The Dose - What’s Missing From the Debate About Controlling Drug Costs?
Episode Date: January 31, 2020Prescription medicines have become so expensive in the United States that we've reached a point where four in five Americans think drug prices are unreasonable. While political leaders have certainly ...taken notice, what are they doing to solve the problem? On the latest episode of The Dose, host Shanoor Seervai sits down with the Commonwealth Fund’s Lovisa Gustafsson to talk about how drugs could be made more affordable for those who bear the brunt of high prices – ordinary Americans. Gustafsson believes some important issues are missing from the drug pricing debate, including a broken patent system, high launch prices, and the lack of cheaper medical treatments.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
The Dose is a production of the Commonwealth Fund, a foundation dedicated to healthcare for everyone.
Robin is a cancer patient. She was diagnosed with multiple myeloma, which is a blood cancer.
Her treatment for this cancer is an oral chemotherapy, and it costs her $15,000 for 21 pills.
While the drug is successfully treating her cancer, the cost of the medicine could financially bankrupt her.
Hi everyone, welcome to The Dose.
You just heard from Lovisa Gustafson, who leads our program on controlling healthcare costs here at the Commonwealth Fund.
Many of you know that the prices of life-saving medicines have been going up and up for a long time.
And we've reached a point where four and
five Americans think that drug prices are unreasonable. Our political leaders have
started to notice this too, and they're looking for solutions. So today, Lovisa is going to talk
about some of the things that are missing from the debate around drug costs and how to control them.
Lovisa, welcome to the show. Thanks for having me.
So let's go back to Robin's story. Is the cost of this drug that she's facing,
is that typical for someone with her blood cancer? The story that we have encountered here with
Robin, I think, is increasingly common across all types of patients, regardless of what disease they're
facing and that they're fighting. The cost of drugs in the U.S. has increased over time and
is only projected to increase even further going forward. And what we're hearing more and more from
patients is that they're not able to afford their drugs, that they're foregoing filling prescriptions,
and that even when they are able to get the drug
they're facing financial hardships in other ways things like not being able to afford their
mortgage or declaring bankruptcy because they can't afford the care that they need
to treat their whether it's robin and her multiple myeloma or another disease that they're fighting
so is there any cheaper treatment that's available for Robin?
Yeah, the way that we've set up our system is to create basically what's called periods of exclusivity. The idea is let's incent innovation by giving manufacturers the opportunity to get
money back. And so we grant patents in which there is no competition for a drug. And basically,
a manufacturer could charge any price they want because there is no other alternative in the market but what we do after that period
of exclusivity is introduce generics or other alternatives to products that
could then compete and bring prices down over time and when that happens we see
prices drop drop drastically and that is when affordability becomes much more
available affordability is much more available.
Affordability is much better for patients, and they're able to, both for patients as well as for other payers, like the governments who help pay for Medicare drugs and Medicaid drugs as well.
So a generic drug is something that would have the same clinical benefits for Robin, but it would be less expensive.
Right. They're deemed
equivalent by the FDA and they're interchangeable even. So a pharmacist, if you're prescribed the
brand name drug, could give you the generic because they know it's less expensive.
So it strikes me if we're talking about ways in which we can control drug prices. It strikes me that allowing more generics
onto the market would be one way. Absolutely. I mean, it's definitely a tool that we have.
The FDA currently is trying to increase generic approvals and getting more of these products to
market. But in certain cases, it can be difficult, whether it be because there are extended patent periods or because there just aren't manufacturers out there that are able or willing to make a particular drug to come to market.
So let's start with the first reason you provided, extended patent periods. What does that mean? Right. So as I mentioned, we grant, the U.S. government as well as other developed countries grant
patents to drug manufacturers when they create a new drug.
And the idea here is to incent innovation, right?
If you are going to spend all that money on research and development, it takes many years
to bring a drug to market and there's a lot of risk associated with it.
So if you as a company are going to do that, you need to know that you can earn that money back
as well as some profit. And we as a society believe that's the case and we incent that
through these patent exclusivity periods. Now, in reality, that's basically a government-granted
monopoly. There is no competition. And so you can set prices wherever
you want. What we've seen increasingly is that there is really a patent strategy throughout the
lifetime of a product. So not just when you create it in the beginning and you say, hey,
I made this great discovery. Let's patent that and bring it to market. But even after it's been
on market for many years, additional patents being filed
and being granted that end up leading to very, very, very long periods of exclusivity that are
much longer than was ever intended by the original law and really longer than that was justified.
So what you're saying is that you're granted a period of exclusivity when you make a new drug,
but there are ways in which drug companies prolong the period of time that a drug is considered a new drug.
Right. So they may make a small tweak or they might get an indication.
They might get approval for a new indication.
So if the drug was originally approved for breast cancer, and later on it's approved for lung cancer, I'm making this up, then, you know, they might get an additional period of exclusivity.
There are some legit reasons why we have these incentives in place for additional patents to
be filed. But increasingly, it feels as though they're being used
just purely as a way to block competition
and to be able to not just keep prices high,
but actually increase prices over time.
When you look at the patents that have been approved
most recently, nearly eight out of 10
are actually for existing drugs.
So drugs like insulin or aspirin,
as opposed to truly novel new products.
So almost 80% of patents being granted today are just adding on to an already existing product.
So the logic that the drug should be expensive because it costs a lot to do the research and
clinical trials to bring that drug to market really doesn't apply here.
Right. And what we see in other countries is that drugs go off patent much sooner there.
In a lot of other developed countries, they have a similar practice, right? They'll have a period
of exclusivity as well. They also acknowledge this need for an incentive for innovation and
the payback for innovation, but they have shorter periods. And so while we, there are drugs that
are still on patent here and there is no competition and prices are very high, in European countries,
there's already generic alternative or other alternatives that have come to market and brought
prices down. And I mean, that ultimately comes down to what the patient has to pay. You know,
it definitely impacts our governments in terms of, you know,
Medicare budgets and Medicaid budgets, but it also very directly impacts patients when they go to the
counter to fill a prescription or they go to the doctor to get, you know, a drug administered.
Are policymakers talking about changing this extended period of patent exclusivity? Is there
a way that they could do that? There are, I think, a number of regulatory approaches that we either through the FDA
or through Congress could take, as well as the U.S. Patent Office, in terms of
making it an easier process. And so thinking about, you know, what are the standards that
you need to meet in order to be justified,
getting a new patent or getting granted a new period of exclusivity.
We could perhaps change some of those standards or perhaps make an overall length of time
in terms of how long an exclusivity period really should be.
Because at the end of the day, we're a capitalist society.
We believe in competition.
We believe in market efficiency.
This is a monopoly.
This is not a competitive market.
This is not markets at work here.
And so if we want to get back to that,
this idea of having competition is an important factor.
And I think it's important for the long term, you know,
fiscal sustainability, both of families as well as our governments.
This is actually making me think of another issue, which is
the price of the drug to begin with. Why is it so expensive?
This is another issue that, you know, people talk about quite a bit about more recently.
It's this idea of launch prices, right?
When a drug comes to market, how do you decide how much it should cost?
You know, because as we just discussed monopolies, companies can charge whatever they want, right?
They can arbitrarily pick something.
And truthfully,
a lot of times it feels quite arbitrary as to what the prices are that get charged in the U.S.
You know, people oftentimes use the term, you know, what the market will bear. But what does that really mean in health care, especially when you're talking about people who are facing life
threatening conditions? Right. What does it mean? Exactly. So, you know, kind of sky's the limit.
And that's not to say that there aren't great drugs coming to market that aren't worth a lot
of money, but we don't have a systematic way to think about what are prices and what's a fair
price for a drug. We don't have a systematic way of saying, what's the value? What's the incremental clinical benefit that this new drug that's coming to market brings?
And shouldn't the price that we pay be somehow tied to that value?
Do other countries have a way of valuing how much a drug should cost?
Just about every other developed country does, in fact, have such a process.
It varies by country. Each country has a slightly different take in terms of how they go about doing it and how they
think about what the value of the drug is. But at the end of the day, it kind of comes down to
if a drug is coming to market just because it's new doesn't mean that you should get to charge a
lot of money for it. If it's new and it's better,
then maybe you should charge more than what alternatives are.
But if it's no better than what's currently on the market
or whatever the other treatment alternative is,
whether it's a drug or a non-drug treatment,
you shouldn't get more money.
If you bring a new iPhone to the market,
you don't charge more for it because it's the same or because it's worse.
It has to have a better camera or it has to have a better battery or other type of features
that are better than the existing product and therefore you get to charge more money.
Right. And the iPhone makes it very easy for you to see.
Apple clearly publishes what they've improved in their new product so you can decide whether you want to…
Right. The bigger screen is worth it to me. We
don't have that same transparency when it comes to our drug. What am I getting by picking the
older generic that maybe is going to cost me $5 versus the new product that supposedly is better
and has a lot of fancy ads on TV for it that cost $200. I as patient, don't know what those trade-offs are. Hopefully my physician will help
me navigate that process, but it's not always entirely clear, especially when a drug first
comes to market and we don't have as much, we don't have real world evidence in terms of how
it works. You see that in other countries as well, where they say, you know, it doesn't appear as
there is actually more evidence that this is better, but we'll track it over time. If you prove over time that this actually does do
better and patients have better outcomes, patients are healthier, they're happier, they have a higher
quality of life, then we can raise your price. But you only raise prices because there's actually
an improved quality of life or outcomes in terms of clinical care. In the U.S., prices just go up over time
just because they go up every year, not because there's anything better about the drug from year
to year. So we're in this situation where prices are very high to begin with, and then they just
keep going up, up, and up, and up. If the government wants to control prices
and, in fact, bring prices down, how could you possibly
do this if your starting point is too high to begin with?
And that's, I think, one of the issues we need
to think about launch prices, because there
are a lot of proposals being thrown out there today in terms
of how can we bring prices down, or don't let prices go up more
than inflation, or hold them constant over time.
But if you're at a million dollars,
it's already a really, really high price.
And we do have negotiations.
Private plans in the US will negotiate with manufacturers
in order to get discounts or rebates
by offering that making the drug available to their patients.
But how far down can you really get in those negotiations if you're starting arbitrarily
or exceedingly high?
It's a double whammy for U.S. consumers.
Right.
It's both higher prices and those high prices last for a longer period of time.
And before we talk about the other things that policymakers are doing or what they can do in the year ahead,
is there anything else that they're not talking about that you think really should be on their radar?
You know, one other aspect which has come up occasionally but not necessarily as a central point
is it goes back to this idea of competition,
and in particular competition for some of the really high-cost drugs that are driving spending growth over time.
And what I'm talking about here are what we refer to,
they're high-cost specialty drugs.
We refer to them as biologics often.
And they are, you know,
when you hear about a lot of these drugs that are coming in the pipeline
that might
cost a million dollars or more, that's the kind of drug that I'm referring to now. And there is a
way, so that is a unique market in some ways because those drugs, because these specialty
drugs, they're very complex, the way that they're created. In fact, they're not just
like pills. They're actually technically living organisms. So it's a very complex,
it gets very scientifically complex very quickly. Way over my head.
Mine too. But there are ways to make competition for those as well. It's just a little bit more
complex. And we call that
those drugs that come to market as competition to biologics, biosimilars. The idea being is
they're very similar to generics. The concept is the same as a generic, right? But because
they're not equivalent, they have a different name. They're called a similar, biosimilar, right?
And the idea behind biosimilars is the same they after a period of exclusivity
they could come to market and bring prices down perhaps not quite as far as generics but it still
is a big price saving especially when you're talking about how expensive some of these drugs
are many tens or hundreds of thousands of dollars right so when you say tens or hundreds of i'm just
trying to think about this for an individual patient when you say tens or hundreds of thousands of dollars. Right. So when you say tens or hundreds of, I'm just trying to think about this for an individual patient. When you say tens or hundreds of thousands of dollars,
you're saying that one person could have to pay a few hundred thousand dollars a year in order to
take this high cost specialty drug. Exactly. You know, it's hard to generalize too much because
different patients have different forms of insurance and those are all designed differently. And Medicare is different than what we get from our employer and things like that. So it can vary. But increasingly, patients are facing that really high cost of the drug. You know, patients face deductibles and during a deductible, they have to pay the whole
cost of the drug. Increasingly, patients are paying, instead of paying a flat co-pay, like you
go to the pharmacy and it costs $50 for your drug, they're facing a percentage co-insurance. So you
have to pay 25% of the cost of the drug. If that's a $100 drug, maybe it's not a big deal, but if it's a hundred thousand dollar drug, that's serious money. Right. And even though there are things in place, like
sometimes out of pocket caps and things like that for the year, that doesn't help a patient in
January where we are right now, right? When you're at the beginning of the benefit year and you're
facing a really big deductible, you could face thousands of dollars in one year,
which a lot of patients, especially seniors on Medicare, don't, and they're living on fixed
incomes, they don't have that kind of money sitting around to pay for their drug. And then
you see patients, you know, not necessarily filling it or giving up something else, whether
it be, you know, buying food or, you know,
paying for their utilities in the middle of the winter.
So we're talking about serious trade-offs that people are facing here, both in terms
of what they're forced to pay over the entire year or years, depending on how long you're
on these drugs, but also it can be just, you know, a timing issue that, you know, a really
big expense in one year until
you hit a deductible or until you hit an out-of-pocket maximum for the benefit year.
And so what you're saying is with biosimilars, if we had a law that allowed more companies to bring
more similar drugs to the market, then patients would have cheaper options. So for example, when you go to
the pharmacy and if you have to pay 25% the cost of your drug, and there is the $100,000 option,
but there's also an option out there that's $20,000, suddenly your portion, what you have
to pay is much less. Exactly. And there is a law in place to try to make this happen,
to bring bios, to create a pathway for these drugs to come to market.
It just, this market hasn't flourished in the U.S.
the way that it has in other countries.
And there can be a number of reasons for that.
Part of it is that we got started a little later than, like, for example, the EU.
So, you know, you start there sooner you know but but it comes back partially to our patent system which we've touched on a number of times today but if we
have these extremely long patents you know there are drugs that are off patent
in Europe and there's a biosimilar in the market and we still are on patent
and there's no bio similar option option. So there's that.
There also are other ways that you could streamline the process,
the approval process in which companies need to go through
in order to get their drug to the market.
There could be things around, you know, I mentioned when we discussed generics
that there's this idea of interchangeability where the pharmacist can say,
oh, your drug prescribed you the brand name, but this generic's cheaper.
Let me give that to you.
There is that interchangeability.
There's a much, much higher threshold for that to happen with biosimilars.
So it's harder to get the same kind of uptake that we see in generics.
And so oftentimes, if there is a biosimilar available, a patient might not even know that it's an option. Got it. Well, it's January. It's the beginning of
the year. What's next? What can policymakers do to address something that is, as you've pointed
out multiple times today, really has a huge impact on Americans making trade-offs between should I take
my medicine or should I pay my utility bill? An option that came up in Congress last year is
around reforming Medicare Part D. That's the Medicare outpatient drug benefit that seniors
and other people on Medicare have. And so they've identified that the Medicare Part D benefit is not
meeting seniors' needs quite as much,
especially with all these new really expensive drugs that are coming to market.
There were various versions of a Part D reform that were both in the House and the Senate,
but what they would do is change the cost sharing.
It would actually reduce how much patients have to pay and would put a firm cap in place so when you hit a certain dollar threshold it wouldn't just keep going
previously there was this catastrophic threshold but patients still had to pay a portion of that
indefinitely like even if it's five percent but five percent of a hundred thousand dollars is a
lot of money so um that that that is kind of you know another is kind of a patient protection, a patient affordability type of thing,
which I think there's a lot of people see that need given the financial hardship that we've
heard from a lot of seniors in terms of being able to afford their drugs. The real concern here is
back to patient affordability. When a patient is in the deductible and they have to pay that whole price,
even if it's a 5% increase, that's 5% more that a patient's having to pay
at the pharmacy counter and that they really can't afford.
Right.
We did already touch on the government negotiation,
and that's another one that's out there.
That's not quite as bipartisan, but that is an option that's still out there that people are talking about.
And the House is interested in figuring out what might happen with that.
Well, here's to hoping for a year of some sort of reform to help solve this problem.
Yep.
Thanks for joining me today, Luvisa.
Thank you so much for having me.
And thank you everyone for listening.
If you're enjoying the show, please tell your friends about it or leave us a review on iTunes
or wherever you find your podcasts.
And if you take a medicine and you're struggling to pay for it, share your story with us.
Send us an email on thedoseatcommonwealthfund.org.
The Dose is hosted by me, Shanur Sirvai.
Our sound engineer is Joshua Tallman.
We produced this show for the Commonwealth Fund
with editorial support from Barry Scholl
and design support from Jen Wilson.
Special thanks to our team at the Commonwealth Fund.
Our theme music is Arizona Moon by Blue Dot Sessions.
Our website is thedose.show.
There you'll find show notes and other resources.
That's it for The Dze. Thanks for listening.