Stuff You Should Know - The Tragedy of the Commons
Episode Date: February 6, 2025Since it was introduced in the 60s, the Tragedy of the Commons, the idea that humans will inevitably ruin any resource we all share, has had sweeping effects on government and public attitudes on who ...owns the environment. Problem is, it was fictitious.See omnystudio.com/listener for privacy information.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Do you want to see into the future?
Do you want to understand an invisible force
that's shaping your life?
Do you want to experience the frontiers
of what makes us human?
On Tech Stuff, we travel from the minds of Congo
to the surface of Mars,
from conversations with Nobel Prize winners
to the depths of TikTok,
to ask burning questions about technology,
from high tech to low culture and everywhere in between.
Join us. Listen to Tech Stuff production of iHeartRadio.
Hey, and welcome to the podcast.
I'm Josh and there's Chuck and it's just us again, Jerry Who.
And this is Stuff You Should Know.
That's right.
Another econ edition.
Typically not my favorite, but you know, this one I could wrap my head around for the most
part.
I think that's one of the reasons why it's had such an enormous impact on the world.
Yeah.
Because it is so easy to wrap your head around.
We should probably say we're talking about the tragedy of the commons.
And for those of you who aren't familiar, it's this idea, this concept that if you have
a shared resource, a commons, say, and people are able to use it at their own leisure, for their own purposes.
Eventually, as they seek to maximize their profits,
they're going to overuse this commons,
and inevitably it'll be ruined,
because people can't have anything nice, essentially.
You know what's funny?
You're gonna laugh at me here.
They're all gonna laugh at you.
The central area of my high school was called the Commons.
And it just occurred to me 35 years or so after I graduated that that's what that meant.
Oh, I see. I thought you were gonna say like my teenage years were the tragedy of the commons. No, I just, I don't know.
I never thought about the word
because when you're in high school,
it's just something the commons will meet in the commons.
But it never occurred to me that that's what that meant,
just like a common area shared by everybody.
It didn't either.
To me, I know exactly what you're talking about.
There was, if it was not high school,
then maybe middle school.
There was some school where that was called that too.
And I wonder if it was like a surreptitious shot at kids,
like they're all sheep.
Because I don't think that's true.
But one of the major uses for commons traditionally
has been for grazing.
That's a really good example.
If you let a bunch of people graze on a shared resource,
but they're taking what they can from that resource
to make money for themselves, to support themselves,
then just because humans are rational, selfish,
horrible beings, that meadow or that high school cafeteria
will be ruined.
Yeah, that's right.
And the idea of the tragedy of the commons
started out in 1968.
An article from Science, the journal Science, was called the tragedy of the commons and it was by
a biologist named Garrett Hardin. And he was sort of piggybacking on a 19th century English
mathematician and economist named William Forster. Not Foster.
I would say piggybacking or hijacking.
Hijacking.
William Forster Lloyd, and you mentioned grazing,
and this is sort of the thought experiment Hardin went with,
which is like you have a grazing field,
and let's say three farmers have use of it,
and they're letting their cows and sheep graze out there.
But at some point, one of them is gonna get
an extra fat cow that they sell for pretty good money.
And they're like, hey, well if that worked out,
maybe I can add an additional cow.
And maybe it'll make the value of all of these cows
go down a little bit, including my own,
because they're not getting as fat
because I've added another cow here.
But if I can sell it for this much money
and it's only costing me a fraction of that for the...
Extra cow?
Well, I mean, it would only cost a fraction of loss
of resources for the other cows.
Like I'm still coming out ahead.
And so bada bing, bada boom, that's what I'm gonna do.
Right, yeah.
So if everybody was making $1 off of their cows
when everything was being grazed on sustainably,
then if you add one more cow,
now everybody's making 85 cents off of their cows
because you're starting to overtax the commons.
But that person who added that cow,
that's an extra 85 cents they wouldn't have had before,
right?
Yeah, and if you're able to sell that cow
for like five bucks, that 85 cents is pittance
compared to what you're making on the other side.
Right, so there's always under the logic
of the tragedy of the commons,
there's always a reason to add another cow,
and add another cow, and add another cow,
because your returns are always going to be more
than the cost that you can offset with the returns, right?
Well, that and you're also on the assumption
that everyone else is gonna be adding cows,
so I'm not gonna be the only sucker not adding cows.
Right, so you're either a sucker or you're just somebody who wants to survive.
Because if people start adding cows and you're the one farmer who's like,
I'm not going to do that.
I find that morally repugnant.
I really like sustainably grazing here and I'll just take one for the team.
In very short order, that farmer would find that
they were no longer making money.
No more team.
Because exactly, because each additional cow was
taking an additional fraction.
So let's say that every time you added a cow, it
reduced the price that all the other cows got by 15%.
That's not a steady price because if you reduce a dollar by 15%
now you're getting 85 cents for a cow. But now when you're adding another cow
that reduces that 85 cents by 15%. So all of a sudden you're making 72 cents and
then 61 cents and then 52 cents right? But again if you're adding cows that's
always extra almost found money. If you're're adding cows, that's always extra, almost found money.
If you're not adding cows, then the cows
that you had originally are now getting less and less
and less until you're making zero money.
So you are forced into adding cows.
And that's why it's considered the tragedy,
or why Garrett Hardin called it the tragedy of the commons,
because inevitably, under these circumstances,
which have long been considered
to be universal circumstances basically,
the commons will always get ruined and depleted,
and everybody will be totally up the creek.
That's right.
Harden was basically like,
there's a couple of solutions here.
You can either divide this area up, and now each person has their own little private part
of the pasture that they're only in control of and no one else can get on it and graze
there.
Or a government body is going to have to step in and regulate this stuff and manage it.
And if you listen to Harden, and we'll talk a little bit about the problems with this
guy in a second. But if you listen to Harden, he'll say when a little bit about the problems with this guy in a second, but if you
listen to Hardin, he'll say when you divide this thing up and make it just private, and everyone
is incentivized to basically preserve their plots and do it sustainably, so their profits are
maximized with making sure the land isn't ruined so they can keep those profits maximized?
Yeah, because now it's their land, and they suddenly realize, oh, this is a finite resource.
If I start to degrade this land, it's only coming out of my profits, because the other farmer's land is not degraded.
So, I'm the only one in competition with myself here, really, and I need to make sure that this land is preserved
because now it's the goose that laid the golden egg and I need to keep it nice and healthy and happy.
That's the direct result of privatization as far as Garrett Harden was explaining,
as far as the tragedy of the commons goes, right?
Simple solution, just give people an incentive to take care of it by making
it their own. And the other way, like you said, is government intervention. And this seems to be
what hardens big... Like this is his favorite, I think, solution was bring the government in and
just say you can't overgraze, you can't graze more than these number of sheep. And if you do,
You can't overgraze, you can't graze more than these number of sheep. And if you do, we'll wipe out your entire family line.
Something along those lines.
Yeah, but here's the thing.
It wasn't like he was some big champion of the government,
because if you read the whole article, Hardin is like,
and another thing, the reason why the world is headed toward a bad place or a bad place
already is because freedom to breed is intolerable. So there's just too many
people, we're making too many babies, and the welfare state that the government is
encouraging is taking away the natural consequence of what happens if you have
too many kids. Like they're gonna not be able to sustain that and the kids are
gonna starve to death. So we're over breeding and
all of a sudden everyone's going, whoa, whoa, whoa, whoa, and he said, and another thing, he said,
this over breeding, it could actually be a strategy where a cohesive group could come along to increase their power and they're like, wait a minute,
are you talking about the great replacement? And he said, I don't know what that is.
Right. And they said, well, it'll be a thing at some point.
He's like, I like the ring of it, though.
Yeah, exactly.
It's catchy.
So yeah, his whole thing was we, using scare quotes,
are overbreeding meant poorer non-white countries
are overbreeding.
Right.
That was basically his whole thing.
And that, yes, because there was such thing
as international aid in the way of food, in the way of money,
that people could just keep having kids
and knowing that the Western wealthier governments were
going to take care of them.
And he was like, that's not what we should be doing.
And here's why the tragedy of the commons.
And to say that, by the way, I read another paper of his, too,
called Lifeboat Ethics, the Argument Against Helping
the Poor.
That was the subtitle.
So he really just put it out there.
But he basically said, OK, let's imagine that all
of the countries in the world are lifeboats.
Some are ridiculously overloaded with people.
Others, the wealthier, more advanced ones.
Let's say that they're in a lifeboat that seats 100,
and they only have 90 people.
But there's tons of people swimming around them,
trying to get in the lifeboat. Do you pick 10 people out of these, you know, thousands
of people out there to let come into your lifeboat? If so, how do you pick
those people? What do you tell the people you don't pick? And he ultimately
concludes that just don't help anybody. Then you don't have to worry about playing favorites
or anything like that.
Plus you keep your 10 person safety buffer
in case things change for you and your lifeboat
and you're fine.
He actually argues against guilt.
You shouldn't feel any guilt.
And as a matter of fact, we shouldn't put guilt on people
for making decisions like these, because they're just smart.
And then secondly, he also says that if you are one of those people like that one farmer who is like
overgrazing, is morally repugnant and I'm not gonna do it. If you were like that farmer in this lifeboat
and you said I just I can't do this. I can't sit there and watch people drown while I'm sitting here.
I'm going to give up my seat for somebody else.
Hardin argued that just by virtue of a person accepting your seat,
they are less moral than you and that over time as more people in the lifeboat give up their seat for moral reasons,
morality will be replaced in this lifeboat with self-interest
and then what do you have then?
So he makes all these like, like if you're a rational person and you take emotion out
of it, you're like, you know, I guess that kind of makes sense in a little bit.
But the moment you add in any, a drop of humanity to it, you're like, this is horrible that
this guy wrote a series of humanity to it. You're like, this is horrible that this guy wrote a series of papers arguing this.
Yeah, and he, you know, as far as the tragedy
of the commons goes, he very explicitly says,
like, you know, you gotta prioritize yourself here
and what you're doing and maximize your profits
and if you don't, if you have ethics or something,
then you're not a very smart person.
Right, exactly.
So this was his whole thing that, you know, like,
all of it was overpopulation.
The thing is, it got diluted or taken very literally,
very quickly, and it was applied to actual commons,
as we'll see, and just it was stripped of its overpopulation,
xenophobia, racism, all of that stuff,
and just got applied to real world commons management.
And to say like it changed things
is the understatement of the century, Chuck.
That's right.
Should we take a break?
Yeah, let's.
All right, we'll be right back everybody. Do you want to understand an invisible force that's shaping your life? I'm Osvalosian, one of the new hosts of the long running podcast Tech Stuff.
I'm slightly skeptical but obsessively intrigued.
And I'm Kara Price, the other new host.
And I'm ready to adopt early and often.
On Tech Stuff, we travel all the way from the mines of Congo to the surface of Mars
to the dark corners of TikTok to ask and attempt to answer burning
questions about technology.
One of the kind of tricks for surviving Mars is to live there long enough so that people
evolve into Martians.
Like data is a very rough proxy for a complex reality.
How is it possible that the world's new energy revolution can be based in this place where
there's no electricity at night?
Oz and I will cut through the noise to bring you the best conversations and deep dives
that will help you understand how tech is changing our world and what you need to know
to survive the singularity. So join us.
Listen to tech stuff on the iHeartRadio app, Apple podcasts, or wherever you get your podcasts. Okay, so the tragedy of the commons became like the dominant way of looking at the world among
Western nations because it did two things.
It said that you can solve this problem,
everyone is going to have.
Anytime you have a shared resource,
people are going to deplete it.
That's what it said, no matter where you are in the world,
no matter who you are.
But we want to save these shared resources
because this paper came out at about the same time
that environmental consciousness came up.
So it was like perfect timing for that.
But it also said, just privatize, buddy.
And at that time, neoliberalism was on the rise.
And they were like, yes, privatize.
Take all these government run things
and put them in the hands of corporations
and we'll all be better off.
Yeah, and one of the ways that happened was,
and we're gonna talk about sort of different versions
of this here and there in this episode, but environmental trading
markets emerged.
And that came from Canada, actually, an economist named J.H.
Dales in 1968, but the 80s and 90s are when they really kind of started flying off the
shelf.
But that's like when the government comes in with a regulation, let's say, to
cap whatever.
In this case, let's say they're capping emissions on...
Baseball caps.
Baseball caps?
I need to get rid of some baseball caps, so that's great.
Oh, you have too many?
Do you have any good Hawks ones?
I'm on the lookout for those.
I have one Hawks cap that I wear.
I gotcha. I just gave away a second one because it was too big,
but your head is too small for this thing.
It is a really tiny head.
I'm like that one Safari Hunter in Beetlejuice.
Do you know what your hat size is?
Like.6?
.6, okay. That's good.
So let's say it's fisheries,
because we're going to talk about fisheries a lot.
So the government will it's fisheries, because we're gonna talk about fisheries a lot.
So the government will come in and say,
hey, you're overfishing,
so we're gonna cap how many fish you can harvest
or make it a certain size and a certain area
or something like that.
And then here's your permit, fishery A,
and here's your permit, fishery B and fishery C.
And they grant these permits,
but, and this is the key to the ETMs
environmental trading markets the word trade you can trade as ie buy and sell
these permits which and this is something that I don't fully understand
or maybe I do understand and that's the whole point but if company A is well
let's say it's an environmental like hey, you're a factory and we're incentivizing
you to clean up your pollution and here's your permit or whatever.
If company A does a really good job and does the right thing and comes in like way under
the amount of emissions that they're supposed to hit, by simply selling that to company
B who's like, man, we're not too good at that.
I mean, is it creating like,
doesn't that kind of defeat the whole purpose?
No, it doesn't.
And we talked about this in the acid rain episode.
Do you remember whatever happened to acid rain that thing?
Oh yeah.
It can work and it does work.
We actually reduced sulfur dioxide emissions
that were associated with acid rain.
So much, the acid rain went away. And it was like the ozone layer of like the early 80s,
I think, and 70s. Like it was a big scary thing. And we took care of it because of cap
and trade schemes. So it can work.
But how? That's what I don't get. If one company is lowering their output,
but another one is increasing theirs
because they just bought the other companies,
then how is that a net loss?
Because of the cap.
Because you put the cap at something close to a target
that you want to reduce things to.
So you don't make some sky high cap
that's more than what you're at now,
you make it less.
And then maybe a couple years later, you make it less. And then maybe a couple
years later, you make it less than that. So those caps, those little shares or whatever,
those allowances that they can trade, they get more and more valuable the less and less they
represent because the law is kind of bringing these emissions down further and further.
So ultimately, you're rewarding a company by reducing their emissions because they can make money selling that to another company, and that other company is
actually technically being punished because they're having to shell out more money than
they budgeted for because they're emitting more than they are supposed to. So ultimately,
you're penalizing and rewarding through this cap and trade scheme, but you're also creating
an artificial cap. All these companies could just pollute as much as trade scheme, but you're also creating an artificial cap.
All these companies could just pollute as much as they want,
but this government is saying, no, you actually can't.
Here's your level.
Here it is divided among the 10 companies, go to town.
But is-
Does that make sense?
Well, yeah, the thing I still don't get though is,
is the company that's buying extra emissions,
whatever, output from the company that's like really good at it,
are they allowed to go over the cap?
They, no, but let's say they have a cap to put out 10 pounds of CO2, right?
Yeah.
And they're going, they know they're putting out 15 that year.
Well, this other company that's putting out five pounds of CO2 that year,
they can sell their other five pounds. So no one goes over the cap, the total cap,
but different companies can contribute different amounts based on how much of those
allowance shares they can purchase or sell. Does that make sense?
Yeah, I guess so.
I promise it works. It worked for sulfur dioxide.
It does work.
The problem is, is it's also like,
it requires a lot of buy-in from industry
or really heavy-handed government regulation.
Well, either way, it became a big deal in the 80s.
And by the end of the 80s,
the World Bank referred to tragedy of the commons
as quote, the dominant paradigm
within which social scientists
assess natural resource issues.
So I mean, you can't, like there's a bunch of different
policies in a bunch of different areas,
so you can't just look at the entire thing as a whole
and say like, well, it's been a huge success,
like you can pick out something like acid rain,
and say it was a success in this case.
But there's humans involved, so you never can tell.
Well, it's not like you never can tell.
I guess they can forecast.
But there's not just one big blanket like,
nope, this is the exact solution.
Right, for sure.
And it depends on the industry, right?
Like you said, acid rain, that was a great success story.
Fisheries are another example.
If you take a fishery, like you were saying,
and you divide up the total catch between companies,
those companies can actually go around and buy,
you know, huge portions of the other company shares, right?
And so all of a sudden, they're basically one company
with all of the rights to catch all of the fish in that fishery,
because they managed to consolidate the shares over time.
And that's a huge problem. That's not at all what you want.
Like, yeah, that fishing company is still staying within the total number of fish that can be caught annually,
but they ran all the other people out of business.
So that's not at all what you want with it. fish that can be caught annually, but they ran all the other people out of business.
So that's not at all what you want with it.
So there's pluses and minuses.
It's situational.
The thing is, the tragedy of the commons has largely been overblown.
And the idea that you can come out on top just by privatizing things like natural resources
has been a lesson learned the hard way that that's just
Overall that's not necessarily the best way to do it and it can really really harm some groups while enriching others
tremendously well
yeah, and like in the case of a fishery like if you're a
Small fishing crew or something good luck kind of working your way up and maybe establishing yourself as one of the larger companies
good luck kind of working your way up and maybe establishing yourself as one of the larger companies, especially if the people that are buying these things up are people
that don't live around there, these corporations that don't have necessarily a local interest.
And again, while they might be like hitting, you know, staying under the threshold environmentally,
it might be working out. But you're consolidating the wealth, sometimes there's regulations on that
where they say you have to be on the fishing boat
and like Chick-fil-A,
if you're gonna buy a Chick-fil-A franchise,
you gotta manage that thing.
Exactly right, you want that Chick-fil-A Cadillac.
Exactly, but sometimes there aren't regulations like that
and what's been proven over and over,
especially with ETMs,
if there's a way for a system to
be exploited for profit, then a company will come along and do it no matter what.
That's basically the neoliberalism t-shirt that you just said, do you know?
Exactly.
Here's the thing, if you look at the actual tragedy of the commons, Hardin sort of just
leaves, conveniently leaves a lot of stuff out.
Like he's assuming in this argument that like,
the people that, the farmers that are sharing
this grazing spot aren't talking to each other at all
about what's going on and saying like,
hey, we're ruining this land by the way,
maybe we should dial it back,
like everybody get rid of two cows.
And it also assumes that their only interest
is to maximize profit and to not care for the land.
And that's just not always the case.
No, I mean, that's really a tough sell
to a neoliberal policymaker.
Like they're just like, you're crazy.
You're so naive for even thinking that.
Of course their goal is to maximize profits.
But what's really cool is we'll see a little later on, real world examples prove that that's
not true.
They disprove the tragedy of the commons by themselves.
It wasn't like, oh, let's set up this crazy really kind of rickety experiment and see
if we can disprove the tragedy of the commons.
No, people went out and looked at real world, for example, indigenous treatment of common resources, and they're like, these people have been managing
and not depleting these things for thousands of years now because they came up with their own
sensible rules that aren't neoliberal in nature. Yeah, for sure. If you look at the original sort
of, like it's not just a theoretical thing, If you look at the paper by William Forrester, I think it said Forrester earlier, not Forrester,
Lloyd that this is the one Hardin, would you say hijacked to begin with?
He did.
He did.
He was talking about actual English commons, which was how it used to work in Medieval
England was the Lord would own all this land, but there
were people that lived on it. It wasn't like, hey, this is my private land. No one can be
here at first. So the people that lived there, they had to graze their animals and fish out
of the streams and ponds and things like that. And they were allowed to with, you know, through
certain age-old customs. Sometimes the local government would step in and kind of help manage this stuff and limit grazing and things like that. But it wasn't like this set codified
system in place all over England. It was just they had been working it out for centuries like this.
It wasn't perfect, but it was sustainable and they didn't like just destroy their land because they
all had self-interest to keep it sustainable.
Right. And then they were enclosed.
And enclosure was this huge, massive,
overlooked, um, world-changing event.
And we need to do an episode on the fencing of the common
someday because it's just, it changed the entire mentality.
Remember our, um, episode on the Luddites and how they emerged from a world
that just completely turned everything on its head?
That's what happened with enclosure
when they fenced the commons.
It changed everything,
and the concept of private property
really kind of developed out of that,
at least in the West, right?
So we'll do a whole separate episode on that,
but suffice to say that it seems to be once the commons
were fenced and were no longer a shared resource, that's when the issues started to come up. If you
ask Karl Marx, he would have said that this is where we came up with the landless proletariat,
the working class who had to work for wages because they no longer owned anything. Mm-hmm.
It created the very, very wealthy class that didn't actually have to do anything because
all they had to do was start renting this private property of theirs to the people who
needed to work.
It created a whole system of problems.
And, in fact, some people are like, whether however you feel about capitalism, you
can kind of trace this back to the beginning of capitalism, the fencing of the commons. The irony
of all this is that William Forrester Lloyd was arguing against Adam Smith's capitalist idea that
the invisible hand of the market will always guide things to a good outcome.
He created ultimately the tragedy of the commons as a thought experiment to show like no actually people don't
people aren't guided to this this bottom good instead
they are going to act in their own self-interest and destroy this stuff. So
Hardin actually took it and turned it around as an argument for capitalism, for private enterprise, for privatizing stuff. This
argument that was originally used to disprove that. Yeah and if you were in
closing your own comments or arguing in that favor at the time, you were saying
hey everything has been chaos up into this point. It's very inefficient and there's got to be a more organized way to do this.
And that was, you know, it wasn't a guise, I guess, but what they were really saying was,
is we want this area.
Right. It's ours.
Yeah. I mean, let's just oversell the chaos maybe, because it was actually working out
okay for many centuries.
But we're going to just sell it as this chaotic mess that needs to be cleaned up and organized.
Right.
That's how it's done, it seems like, isn't it, Charles?
People come along and create a problem that's not actually there for their own benefit ultimately.
Yeah, I have a friend who, ever since college college he was just one of those guys that while we
were just like, whatever.
About everything, about the world, about politics, about that period of college where you just
kind of check out and all you care about is where you're going that night.
All that to say he was a very smart guy back then and he used to just say stuff that used
to shake all of us to our core about what what's coming about this that or the other with the government and he would always say
But here's how they're gonna sell it to you and I was that always stuck with me and he's totally right
Like they'll sell it to you is this but then it becomes this right? Yeah
That's really interesting. I love stuff like that about how
Just massive sweeping changes come from just
a change in an idea, a change in perspective.
And that's a really great, that's what the tragedy of the commons was.
It was an idea.
It was a perspective.
He, like Garrett Hardin didn't undertake a bunch of different experiments or
field studies or anything like that in his paper,
which is published in Science, by the way, it was an essay about his own thoughts on something that he presented
so reasonably that people who were, again, neoliberals who were in favor of privatizing everything,
including common resources, could go to government policymakers and be like,
here's how it works. Doesn't that make sense? And the government said, yes, that makes sense.
Let's start privatizing everything. And it was just because this guy took this idea and
made it approachable. That's it. It became fact, even though it was never fact. I just
find that fascinating how something like that can just change the world.
Well, you know, I think there are so many people licking their chops.
They're like, oh, here's a great opportunity for us to jump on this bandwagon to take more for ourselves.
Right. But what if the bandwagon had never been there?
Would anyone have figured out how to manipulate things so thoroughly, especially so quickly,
too, without this one paper this one biologist wrote?
Yeah, someone would have.
Yeah, but it would have happened piecemeal, I think.
I don't know.
It's questionable that it would have happened like it had.
Yeah, maybe.
Let's take a break.
All right, we'll be right back.
We're going to contemplate that and come back with a definitive answer right after this.
Do you want to understand an invisible force that's shaping your life? I'm Osvaldo Loshan,
one of the new hosts of the long running podcast Tech Stuff. I'm slightly skeptical, but obsessively
intrigued.
And I'm Kara Price, the other new host, and I'm ready to adopt early and often.
On Tech Stuff, we travel all the way from the mines of Congo to the surface of Mars to the dark corners of TikTok to ask and attempt to answer burning questions about technology.
One of the kind of tricks for surviving Mars is to live there long enough so that people
evolve into Martians.
Like data is a very rough proxy for a complex reality.
How is it possible that the world's new energy revolution can be based in this place where there's no electricity at night?
Oz and I will cut through the noise to bring you the best
conversations and deep dives that will help you understand how tech is changing our world and what you need to know to survive the
Singularity so join us listen to tech stuff on the iHeartRadio app, Apple podcasts, or wherever you get your podcasts.
We don't have a definitive answer, I was just kidding.
You got me.
We should talk about Eleanor Ostrom though.
This is a woman who wrote a book in 1990
called Governing the Commons, colon,
the evolution of institutions for collective action.
And she's probably like at the top of the list
for really bringing this to the upper echelons
of the political world worldwide, I guess.
She took a bunch of examples all over the world of controlled CPRs like grazing areas,
it's always a good one, in Switzerland in this case, forests in Japan, meadows in Japan,
and of course fisheries and things like that, in this case in the Philippines.
So kind of really kind of picking different spots all over the world and examining these and how they've worked out and
basically argued that like, hey these things are
had been working out for centuries and it worked out pretty good because everybody
lived there who was involved.
And when you have local people that have long-term interest
in the well-being of their land and their area and keeping that up,
then the economic side of things is not going to go away,
but it's going to take a back seat to ensuring that this land
that they live in stays as close to as it is as possible.
Yes and. So she was the one who went out and actually did those field studies that Garrett
Hardin didn't. Like she had the receipts to back up what she was saying, which was the tragedy of
the commons isn't actually true. It's certainly not in every case. And what's the ironic thing is this, Chuck.
The tragedy of the commons played out,
I feel like for the most part,
when things were privatized and outside industry
were allowed to come in and have a share of the commons.
That's when it was, that's when the problems really began.
Yeah.
I, I, so I want to say one other thing too, because I know I'm kind of known for
having a very hard nose, certain opinion about things and it's like, you know, in
this particular direction, typically.
Okay.
in this particular direction typically.
Okay.
I don't know, in the last like year or so,
I've kind of lost my, um, taste for,
for rigidity like that, or black and white thinking.
So, I don't want anybody to think that I'm just like,
neoliberalism equals bad.
Alternatives to neoliberalism, all good.
Yeah, yeah.
Like, I just don't see the world like that anymore.
So, I don't want anybody to think that I'm just,
like I'm bashing neoliberalism as if there's no redeemable quality to it whatsoever.
I just don't believe that.
But in the case of the tragedy of the commons,
I feel like more often than not,
neoliberal policies, again, privatizing shared resources
or taking oversight away from the government
and just putting it in the hands of the market has been disastrous for the world over the
last like 40, 50 years. It's been really good for wealthy people and helping other people
get wealthier, but that ignores the expense on the backs of other people that it's created, too.
I just wanted to
put that out there. I don't want anybody think I'm just bashing
neoliberalism because it does help in a lot of ways.
No, and I know you well and I can tell everybody that you are a very varied
person who looks at things from all angles and is very considerate of... you
don't just shut anything down outright.
You like to consider things.
Now.
Okay, so back to Ostrom though.
She argues that, hey, we've shown time and time again,
I show in these real world examples in my books,
in Japan and in Switzerland and in the Philippines
with the fisheries, that this can work.
But there's some parameters that have been shown to ensure that it works.
And you got to follow these or it's not going to work.
And she narrowed it down to eight principles of like a successful regulation of a commons,
which is clearly defined boundaries.
So who can use this area?
What is this area?
Rules that fit local needs,
and this is something we've been kind of hammering on.
It's got to be the local parties
that come up with these rules.
The addition of outside people stepping in
it seems to be when all of the problems start,
because their interests are not the same as local interests.
Yeah, history kind of tells us that when outside groups come in and start pushing the people
who've been using this thing for a thousand years, pushing them around, it just doesn't
go very well, typically, because the outside groups don't necessarily understand this.
And as we'll see, that doesn't mean that there shouldn't be the involvement of any
outside groups.
What Ostrom was saying that she found from these studies is that you have to begin the
base, the people who are really laying the groundwork and setting the rules for this,
they have to be the people who are actually using this resource.
Yeah, for sure.
The third one is group decision making.
So it's not just a couple of people or a small board deciding these
things.
Like, get as many people in there as possible, local people.
Monitoring, you have to have people monitoring, and you know, she used her forest land example
in Japan was one where she was like, hey, they had locals monitoring the stuff and levying
fines, so you've got to know that someone is out there doing this, so people, you know,
know they're going to be held accountable.
And then the next one ties into that.
And then when you do that, you've got to start out small with these sanctions.
It's got to be like a warning first and then a small fine.
You can't just come in there with the billy club and say, you're out.
You've got to encourage people to stick around and like, all right, here's a warning,
but you can't keep letting this happen, that kind of thing.
I was really curious what the ultimate punishment is
for repeat offenders.
And the only example I could find was among a group in Bali
and ostracism is what the person ultimately faces.
Get out.
Which, yeah, and that's bad enough in like
a Western society, you know?
But also, you can make do, you know?
There's the internet, if you go into a store,
the person basically has to take your money for food.
In a more traditional culture, ostracism's like,
you're in big trouble because groups rely
on one another for help, and the example they gave was
if one of your relatives dies,
there's certain rights you have to perform
and if you're ostracized, you have to figure that out
all by yourself because the community's not gonna show up
and help you for these death rights
that your ancestors demand of you
because that's just tradition.
Yeah, yeah, for sure.
The last three of the eight, easy dispute resolution,
so just something on the cheap that's pretty informal
and not some big drawn out expensive tribunal
or something like that.
Yeah, no wigs, no powdered wigs.
No powdered wigs at all.
You have to have support from authorities
and it may be a local thing,
but you've gotta have the blessing
of a larger government body to,
at the very least, not get in there
and muck it up themselves
and just sort of let you do your thing.
But maybe also support.
And then finally, building up to a larger system.
So again, keep it local,
but if it's a system that connects to a larger system, like a creek
that connects to a larger watershed, you're going to have to start linking up with other
local groups and make it a larger thing.
Right.
But the point that she made too is that that works.
That's actually scalable, which is good because like you said, a creek is one thing, but it
depends on a watershed.
And so if you can get together with other people who are managing their own creeks,
you can manage the watershed based on the individual common, I guess, rules that groups
have come up with and that you can scale that into more modern systems too, right?
So like say a city has somehow created a cap on how much emissions
that the factories in the cities can create. You can combine that with other cities, and
now you're starting to manage a larger part of the atmosphere. And then the state can
come in and work with all of those cities, and then the state can work with other states.
And all of a sudden now you have regional air quality being controlled from the rules that are based on
the actual stakeholders in each individual community.
That's right.
And didn't she win something for this work?
She won the Nobel, which Livia put in parentheses,
fake Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences,
because that's not one that was actually organized
originally.
Oh, I wonder what she meant by that.
But one of the things that came out of the book,
there's a University of Chicago legal scholar
named Lee Ann Fennell,
who points to that book and says,
you know, this is sort of,
corrects these legal theories that say,
property is all or nothing, like
you either own it and have total control over it or you don't.
And it's actually possible, you can have a common, you can have an area that people share
and the example that, and still have some autonomy.
And the example that Livia gave was like a house.
And if you got a family in the house, you know,
let's say two people that have coupled up and have children,
you know, it's a collective.
But like, you know, generally speaking,
unless you live in a terrible house
with an authoritarian dictator as the head of the household.
Or a stepdad that makes you feel stupid.
Yeah, stepdad that makes you feel dumb.
You've got, you know, your kid has your room, and you know what?
You can, this is your room.
You know, you have a right to your room, and you can basically
decorate it how you want within reason and do what you want in here.
But it's still part of the house.
Right, and technically, your parents own that room.
But because of custom and tradition,
they probably respect that room as your private space.
Yeah, and that's something as a parent I found
is super important because at a certain age,
and this has been the last couple of years with Ruby,
like, you know, I'm gonna go into my room
and shut the door.
Yeah, and you're like, no you're not.
Well, I'll open the door,
because I just like, and it's not in a spy way,
I just like peeking in and seeing the fun stuff she's doing.
And Emily's like, you know, leave the door shut.
She's got to have that autonomy.
And I'm like, I don't know.
Oh, good for Emily.
That's really sweet.
When you open the door, do you suddenly open it
and go, what are you doing?
I'll give a little knock now, you know.
And you know, she's usually in there drawing pictures
of cats and listening to music.
Reading teen beat?
Yeah.
Man, do you remember, so was your room
your own private sanctuary?
Yeah, I mean, Scott and I shared a room until I was,
uh, I feel like I was probably 10 or 11.
That's the, that's the roomage right there.
Yeah, and that's when we split, but we were upstairs at our house. Probably 10 or 11. That's the room age right there.
Yeah, and that's when we split, but we were upstairs
at our house, it was just two bedrooms,
and separated by a joined bathroom.
And my sweet brother, he, I was so sad about moving out
of his room at first, he agreed to keep his bathroom door open
so I could lay in bed and see through the bathroom
to him in his room.
Oh my God.
He is such a, he'd be the rancher that would be like,
I'm not overgrazing, I'll just die.
I know, he's one of the best.
But yeah, so I had my own room and it was like,
my sports posters and I went through a Marilyn Monroe phase
for some reason where I had a bunch of her posters up.
I went through a James Dean phase that was similar.
Yeah, exactly.
But yeah, it was my room.
I took a lot of pride in decorating it and doing my thing
and my parents, my father literally did not come upstairs.
That's a whole other story.
And my mom did for a while, but basically,
I mean, that was our zone for the most part.
That's awesome.
I remember there not being anything more satisfying
than undertaking a total remodeling of your room.
Oh, moving stuff around.
Furniture, all of a sudden the bed's over here.
I used to love doing that.
It was so, it just changed everything.
I love that so much.
I have so many great memories of my room.
Yeah, me too.
And I used to do that to apartments I lived in.
And I had, ironically, recently had a thought
about how much I used to enjoy that
and how, like our house, you can't really do that.
Like it's set up in a way that I can't be like,
hey, let's rearrange our living room.
It's like, well, you can't, because.
Let's move the built-ins outside.
Yeah, exactly.
So those days are over for me, unfortunately.
Yeah, same here.
That's just how it goes as you get older.
It's one more thing that brings you joy
or brought you joy that's now dead
and shriveled up like an old leaf.
All right, well, let's finish up on Tragedy of the Commons
because we can use an example of Maine lobster fisheries
as a pretty good example of how people can start to do the wrong thing but correct course on their own. Yeah.
And that was the case in the 19th century when the state of Maine started setting legal minimum sizes for catching lobsters.
And they couldn't enforce it that well at first, and people broke the rules and were like, you know, trying to make extra money or keep more lobsters than they
should for a while.
But eventually they were like, hey, wait a minute, we're not doing ourselves any favors
here, and if we're going to all continue this to sustain our living doing this, we got to
work together.
So they form harbor gangs to start self-policing basically.
So Maine Lobsterman Harbor gangs,
is there anything scarier than the sound of that?
Just seeing them kind of slowly come up on your boat
and they're all like, they have chains in their hands.
Don't go over there, that's where the harbor gangs are.
Boy, you just took me to Cabot Cove.
So they started self-policing and everyone bought into this idea that let's not ruin all of our livelihood here.
And one thing that gets pointed out is you can do this in a case like that because lobsters are close to shore.
It's a small community. It's local people.
In the case of Cod, and at some point we should do one on the Cod wars because that's where this factor is in, Cod travel long distances and
so it's hard to regulate something like that that's widespread and there's different countries
involved.
So, yeah, I guess tragedy of the commons has been largely debunked even though it completely
altered the world for decades and decades and still does.
Yeah, I mean, either blamed or credited
with the birth of capitalism, that's a small thing.
It's pretty big, yeah.
Yeah.
Yeah, so we're gonna do one on fencing of the commons
one day, and then we're also gonna do one
on neoliberalism someday.
And the cod wars.
Yeah, and the cod wars.
There you go.
Well, since Chuck corrected me and added cod wars,
of course that means it's time everybody for listener mail.
First of all, quick correction to a correction.
When we got written in about the Hodgepodge,
I kept saying Modgepodge.
Right.
It is Modpodge, and the corrector got it right.
I just kept saying it wrong.
Wow.
And I played it off to myself as a joke, but it was not.
Mod Podge is better.
I think the inventor of Mod Podge is just like, oh, why didn't I call it Mod Podge?
Mr. Boat.
It rhymes even.
I wonder if it was from the time when Mod Squad was out, because it does have kind of
like a hippie-dippie flower
look to it, doesn't it?
Well, decoupage is a very old thing,
and I suppose that meant a modern decoupage,
is my guess.
Okay.
Don't you think?
I don't know.
I didn't ever think about it more than I have
in the last couple weeks.
I know, right?
I wish you'd have brought it up.
Oh man, how did it get going?
Oh, I remember now.
We mentioned Martha Stewart and I said,
there's a hodgepodge everywhere.
All right, so this is from a friend in the Netherlands
who said, good luck pronouncing the name.
I think I've nailed it, so we're gonna see.
Okay.
Stay tuned for the end.
Hey guys, just finished the episode on automats
and I felt I needed to write in.
I'm from the Netherlands and believe it or not,
automats are still a big thing there.
And I remembered now after I got a couple of emails
about these of being in Amsterdam
and seeing these Feebo's, F-E-B-O, places.
I've not heard of that.
Well, it's an automat basically,
except instead of a huge restaurant,
it's just like a, you know, a smallish room.
We refer to it as eating out of the wall.
These places mostly just serve deep fried food,
but in general is quite fresh.
Not sure why they're still so popular though.
Maybe it's because the Dutch aren't really known
for their fine dining,
as we just want our meals to be efficient and cheap.
Nevertheless, if you're ever around,
I invite you to take one of our famous croquettes
or bitter balls out of the wall,
which are especially good after a night of heavy drinking.
Love the show, best regards.
And that is from Gys.
Nice, will you spell that for us non-Dutch speakers? At least that's how I was told to say it.
It is pronounced, or I'm sorry, spelled G-I-J-S.
Wow.
And it said, Hez.
That is fantastic.
That looks like I just brushed up against the keyboard.
It really does.
Can you pronounce it one more time?
What I've got and what I'm sticking with is his.
That is great.
I hope you nailed it, Chuck.
I hope so too.
You deserve to.
Well, thanks a lot.
His.
The name you're trying to pronounce is his.
We appreciate the email.
Thanks for filling us in.
Had no idea about bitter balls and eating from the wall,
or out of the wall, in Amsterdam. So thank you. And if you want to be like,
the name is his, then you can send us an email too. Send it off to stuffpodcast.ihartradio.com.
Stuff You Should Know is a production of iHeartRadio.
For more podcasts, my heart radio, visit the iHeartRadio app, Apple podcasts, or wherever
you listen to your favorite shows.
Do you want to see into the future?
Do you want to understand an invisible force that's shaping your life?
Do you want to experience the frontiers of what makes us human? future.