governors.
She did not get confirmed.
A bunch of economists and Fed employees wrote letters saying her views were extreme and
too partisan on monetary policy.
Judy says tariffs can really work when it comes to achieving the administration's economic
goals, which is not only to deter people from buying imports, but also to incentivize them
to buy stuff made in America.
The whole agenda of the Trump administration
is oriented toward correcting the past general shift
toward a more government-managed economy,
a more financialized economy,
and going back to the real economy where people make things.
To Judy, redirecting that spending is the best part of tariffs. But even if Americans
refuse to buy American.
If they go ahead and continue to purchase the good produced by another country and they
pay the tariff, I guess the consolation prize is that you get the beautiful revenue,
right? You get the increased taxation, the revenues to the U.S. government from the tariff
that's being applied. And this is one more benefit the administration points to, to solving our
problems using tariffs. They say it will help rebalance the government's budget. Right now, more money goes
out of the government than comes in. If tariffs raise beautiful revenue, that's money in our pocket.
But of course, if we are taking money out of our pocket for new spending or, you know, collecting
less money through taxes, then tariffs won't necessarily improve the budget problem. Like,
much of the revenue from tariffs in Trump's first term was offset by bailing out farmers
who were harmed by trade retaliation.
And now the administration is talking about compensating farmers again.
Now, all that, that has been basically their argument for why they want to use tariffs.
And the way Trump is applying these tariffs is pretty different from the prescription
that many economists are now on board with.
There are a bunch of different tariffs flying around right now, so we're just going to
focus on one.
One that President Trump has been talking a lot about in recent weeks.
Cars.
Last week, Trump announced 25% tariffs on all imported cars and certain car parts.
Cars made in the US, even by foreign companies, no tariff.
And the stated goal is to get Americans to buy cars made in the US, because they would
be comparatively cheaper.
And the US gets those good manufacturing jobs.
Now, you could make the case that electric cars are maybe an infant industry, but the
auto industry in general, it's not an infant industry, but the auto industry in general,
it's not an infant industry. It doesn't need piano lessons. It has been competing on the global
stage for years, and now it's getting protections. And that means that car prices are going to be
artificially higher. Foreign cars will be subject to, import tax, but also US car makers use foreign parts,
which also face the same import tax. And there will be less pressure on US car makers to
keep their prices low because their foreign competitors have a big price disadvantage
in the US market. So yeah, likely higher prices all around. And that means consumers will
likely buy fewer cars.
So if this stuff works in the way the administration seems to want, the best case scenario seems
to be that it will still be an expensive, slow process, like multiple years, to build
up all of this manufacturing in the United States. In fact, after Trump announced his
car tariffs, the stock prices of U.S. automakers fell. The market is signaling that this policy will have costs even for American manufacturers.
And the rollout of many of these tariffs has been a little chaotic.
This year alone, we have seen Trump go back and forth on tariffs on different countries,
and that uncertainty has a cost.
It makes it hard for businesses to make decisions about which plant to build or where to hire?
And waiting is expensive.
And we actually have a little bit of data from last Trump term so we can see empirically
what the effect was of similar policies.
The Trump administration back then, they put tariffs on a bunch of Chinese goods, including
washing machines.
And one study found that the washing machine tariffs actually did create jobs.
One thousand eight hundred new jobs in the USA making washing machines.
At an average cost to US consumers of more than eight hundred thousand dollars per job.
Even after accounting for the revenue raised from the tariffs.
The view from the Trump world though is like, yeah, the transition from our current setup
may be painful, but it's going to be worth it.
But there is this whole other side to the way Trump is using tariffs.
Like earlier this year, Trump wanted to deport Colombian citizens who were in the US to send
them back to Colombia.
The normal course is, apparently, to send people on commercial flights.
But in January, the Trump administration sent two military planes.
The Colombian president wouldn't let the military planes land.
So, Mark Summerlin says, Trump turned to tariffs.
For President Trump, a tariff is just a form of power.
So with, you know, with Colombia, he wanted them to take back certain people and he wasn't getting the
answer that he wanted.
And so he just threatened 25% tariffs.
25% tariffs on Colombian goods.
And Trump said they'd go up to 50% a week later.
That was Sunday morning.
And by that evening, Colombia and Trump had reached an understanding.
Colombia would allow deportation flights without restriction.
No tariffs.
Though the White House said that the threat of tariffs would be, quote, held in reserve
in case Colombia reneges.
So that was a case where for some of us, it might be uncomfortable seeing it.
Different people have different philosophies on whether big countries should be bullying
little countries or not.
But in that case, he got what he wanted.
It was short lived.
From a U.S. perspective, there wasn't really any damage done.
And the reason the U.S. can act like this, the thinking goes, is because we're rich.
There are so many of us and we spend so much money.
We don't rely on trade as much as our trade partners do.
In the end, we kind of do have the leverage. So I mean, if they want to retaliate, I think
ultimately they're going to lose that game because they need us more than we need them.
I mean, to put a sort of another like blunt frame on it, it's like using a richness as a country as leverage.
Yeah. A bullying tactic.
Yeah, as leverage. Yeah. Yeah. That's it. That's it. As we're using our power.
And because we have this power, thinking goes, if we're going to trade with someone, we should
get something we want for it. The Trump administration did this with Mexico too, threatening tariffs
and then delaying them because Mexico did something he wanted,
agreed to send troops to the border.
Because trade is power. And we have used trade policy kind of like this in the past as a geopolitical tool.
For example, we thought, you know, that capitalism would cure communism.
Judy remembers being in China when it was opening its markets in the 1980s.
We thought that it was two sides of a coin, that if you liberalize the trading rules so
they could benefit economically, then you would have people demanding more freedoms.
They would insist on sort of empowering their own private sector, and that would be all
to the good.
We had this idea that we could use free trade to make other people see the world in the
same way that we do.
Now the US is operating with a slightly different idea.
Instead of free trade as an incentive to be our friend and join our democracy club, the
US is threatening to close trade, to incentivize, strongly incentivize people to do what it
wants like nice economy you got there.
And that's kind of the view from Trump world.
We have all of this power and we should use it.
We could go through some pain to get some gain.
We have a new perk for Planet Money Plus supporters.
We have a new perk for Planet Money Plus supporters. You can now listen to some of our classic series from the Planet Money Archive.
Like when we wanted to understand the global financial crisis and bought a toxic asset
we named Toxy.
You can now find all 8 Toxy episodes in one playlist.
And there are more playlists to come this year.
If you're already a Planet Money Plus supporter, you can check them out. If you're not, you can
sign up at plus.npr.org. You also get bonus episodes sponsored for listening and know
that you're supporting our work.
This episode was produced by Willa Rubin and edited by Meg Kramer. It was fact-checked
by Sarah McClure and engineered by James Willits.
Alex Goldmark is our executive producer,
I'm Greg Rosalski.
And I'm Mary Childs.
This is NPR.
Thanks for listening.
["The Daily Show"]