The Dividend Cafe - It's Worse than You Think
Episode Date: March 3, 2023I have written about excessive indebtedness many times in these Dividend Cafe pages, including a piece nearly two years ago that I think has held up quite well. Lately I have written about Japanific...ation, which is not quite the same topic (though there is certainly heavy overlap). I have long believed in treating the disease, not the symptoms, and I didn't even go to medical school (in fact, if I had, it seems these days I'd be less likely to believe that). That may be an overused cliche, but it has utility when it comes to how we think about our personal lives, our health, our finances, and so many other things. And when it comes to the issue of Japanification I think the overall subject will be served to look with more granularity at the nature of the excessive debt to which I refer. This is a seriously action-packed Dividend Cafe, and if you do not agree after reading it you are entitled to a full refund of your subscription price. Let's jump in to the Dividend Cafe ... Blog post here: https://bahnsen.co/3KMCDrK Links mentioned in this episode: TheDCToday.com DividendCafe.com TheBahnsenGroup.com
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Welcome to the Dividend Cafe, weekly market commentary focused on dividends in your portfolio
and dividends in your understanding of economic life.
Well, hello and welcome to this week's Dividend Cafe.
You may be able to tell that I'm not sitting in my studio in New York.
I am in the office in New York and yet our studio, which is right here in the office,
is having some tech difficulties. And so we decided just to go old school and have me come
sit right here at my desk and record Dividend Cafe for you as if we didn't have our big fancy
studios that we use so much. I don't think you care much and those of you listening to the podcast
really don't care.
I want to talk to you today about a pretty sober subject, something much more important than our studios and where we record and things like that. And that is the subject of
the US's debt issue. And there's a kind of fascinating angle on this,
And there's a kind of fascinating angle on this where I make an argument, as I've been making for some time, that the U.S. faces a real systemic problem of low, slow and no growth. And I call this problem Japanification.
And the basic kind of setup goes something like this, that an asset bubble forms. And that could be
from a combination of circumstances. You can have government policy feeding a bubble, excessive,
overly accommodative, easy money, government stimulus. You can have just general investor
euphoria, human nature doing what it does.
There's a lot of things that create a bubble.
And yet a bubble that forms eventually, of course, pops and bursts.
And then great economic damage is done. by which profits decline in the economy, wages decline, jobs decline.
That's basically what generally we call recession.
And those economic difficulties, either some or all of them put together,
become the situation that policymakers try to respond to because people's standard of living
is declining, their quality of life is declining, it can become very politically toxic. People don't
like bad things happening in the economy. It's all pretty simple so far. On a real severe basis,
when you have an asset bubble form, and then it bursts, you can be susceptible to what we call debt deflation, a debt deflation spiral.
It was something that the great Irving Fisher wrote about after the Great Depression, whereby things are declining enough and are bad enough that one is trying to liquidate debt. They're selling assets
to get rid of debt, but the assets are declining in value. The income is declining in value. The
net worth is declining at a faster pace than one can sell off assets. Therefore, you get into a
spiral where by reducing debt, you're actually increasing your leverage because the very
process of reducing debt is putting downward pressure on that denominator, the asset value.
It's a little wonky, I suppose. I hope you understand what I just said. It's not really
a very controversial thesis in economics anymore. And it can be one of the
worst experiences for an economy to go through. And it's more or less what the Federal Reserve
and other central banks were put on earth to do, was avoid these debt deflation spirals,
generally that can come about because some sort of illiquidity crisis creates a solvency crisis.
And that's where this idea of lender of last resort came from.
Well, anyways, a severe downward turn in the economy from a bubble bursting can be a debt deflation spiral.
But even if it's just a run of the mill recession,
inflation spiral. But even if it's just a run of the mill recession, generally the problems of that bubble burst are treated with Keynesian stimulus, increased fiscal spending to sort of
counterpunch the decline in real wages and in corporate profits. and the sentiment concern that because wages are down, people will start
spending less, which makes wages go down further and rinse and repeat. That's the concept behind
Keynes' notion of stimulating aggregate demand. And of course, the only way that they can do that
is by using the balance sheet of the government, which we're going to talk about here in a moment. So all this right now is set up. And yet, by definition, to do that from the government very
likely means deficit spending. It means adding to the national debt, which the future service
of that debt takes away from future national income. Okay, easy enough. So while you are in the midst of trying to treat
the effects of downward pressure on asset prices, downward pressure on wages, a bubble bursting,
so you're stimulating with the central bank, you're stimulating with fiscal Keynesian spending, you're trying to lower your cost of capital with easier money,
then you end up getting more people borrowing, because the cost of capital is cheaper. So that
obviously incentivize people to borrow more, which then puts a few a bigger drag on future growth,
people to borrow more, which then puts a bigger drag on future growth because there's now more debt and more borrowing, more spending means that there's less savings and investment. And if
there's less savings and investment, then there's downward pressure on growth. And this is sort of
the chain of events that I've talked about for years that I've kind of dedicated much of my
is sort of the chain of events that I've talked about for years that I've kind of dedicated much of my professional academic study to is the effects and the interactions of these different
components in a complex economy. And what I would say is that at the root of all of this,
this Japanification result always comes from some form of excessive debt and
leverage, and that the end result ends up being downward pressure on growth. That's really the
name of the game here, okay? So I would prefer to not have to get overly technical in the way we treat this. But the problem when we talk about excessive debt, excessive spending, is sometimes we're not talking about governmental debt.
So I'll give you an example. The household sector was really at the heart of what created the great financial crisis. The households of America
had levered up so much primarily with mortgage borrowing. There was other borrowing on their
balance sheet, credit card debt, student debt, auto debt. But for the most part, it was residential
debt that households were comfortable levering up because they saw the asset growing with it.
And then, of course, we know that whole story.
But there was something in the range of, oh, let's see, what was it?
$13 trillion of household debt.
And after the financial crisis, it got down to $11 trillion because there was that delevering.
And so you have throughout 2001 to 2006, a buildup of excessive absolute debt and a buildup of leverage, meaning the ratio of debt to income, got to be ridiculous.
But see, the Keynesian idea would then be to say, okay, well, let's have government spending now offset.
In other words, the economy is screwed up because households have to de-lever, but the government will counter punch with fiscal spending and offset it.
But that presupposes a sort of equilibrium that the government itself is not over indebted, overly levered.
over indebted, overly levered. And you will recall going into the new century, new millennium that we're in now, that we had something in the range of $5.6 trillion of national debt pre 9-11.
And by the time we got to the financial crisis, we were at $9 trillion in debt. Now look, people can say the Afghanistan war and the Iraq
war, and some people could say those were bad wars. Other people could say, no, we had to do it.
Others could say maybe there was some understanding to the war, but they did it in a way we don't like.
I'm not making the comment right now about what I think about the wars and the cost of the war
at all. I'm just simply saying that they cost trillions of dollars. And then on top of that,
you also had No Child Left Behind and Medicare Part D, which was passed in the first half of
that new century, of that new decade. You hardly were talking about a period of government austerity. So but of course, the debt to GDP wasn't going up that much. I believe it had gone up. Let's see here.
a 50% debt to GDP to about 60%. So even though they added trillions of dollars, they added 60% to the debt level, the leverage went up about 20% because why the GDP was growing so much through
the housing boom and all of that kind of stuff. We entered the financial crisis with a governmental sector that was really quite
heavily indebted, but nowhere near as levered as the household sector. And it's one of the
great ironies of what we face now is that at the time, the idea was, well, the government is less
levered. Let's have them fill the capital hole. So yeah, households had
$2 trillion of bad debt to wipe away. They had to sell off real estate and pay off bad debt.
Really that debt bond in the banking sector. I mean, for the households were primarily walking
away and they had to get that debt off their balance sheet, which removed the asset off the balance sheet.
And that's what a debt deflation cycle is,
is selling off bad debt
and therefore having a lot of asset impairment
while you do it, okay?
And the government was gonna have to plug that hole.
And if it was just Bill Smith down the street
and Nancy Jones down around the corner, it would have been bad for Bill and Nancy, but it wouldn't have been real bad for the whole country or the whole economy.
But because it was so many people and the real indebtedness lied inside as an asset inside the banking sector, Bill and Nancy owed the bank money.
So it's a liability to them and asset to the bank.
And now that asset's going away, therefore the government came in to plug the hole that was
created as a capital hole in the balance sheets of our banking system. So I hope you don't mind
me spending so much time to set this up, but I just think it's a very important topic. This was a conscious, policy-oriented,
Keynesian, academically defended idea. I don't believe in it. There's certain things about what
they had to do in the financial crisis I don't want to get into right now, but I'm saying this
was the concept, that you need that government balance sheet to fill in for when there's
weakness in the corporate balance sheets, or in for when there's weakness in the
corporate balance sheets, or in this case, household balance sheets. And when I right now
refer to Japanification, this is the irony, is I'm referring to excessive indebtedness
from the governmental sector, that households did a pretty successful de-levering process post financial crisis.
And yet, I just want to give you the real numbers of what we're referring to.
So we get into the financial crisis now with $9 trillion of debt.
We only had $5.6 trillion starting off the new century, 9-1111 and then we're at nine and then by the time they were
kind of done with all the medicine they were giving the economy post-financial crisis so
let's call it about 2013 and they've done QE 1, 2, and 3 and they've done zero interest rates on
the Fed side and they did the stimulus, and they've just kind of tried
everything governmentally and within this sort of Keynesian policy toolbox to address things,
then the debt levels were at $17 trillion. $17 trillion. So we went, the households delever 13 to 11. They take 2 trillion
off their debt and the federal government levers from 10 to 17. One pocket adds 7 trillion,
the other pocket reduces 2 trillion. Anyone have any problems with this math so far?
All right. I hope you see the point I'm making. It wasn't a matter of $1 filling in a
hole that was caused by another dollar. We were adding on an aggregate national basis,
massive amounts of debt. And then this is the whole point I want to make.
I wouldn't have supported it, believed in it, found it productive. Don't think it's a good
idea to pay someone to dig a ditch that doesn't need digging. I wouldn't have believed in it, found it productive, don't think it's a good idea to pay someone to dig a
ditch that doesn't need digging. I wouldn't have believed in any of that, even in the point of an
emergency, a crisis, whatever. But that's how those things are generally defended. And then
there's totally legitimate arguments to be had as to whether or not that's a good thing.
But from 2013 to 2020, we're now post-financial crisis and we're pre-COVID.
And we basically added another trillion dollars per year.
Okay.
So by the time President Obama left office, we're at 20 trillion of national debt.
When he came in, it was at 10 trillion.
About 7 trillion of that was in that post-crisis era.
Then we added another $3 trillion. Then
President Trump comes into office and before COVID, we add another several trillion dollars
to national debt. So that before COVID even begins, we're sitting at $23 trillion a debt.
$3 trillion of debt. And that is more or less explained by rewind the first 20 years of this new century. We basically added three to $4 trillion, let's call it $4 trillion of debt
before the financial crisis starts post 9-11. Then we add $7 trillion during the financial crisis in the aftermath.
Then we add another $3 trillion after financial crisis, excuse me, another $7 trillion.
And then we go into the COVID moment. You follow me? So if your head is not spinning yet,
this is when it all gets really started. Big numbers. I mean, no child's play
stuff of 600 billion here and a trillion and a half there. Then we proceed to take that 23
trillion national debt to 28 trillion in one year. And now we're sitting at 31 trillion. We've added
another three since the initial COVID year.
The CARES Act alone was about 5 trillion.
I mean, in the aftermath from there.
Okay.
And plus you had some declining revenue and other things.
But yeah, so we're at 31 trillion in debt. And that is in 23, 22 years, we went from 5.6 trillion to 31 trillion.
All right.
We went from 5.6 trillion to 31 trillion.
All right.
So does anyone believe that that happens without downward pressure on future growth?
Well, my argument is that downward pressure on future growth started at the point of financial crisis, and I believe it will continue to play out this way for many years to come.
And you say, OK, well, this is really bad.
You've really depressed me. But at least now
we're somber, we're sober, and we're ready to deal with this. The problem is my whole story
hasn't even started. Because we're not done at 31 trillion. We're debating if we want to add a
trillion or 3 trillion more per year. Okay. There are a couple of different charts. First of all,
I'm going to start right now with a chart showing you what we spend money on, because this is always
the problem that people think, okay, fiscal conservatives like David, they just want us to
cut this excess of spending. And we all know those famous stories about the Pentagon spending $10,000 on toilet seats back in the 80s.
Let's cut off all that stuff and we can deal with this.
But if you look at the chart, 60% of our outlays go to transfer payments.
That's the combination of the Medicare, we're calling safety net spending, food stamps, other entitlements,
Social Security, Medicaid, all of these could be very legitimate and necessary.
Some of them could be, again, I don't need to right now for our purposes get into an argument
about what size of a social safety net we want to have. My point is that there's 60% of our outlays
that are highly unlikely to be touched for the very nature of what they are.
12% goes to military spending. Now, people can say they wish we spent more or they wish we spent
less. But do you think with the state of NATO, Ukraine, Russia, China, Taiwan, should we be cutting from that?
Will we be?
I don't think so.
And so the 12% of military outlays are not likely going anywhere.
8% goes to national debt service, just interest expense.
That number is not likely going much lower
anytime soon. It could be going higher. It has gone higher. You're going to see another chart
later that will speak to that. And then you look at some of the discretionary things and so forth.
There's just very little wiggle room as you see in how we've spent money as to how they can really do much politically. And just in terms
of the will of the people, I remain at a total loss as to what people are willing to cut here.
Now you could do across the board spending cuts and that's kind of what I would do, but
I assure you I'm not being elected anytime soon, which is to say ever. All right. So now you look at it. Let's just
summarize how bad things are so far. We've built up this huge amount of debt. We've done a lot of
it with bad things like wars and financial crisis and COVID. And we've done a lot of it and not bad
things, just routine, huge growth of government spending programs and routine excessive spending during benign
economic periods. So 22 years of $25 trillion of additional debt, it didn't happen easily,
but we've done it. And we're looking to add more to it with increased deficit spending.
And we don't have a lot in our federal budget that looks
particularly able to be cut. Okay. So here's the issue. I'm going to put another chart up right
now. As we sit here with $31 trillion of debt, that ratio of debt to GDP, I spoke to earlier that in the first decade, when we were
spending a lot more, we were still growing the economy at such a rate. Remember, you had two
Bush tax cuts, 2001, 2003, there was a lot of juice in the economy. The GDP was growing at a rate
that the denominator was moving higher, even as debt was moving higher.
So even though we added, I think it went from 50% to 62%, but now you can see the debt to GDP ratio
has got up above a hundred percent during post COVID. It got to about 120. And now no one's
talking about that coming lower.
I would like to think it doesn't have to go a whole lot higher.
But my point is that we're now kind of baked into this place of a very high debt to GDP ratio that is clearly in that zone of putting downward pressure on future growth and future productivity.
When you look at the actual deficits now, I want to put another chart up. The spending is not going down.
Deficits are not coming in. All we're debating about is how much worse it gets, at what speed
it gets worse. And so whether you're looking at the CBO, which is where these projections come
from, the Congressional Budget Office, what the Republicans say they want or the Democrats say they want, there isn't anyone who's
talking about a balanced budget. We're just simply looking at some level of deficits that is adding
to that $31 trillion and not taking away. And again, I'm just piling on here on purpose to make the point I'm going to end up
closing us with in a few moments. You really are looking at best case numbers. I mean, I'm serious.
These are best case numbers because right now I'll throw up Social Security and Medicare.
We're not talking about the unfunded liabilities
of what needs to be paid out of the Social Security trust fund over the years,
the growth of Medicare entitlements year by year that are owed to the citizens.
Social Security and Medicare were basically about 3% of GDP 60 years ago, and they're now 10% of GDP.
And yet revenues as a percentage of GDP are the same.
So revenues to Treasury as a percentage of GDP have stayed somewhere around 15% to 18% for 60 years, and yet Social Security and Medicare have tripled
as a percentage of GDP. So there's this ongoing challenge as the growth of transfer payments and
entitlements within the economy, and you don't have a way to get more revenues to pay for it,
because you can say, well, let's get more revenue into the Treasury Department.
But only way you can do that is at the cost of economic growth somewhere else. Take a dollar
from the private sector to put in Treasury, right? They're in a pickle. Perhaps there's
knobs that can be turned, but not very dramatically. And then the final thing I'll say to pile on,
and then we'll bring it to a conclusion, is none of this includes states. None of this includes counties and cities. Now, generally speaking, their taxing
authority and their spending is different than the federal government because they can't spend
the money out of thin air that the federal government can. But there is a significant
amount of indebtedness that they have.
And primarily their indebtedness is in the form of unfunded liabilities,
usually to pensioners.
So they can't get out of those obligations.
And yet the money that has to be spent in the future generated,
then diverted to that aim of this buildup of debt represents money that
comes out of the private sector, out of economic output, out of growth. And all of these things
are part of the argument I'm making for a low growth future. And so I think you could look at
it like, okay, the $31 trillion sounds bad enough.
And what is a real serious, sober, somber approach we're going to take to deal with that?
But what I'm trying to suggest is it's $31 trillion without factoring in how much worse the Social Security and Medicare expense side goes,
without factoring in the reality of states and local municipalities are already seeing their
state their local tax revenue state tax revenue decline this is without a real major bad event
you know i don't think you have another covid pandemic tomorrow but a recession right another
shock uh uh uh external uh shock to the system there's a. There's a number of things that can make all this a lot
worse. And that's likely where you get to a different point in how we converse about this.
So what is it I'm actually saying when all is said and done? I mean, really, I'm just trying
to present facts that you can draw conclusions from. Now, if I was trying to make a political talk here
or recommend a policy prescription, then maybe this would be a great time for me to go into why
we want a balanced budget or we want more growth-oriented policies to help kind of offset
a lot of these things. And I do, by the way, feel pretty strongly about a lot of those issues and I'm very happy to interact with.
If you email me, ask questions, I'll interact on that stuff all day.
It's stuff I'm really quite passionate about.
But what I'm now saying in terms how it governs our finances is we could conclude a default is coming, but I really doubt it.
And we can conclude that a societal collapse is coming.
Some people have sold a lot of books saying that,
and some people have gotten a lot of clickbait
and newsletter doom and gloom type subscribers saying that.
It's a business model that works.
But it hasn't been very good for years and years and years
and decades and decades and decades
at actually predicting anything accurately. What I would say is that, well, by the way,
inflation, people say could be the outcome. Developed market history has kind of shown
the opposite. You look at Japan, you look at what the U.S. did coming out of financial crisis.
I don't think that you get an overheated economy out of the things I'm talking about.
I think you get one that is really deflated and stagnated by these events.
Now, maybe you get a cure because of some incredible political consensus,
a sort of societal unity that allows different tribes and schools of thought to come together
to work for consensus and compromise and the better aims of the country. Now, that might be
the most ridiculous thing I've said today. And I'm sad to say that
as one who loves this country a great deal and does believe in what ought to be a more
consensus-like process in government and just a more unified society to some degree.
But I don't think anyone listening, and certainly, you know, myself as the speaker,
believe that that's on the horizon. So I'm leaving you with two conclusions as to what I think,
where this goes. If someone says, well, don't you think that just all the blank hits the fan in 2024,
2026? I don't. I don't think it's impossible. I just don't know. I think there are two things I feel comfortable saying.
One is Japanification, low, slow, and no growth that is this whimpering effect of downward pressure
on quality of life for a greater number of people, less economic growth, less economic opportunity.
The things I do talk about quite a bit that forced me through a different paradigm in the way I approach quality
of investing. And number two is that people need to be prepared for surprises. And another word in
economic and financial and investment parlance for surprises is instability. Rates go higher
than people think at times, and they can go way lower than people think.
I really believe that those who think we should get to a five and a half or six percent Fed funds rate don't realize that that's what's going to force them back to a zero percent rate.
sensible in the two and a half to 3% range, not as high as five or six, they wouldn't have to go back to zero. But they continue on this very heavy, boom bust exacerbation. I also think
that we are totally oblivious to the level of creativity that the Fed is willing to take on.
And I think that that's a bad thing. I think that you do not want an excessively creative central bank.
And yet I imagine there'll be surprises around the creativity
of what central bank interventions come.
I think certain shoes will drop.
I think certain shoes will look like they're going to drop and not drop.
There's a lot of instability into the future. I expect that to be a permanent
paradigm for years, if not decades to come. And that is all attached to this thesis about
Japanification. I covered so much ground. I know a lot of it was wonky. I really hope you got a lot
out of it. This topic is so important to me. There's a lot of economic history in there.
hope you got a lot out of it. This topic is so important to me. There's a lot of economic history in there. It's a bit more succinct and it was delivered a little more tightly in the written
dividend cafe. If you want to go there now, read it over, look over some of the charts.
By the way, I'll close you here with our chart of the week. Just to give you an idea about one
of those variables is only 8% of federal outlays. We were spending about a billion dollars a day in interest expense.
Well, now it's 2 billion a day. Now, it's really sad to say like a billion doesn't seem like that
much money, but of course, 365 days, you can do the math. We're spending about 350 billion and
now it's 700 billion, right? You're getting close to a trillion if rates go up much more.
Now, of course, they can come down and that can move that lower. And in fact, that's one of my arguments as to why I think they will,
because I don't think they'll be able to afford that level of debt service. But if you see this
chart, how that debt service had gone so much lower and then has creeped higher, here's where
we are. So I don't say any of this to be the bearer of bad economic news. I'm not a perma bear. I am
an unbelievable bull in the ingenuity innovation of entrepreneurial talent. I believe in America's
capacity for economic growth. I believe in the God given human spirit for entrepreneurial success.
I believe in investing in all of those things
and capturing risk premium from them.
But we're being handcuffed and ankle-weighted significantly
around excessive indebtedness.
And households can go liquidate some of that debt,
but they don't have to respond to voters.
They don't have to take away entitlement benefits.
When you look to the loving hand of government to lever up, to help you out with capital
holes, you end up with Japanification.
This is the moment in history we're living through.
It's a moment in history that I very soberly plan to invest through with wisdom and poise. Thank you for listening to, watching, and hopefully
reading The Dividend Cafe. Reach out with questions at thebonsongroup.com.
Look forward to talking to you again soon from wonderful New York City. Thank you. or other information contained in this research is provided as general market commentary and does not constitute investment advice. The Bonser Group and Hightower shall not in any way be liable for
claims and make no expressed or implied representations or warranties as to the
accuracy or completeness of the data and other information, or for statements or errors contained
in or omissions from the obtained data and information referenced herein. The data and
information are provided as of the date referenced. Such data and information are subject to change Thank you. This material was not intended or written to be used or presented to any entity as tax advice or tax information.
Tax laws vary based on the client's individual circumstances and can change at any time without notice.
Clients are urged to consult their tax or legal advisor for any related questions.