The Joe Walker Podcast - Australian Policy Series: Inside Immigration Policy — Abul Rizvi
Episode Date: January 31, 2025This episode is the first of my live policy salons. It was recorded in Melbourne on January 23, 2025. In this salon, we go deep into Australia's immigration policy with Abul Rizvi, former Deputy Secre...tary of the Department of Immigration. Abul managed Australia’s migration program from 1995 to 2007 and played a crucial role in the 2001 policy changes that massively increased the intake of skilled migrants—most notably by expanding pathways for overseas students. If you’d like to attend an upcoming salon, you can get tickets here: https://josephnoelwalker.com/events/See omnystudio.com/listener for privacy information.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Hi, everyone. A quick note before we begin the episode.
This is a recording from one of my live Australian policy salons.
So the conversation is held in front of a live audience.
And we have some audience questions at the end, too.
To my American, British and other overseas listeners,
you might find these Australian policy episodes a bit parochial or not.
I'm sure many of you will find them interesting,
learning about policymaking and policy issues in Australia.
So you're welcome to come along for the ride, of course.
I'll be back to my usual style of episodes
with a more international focus after this series.
Enjoy.
All right. Well, thank you all for coming.
Let me set some context for this conversation before we start.
So one of the most consequential policy decisions that
Australia has taken in the 21st century,
went largely unnoticed at the time.
In 2001, the Howard government
introduced a series of regulatory changes to
immigration policy that increased our immigration intake
to levels that we hadn't seen since the populate
and parish days of the post-war era.
Now, the Howard government didn't wanna compromise
on the skill level of migrants,
but there wasn't a deep pool of applicants
waiting to come here.
And so the innovative solution was to massively expand our intake
of international students and working holidaymakers. And the idea was that we would have these
people come to Australia, upskill, and then they would be given the chance to apply for
permanent residence. And the decision worked. In the sort of two decades since then, more
than two million international students and working holidaymakers have come to Australia,
many of them settling permanently.
In recent years, international students have made up
more than 40% of annual net migration.
And it's probably not too much of an exaggeration
to say that in Australia today,
immigration policy boils down to decisions
about international students.
Modern Australia would be unrecognizable without immigration.
About 30% of us were born overseas, which I think is the highest rate in the developed
world.
And we have one of the youngest and most multicultural populations in the developed world.
But while the fruits of our immigration policy are all around us, I realized that I knew
very little about how the system actually works.
And last year I was doing some research into immigration policy in the context of some
research I was doing on the housing crisis, because obviously immigration contributes
to the demand side of the housing market.
And that's when I realized that I knew next to nothing about how immigration policy works in Australia.
And then someone recommended that I read a book,
which I thoroughly enjoyed, called Population Shock,
written by our guest this evening.
So Abel Rizvi holds a PhD in immigration and population
from the University of Melbourne.
But before that, he was deputy secretary
of the Department of Immigration
and managed Australia's migration program
from 1995 to 2007.
And he was deeply involved
in those transformative 2001 changes.
In fact, probably one of the top two senior public servants
involved in those changes.
So he is uniquely qualified to help us understand immigration
policy.
Abel, welcome to the podcast.
Thank you.
So the way this will work is we're
going to have a chat for the next 60 or so minutes.
I'll ask the questions that I want to ask,
and then we'll open to your questions as well.
And in this conversation, I want to strike the balance between being too philosophical
and too technocratic.
And I think the risk is more that it becomes too technocratic.
And that's because there's more or less bipartisan consensus around immigration policy.
And also the system just fundamentally works.
And that's a testament to the efforts of public servants like Abul. But if we just have a conversation that sort of tinkers at the margins of the system, that's a testament to the efforts of public servants like Abul.
But if we just have a conversation that sort of tinkers at the margins of the system, that's
not going to make for a very interesting podcast episode.
So I sort of challenged myself to think, well, what are some of the big philosophical, maybe
even contrarian questions that I could ask Abul this evening?
And my first question is actually going to be more of a thought experiment.
And that is, if we go back to the end of World War II,
and Australia hadn't had the mass migration that it's had since then,
which country would we look most like today?
We would be significantly smaller, of course, probably less than 10 million.
We would be much, much older.
Our median age at the moment is about 37, 38.
And if we hadn't had that migration program,
our median age would probably be about 47, 48.
And you might think,
oh, someone in their 40s, that's OK, it's not too old.
Remember, that's the median.
So there's a lot of people a lot older than 48
if that was what would happen.
And the third thing that we would be experiencing
is that the number of deaths every year
would far outweigh the number of births.
So we would be older, smaller, and shrinking.
And we would look more or less like Japan.
Interesting. Okay, so like a smaller, whiter Japan.
That's right.
Okay. So...
And probably shrinking just as fast.
Yeah, okay. Well, I want to come back to that.
But before we get there, what do you
think is the biggest thing, the most important thing
that smart Australians, people like the members of this audience,
get wrong about immigration policy?
I think there is a tendency to think
that the government has a level of control over migration in a day-to-day
sense that we just don't. We make policy changes and the effects of those policy changes will
usually take one, two, three, four, five years before you see what happened. And so there's
a tendency to think,
oh, well, you know, Mr. Albanese's
let the immigration program blow out of control.
Well, yes and no.
Most of the policy decisions that led to the huge boom
in net migration in the last two years
were actually made during COVID and before.
This was coming at us anyway.
Where perhaps the Albanese government fell down was
that they didn't really respond to what was happening quickly enough and it reached a point
where it was at levels that they were not comfortable with, that they did not plan for, and that has consequences.
So in my view, what's happened with immigration in the last, say, three or four years in terms
of the alleged loss of control is the fault of both parties, and we will soon go into
an election where they'll both stand up and point at each other and make the assumption
the Australian public's too stupid to work out what actually happened.
So to help people sort of understand what actually happened, maybe there's another piece
of context we should add here because people might be wondering, how is it possible that
government loses control?
Isn't it the government that kind of sets the number of visas and issues those visas?
But if we think about, and I'll give sort of my understanding and then correct me if
you can edit this if I'm wrong.
So the relevant metric here is net overseas migration, which I guess the technical definition
is the number of people coming into the country for 12 out of 16 months minus the number of
people leaving the country for 12 out of 16 months, minus the number of people leaving the country for 12 out of 16 months.
And that includes both the permanent migration program and the temporary program.
And it's only the permanent program that the government caps.
The temporary program is demand driven.
So that's the international students, the working holidaymakers.
And that program probably amounts to a larger portion of overall net migration.
And so in the sense that we kind of lose control of the numbers, it's because we have all of
that demand-driven temporary migration coming in, blowing out net migration.
And that's the sort of context there for people.
That's absolutely right.
I would just add two other little groups that affect net migration.
New Zealand citizens move in and out relatively freely.
And in terms of the number of temporary migrants in Australia, they are the biggest group,
about 700,000.
The other group that people forget about that are included in net migration are Aussie citizens.
So an Aussie citizen who leaves for 12 months or more is counted as a negative on net migration.
An Aussie citizen who returns and stays for 12 months out of 16 is a positive for net migration.
In most years, more Aussie citizens leave the country long term than return.
Right.
So I want to pin you down, you Abel Rizvi, on what your principles are for migration
policy.
And I want to start by asking, what's the unit of analysis here?
So should the goal of immigration policy be purely focused on welfare for native Australians,
and then to the extent that migrants benefit, we just treat that as a sort of happy byproduct,
but it's not an end in itself?
Or should we also think about migrant outcomes as ends in themselves for immigration policy?
The two actually go together.
A successful migrant helps Australia prosper.
So there's nothing wrong with a successful migrant.
That's a great outcome.
More often than not, a successful migrant will mean more Aussies get jobs because there
are flow-on consequences from the successful migrant. So I don't see it as an Australia first or an America first type concept.
We actually benefit in both ways.
The migrant benefits, we benefit if the migrant is successful in Australia.
Right.
So that we don't really kind of, we're not really confronted by those tradeoffs, practically
speaking.
No. And I mean, often politicians will present it that way, but they're presenting it that way,
knowing they're wrong. I think most of them know they're wrong about that.
But they'll present it that way because of political advantage.
So my next question is about the sort of objectives of immigration policy. So you have,
So, my next question is about the sort of objectives of immigration policy. So you have, you know, one objective or one rationale would be slowing the rate of population
aging.
Another would be filling skill shortages.
But then you have all these second order consequences as well, like the diversity of the Australian
population, fiscal benefits of migrants.
What do you think is the right set and balance of objectives for immigration
policy?
What are we actually trying to achieve with it?
Right.
You're absolutely right.
In my thinking, the primary or the initial objective of our immigration policy should
be to, over the next 50 to 100 years, slow the rate at which we age.
We will age, we will get older, we'll get a lot older.
But if we can slow the rate of ageing, our ability to adjust to that is much better than
if the rate of ageing was very, very fast.
If we were ageing at the rate of China or Japan or South Korea or much of Western Europe,
the adjustment processes are much more difficult.
Businesses would find it much more difficult to adjust.
Government agencies would find it much more difficult to adjust.
So I think a primary objective should be demography.
And indeed, it was demography when Arthur Callwell started the post-war migration program.
He was thinking demography.
And so back in the late 90s, early 2000s,
when you were advising Ruddock and Costello
and then persuading Howard to implement the changes
that we did, how much of that decision
was about slowing the rate of population aging?
Was that the main motivation?
Probably 80% was demography.
Oh, interesting.
It would have been 80% demography.
And it would have probably been 10% pressure from universities.
We need a way of making money.
And we can't fund ourselves unless we can make money. And so we had
to open up the International Education Program. It just happened to be the case
that was the best way to also increase the migration program in a manner that
it contributed skills to Australia, it contributed export income to Australia
and it slowed the rate of aging,
and it was a budget benefit. Put all that together and it was too attractive for any
government to refuse. Right. Yeah, I've kind of thought of this as like a real stroke of
Australian policy genius, these changes, just in terms of the number of boxes that they ticked
simultaneously with that change. So in your book, you write that it took about 18 months
to get the department ready for those changes, which
they were implemented on the 1st of July, 2001.
I'm just curious, because I'm kind of interested
in questions of state capacity and just why Australia's
government is so effective, or relatively speaking.
And I'm curious what it was like inside the department at the time and whether you could
kind of take me back to those days in the early 2000s as you're trying to implement
changes that are so significant.
Can you tell me a little bit about what that was like and maybe also, I don't know, what
the biggest sort of unexpected challenge that you encountered was in terms of the implementation?
Initially, a number of ministers in the Howard government were reluctant to go down this
path.
We had, over the previous four or five years, severely constrained the migration program.
We had cut it very significantly, and the government felt that was an achievement.
And to then turn around and say,
we want to now grow the program,
was hard for many ministers.
I might even say prime ministers.
It was difficult for them to swallow.
And it took time to convince them of the merits of what we were proposing.
There were, in addition, many within government, within the public service, and indeed within
my department, who thought what we were proposing was anathema,
because to them it felt like we were losing control. And immigration departments and immigration officials
have one common feature around the world,
control, they like control.
Control is good.
And losing control is a risk.
And I, to some degree, agree with that.
But sometimes you have to take some risks to get some rewards.
But I'm interested in sort of at the level of an administration,
like what is it like trying to prepare a bureaucracy
for those changes?
So I guess to give an example of the kind of thing
I'm contemplating, we're talking about how net migration is give an example of the kind of thing I'm contemplating,
we're talking about how net migration is measured in terms of the number of people who've been here
for 12 out of 16 months minus the number of people who have left for 12 out of 16 months.
And you might wonder, well, how do we actually track and measure that?
And the Department of Home Affairs tracks passport movements.
And so we have all of these really good, almost real-time data on the movements of people
in and out of Australia that kind of then can flow through to those net migration statistics.
So things like that, I mean, was that something that specific, I don't know if that specifically
was something that you needed to prepare, but how did you sort of get the administrative
state ready for those changes?
Much of that rode on the backs of my predecessors of 20 and 30, 40 years prior to 2001.
Two decisions were made that were absolutely crucial to being able to do that.
One natural advantage is we're an island
and we're a long way from anybody.
That gives you a big advantage.
Right.
We introduced what is called the universal visa system.
The universal visa system to most people
and to most other immigration agencies around the world
was, you lot are
crazy. Why would you do that? Because you don't need to control low risk tourist movements.
You don't need to worry about that. And at the time, most countries had gone down the
path of what is known as a visa waiver program, where they identified nationals of certain countries
and said, you don't need a visa, just turn up at the airport, we'll give you a stamp
on your passport and away you go. Indeed, a few times I've been to Europe and I didn't
even get a stamp in the passport, I just, there's nobody here. You just wander in or
you drive across the border. Now,'re changing but at the time when we introduced
the universal visa system and we introduced a thing called the electronic travel authority,
just about everybody in the world now has an electronic travel authority, but when we
introduced it once again we were told you're mad, why would you spend all the money introducing
an electronic travel authority?
The reason we did it was because we wanted to have control
over who was coming in and out.
We wanted to know who's in the country and who's left.
We introduced that in the early 90s.
And we had to negotiate with a lot of countries who said,
well, if you introduce this ETA for our citizens,
we will reciprocate and withdraw our visa waiver program with a lot of countries who said, well, if you introduce this ETA for our citizens, we
will reciprocate and withdraw our visa waiver program from your citizens.
And we had to convince them that the ETA was so seamless that no one would notice.
And in fact, it turned out that's the way it was implemented.
I remember an elderly lady in the UK was coming to Australia and knew that we had a visa
system, you had to get a visa.
She'd applied for the ETA without knowing she'd applied for the ETA because the way
you applied for the ETA was you bought an airline ticket.
And the airline reservation system toggles across to our systems, checks the person off,
checks that they're not on the movement alert list, they're not a baddie, and then automatically goes back and says, tick, you've got an ETA.
And the lady said, but there's nothing in my passport.
And he said, oh, it's invisible.
It's in there.
And that made her happy.
So the Department of Immigration, as it was then called, had integrated with the software
systems of every airline
in the world.
That's right.
Jeez.
Basically every airline in the world.
Well, the airlines all operate off a common system called CETA, S-I-T-A. And we had to
integrate with CETA.
We had to talk to all the airlines who flew to Australia to make sure they understood
what was required understood what was
required and what was being changed.
But yes, essentially our movements database integrates
with CETA to run the Electronic Travel Authority.
Interesting.
OK, so you mentioned control.
I want to take a quick digression and talk about a
very specific policy issue, and then we'll kind of come back
to the main narrative about population aging.
I had a phone call this morning with Peter McDonald, arguably Australia's greatest living
demographer and one of Abel's PhD supervisors.
And I was asking him what I should ask you tonight and he said, okay, there's one question
you have to ask Abel and it is, there are about 100,000 people in Australia today
who have kind of exhausted their last resort
of obtaining a visa, the sort of run out of options.
Many of them have appealed to the,
you know, the relevant appeals tribunal,
either sincerely or otherwise,
and they're allowed to stay in the country
while that process happens.
We currently have about 100,000 people who now just shouldn't be in the country, and
we have no way of getting them out.
If you were back in charge of the department, what would you do?
What would it take to remove those people from the country?
And I guess I'm interested because I'm interested in how a former administrator thinks about
this as a sort of logistical and bureaucratic
challenge, but what would you do?
I'll just go back a couple of steps to explain how we got here.
Great.
Please.
Because it was a mistake.
We got it wrong.
The ETA and all those things we introduced, all those controls, the universal visa system,
was about not letting this happen.
What happened was in about 2015-16, we had a trafficking scam emerge, a labour trafficking
scam.
We've had labour trafficking scams many times in our history.
This labour trafficking scam was not new.
And when it started, I thought,
oh, well, we'll do what we always do.
We clamp down on it very quickly.
We identify the organisers.
We investigate.
We prosecute.
And the scam stops.
But for some reason, in 2015-16, no one responded.
And I couldn't work out why.
And it just kept on growing.
So in 2017-18, we had just under 28,000 people apply for asylum in Australia, 67% of them were from just two nationalities, Malaysia and China,
who usually generate very few successful asylum claims. And this scam just continued. And it only
slowed down when we had the international borders closed with
COVID, when the international borders reopened. The scam had stopped. But by then the backlog
of applications was so big that we had emerged asylum applications
which were essentially opportunistic rather than organised.
So we moved into a different phase.
Now that phase is moving through people
who have come to Australia under the PAM scheme,
the Pacific Labor Mobility Scheme,
and it's also moving into much more overseas students.
That's where we have it.
What would you do?
With such a scam, you've got to slow the application rate.
If you don't slow the application rate,
doing anything at the other end just doesn't matter
because the number of people coming through is very large. slow the application rate, doing anything at the other end just doesn't matter because
the number of people coming through is very large.
So you fund the primary decision makers adequately to process the application so quickly that
the organisers don't get the benefits of the work rights associated with the asylum
application.
I mean, there are still people being approved, which is fine because they meet the criteria, but the bulk of the people were not genuine.
And so the Labor government did invest more money into processing them faster, and that has
stabilised the backlog at the primary level. It's in fact come down a bit. They funded the
Administrative Review Tribunal to process more quickly and that
has stabilised the growth in the backlog at that level. I am told they have put money into pursuing
and investigating the organisers and to start prosecuting them but I haven't seen many
prosecutions yet so let's wait and see.
So they've done those three things, which are sensible, and they should have been done.
But then you have the situation of, well, what do you do with the 40, 50, 60 thousand
and growing people who have been refused but are not going to be leaving.
Now, if Mr Trump was ruling Australia, he would do what he's allegedly going to try to do in America.
I have some doubts about how that will work, but that's what an authoritarian leader would probably try to do. If I had access to such an authoritarian leader
and I had enough courage,
I would say to the leader,
this is going to cost you a fortune,
tens of thousands of mistakes will be made,
you will disrupt the economy enormously,
and ultimately you will fail.
Do you really want to do that?
Mr Trump at the moment is asking for $86 billion from Congress to do his mass deportation
and his border czar has said, that's a down payment.
I'm coming back for more after my 86 billion.
And he will be coming back for more.
They will be paying and paying and paying for a long time to try to do this, and they
will fail.
They will make any number of mistakes.
They will set up detention camps of huge size, essentially barbed wire camps with tents, probably in the desert, but huge,
of huge, huge size. You know, tens of thousands of people detained for months and months and months
in tents surrounded by barbed wire. It doesn't sound like America.
Sounds like another place in history.
And ultimately, this will fail.
So I would be saying to any Australian leader who asked me,
what are we gonna do about the 60, 70, 80,000 we've got?
I would say, don't copy Mr Trump because that will cost you a fortune and it won't work.
I would gently and very carefully manoeuvre the advice to convince the Prime Minister that you have to stop the problem growing
and once you've done that, you then have to deal with the people who are left over.
And the bulk of those people are now working in Australia.
They've been working in Australia for many years.
They have developed relationships with people in their local communities.
Trying to get them out would be a nightmare.
Find them a subtle way to give them a pathway to permanent residence.
Now the immediate reaction to that, if that hit the public, would be, oh, that's an amnesty.
You're just rewarding bad behaviour.
Well yes, but one, most of these people were manipulated.
They didn't know what they were being put into.
It was the organisers who were doing the asylum applications.
Secondly, the costs of us trying to resolve it by a mass deportation program would far
outweigh any sort of political cost where you get criticized for pursuing an amnesty.
What's the biggest component of the costs there?
Of the deportation?
What's the hardest part of the problem?
The biggest cost is undoubtedly the detention capacity.
And that's why the detention centers Mr. Trump will build will be barbed wire and with fences,
because if he built them with bricks, he would take years and years to build such huge facilities.
We're talking about essentially cities. So he'll reduce the cost
that way, but that will be the biggest cost.
Right. And so these people in Australia who are not meant to be here, who are mostly from
China and Malaysia, what was the original, what's the kind of characteristic argument
they make when seeking asylum? Is it like a religious persecution argument?
Oh, it's usually just a cut and paste
from previous applications.
Right. Yeah.
And so there are businesses in Australia
who help them facilitate this?
Oh, absolutely. Absolutely.
The labor trafficking is the second biggest
criminal enterprise on the planet behind drug trafficking.
Right.
And the people who run these operations
are rich and powerful.
Hopefully, you know, when we publish this podcast,
there might be some policymakers who will be listening to your advice.
We did one of those amnesties once. We just didn't call it an amnesty.
When was that?
In 1993, the 1st of November.
Okay. Who was involved?
Paul Keating arranged it.
And because we couldn't find a sensible name for the visa category,
we called it the One November category.
It was to deal with 40 to 50,000 Chinese students who were not going to go home.
And we didn't want to process them for asylum because that would have cost a fortune.
And we knew the outcome, so why put them through all of that?
So we found them a neat little visa category where just about everybody would pass.
And we called it the One November category, and we expanded the program and we fitted
them in.
Have we tracked their outcomes?
Not really.
But their children are very successful.
We know that.
Yeah, so there's some research that shows that second generation migrants are massively
successful.
Yes.
Especially Asian migrants.
To come back to the main narrative, I guess what's turned out to be one of the big benefits
of the 2001 changes is the huge expansion of the tertiary education sector.
Education quickly grew to be our third largest export,
and that's raised living standards for all Australians.
Back at the time, did you foresee the full extent
to which the education sector would grow
as a result of these changes?
Or did it surprise you?
It did surprise me how far it grew and how fast it grew.
It did surprise me how far it grew and how fast it grew. We tried to put in as many safeguards into the system as we could.
We didn't put in enough.
One of the safeguards I tried to introduce in 2005 was a standardised entrance exam for
an overseas student. So if you apply to become an overseas student.
So if you apply to become an overseas student in Australia,
sit the exam, if you pass, you're just about guaranteed a visa.
If you fail, you're just about guaranteed a refusal.
I think that is a very much more efficient, objective,
certain and fair way of doing things than the current arrangement,
where a visa decision maker has to decide whether you are a, quote,
genuine student. And frankly, determining whether someone is a
genuine student is hocus pocus. And as a result, you get highly
uncertain decision making. We've got to move away from that. But government, for some reason, doesn't
want to go down that path.
And the universities don't want to either.
So I feel like in the last year or two,
there's been a negative mood develop around immigration
in Australia.
And my very simplistic model of that
is that when things aren't working in the economy, when
housing costs are very high, people switch
into a sort of zero sum mindset and immigrants are the first sort of logical scapegoat.
And this is happening at the moment with respect to international students.
Could you help me understand how do you think about what's the actual effect of international
students on the housing
market?
Undoubtedly, they have an impact near universities.
So in the CBD, most of our major cities, which is where they live.
And so it does certainly have an impact there.
Working holidaymakers have an impact on backpacker hostel accommodation.
But they have very little impact in suburban Australia.
Not many overseas students live out in Heidelberg
or somewhere like that.
Yet that's where the big complaints are
in terms of housing.
Undoubtedly, they make a contribution to the demand side,
but I think much of what is being talked about
in the housing space at the moment
is a function of many other factors.
But it's easy to blame immigrants.
It's been the go-to for people for a long time.
Absolutely. I mean, they also typically live
in student accommodation
or they rent.
So they're not, I mean, maybe some international students
are pushing up home prices at the margin, but they're not,
I mean, are they even allowed to buy homes?
Yes, they are allowed to buy home.
They have to go through the Foreign Investment
Review Board process, but yes, they are.
Yeah, so maybe a tiny sliver of international students would be doing that. They have to go through the Foreign Investment Review Board process. But yes, they have. Yeah.
So maybe a tiny sliver of international students would be doing that.
I mean, most of them wouldn't be able to afford to buy a house in Sydney or Melbourne,
because of fortune.
Yeah.
Yeah.
I've noticed, yeah.
So one more economic question, and then I'll talk about aging.
So there's a debate in labor economics around the impact of migrants on locals' wages.
And in America, you have people like David Card on one side who say that
your migrants don't really do anything to push down wages. On the other side, you have people
like George Borhouse who say that they do. In Australia, maybe the closest analog to
George Borhouse might be like a Bob Burrell or someone
like that.
But where do you lean in this debate?
It depends on the circumstances, I think.
I don't think there's a simple answer.
I always start with the immigrants impact both demand and supply.
So you've always got to start with that mindset.
There will be circumstances where parts of the labour market may be oversupplied.
And the price of labour in those circumstances for some reason is being held down.
And if you inject more migrants into that portion of the labour market, yes, you could
conceive of a negative impact.
So examples here might be things like healthcare or aged care. Well, potentially, although aged care and healthcare are the two,
leaving aside construction tradies for the time being,
are the two areas where we most struggle to fill vacancies.
So, yes, they look like the type of area where you could have a negative impact if there
was an oversupply, but there is no oversupply in terms of aged care workers.
In fact, most of our aged care providers are saying, just complaining, saying we can't
find enough people.
Right.
Is that just because the government can't or won't lower wages or, sorry, rather increase
wages?
Well, the government has increased wages of,
well, it's both increased quite a deal,
Australia's minimum wage,
and it's increased the wages of aged care workers as well.
But it's still not enough.
The work of an aged care nurse or an aged care worker
is usually involved shift work.
It's difficult work. It is often backbreaking work. And it pays very little. Why would you work there if you had an option? Okay, let's talk about aging. So Australia's total fertility rate, which is the average number of births that each
woman is expected to have over her lifetime, dropped below replacement level, which is
a little bit above two children per woman in, I think, 1976.
And the last measure put it at about 1.5 so it's well below
replacement. Now we've as you you know touched on earlier we've been kind of slowing the rate of
population aging through net migration and our migrant intake are very, you know, they skew very young.
And migrants, they contribute to the number of births in Australia because they skew
young and that means that they are women migrants will tend to be in the kind of childbearing
age range.
And so they'll contribute to the births.
Imagine, you know, counterfactually, we cut net migration to zero tomorrow.
How soon would Australia cross the threshold to natural decrease, so that the point beyond
which death succeed births?
My PhD advisor, Peter McDonald, did the calculations on that thing, and he came to about 15 years.
About 15 years.
Which isn't bad.
For a developed nation to go to zero net migration
and not have deaths exceed births for 15 years is pretty good.
If Canada did the same thing, they would be at,
they would reach that point within a year or two.
Oh, really?
And so because we're cutting net migration to zero,
in 15 years, when deaths start to
exceed births, definitionally, the population starts shrinking because population growth
is a combination of birth, net migration, and natural increase or decrease.
OK, so next scenario, assume we sort of continue our rate, our current reasonably high level of net migration of I don't know, say 200,000 per year, how long until we project that into the future
and imagine the total fertility rate remains kind of where it is at the moment?
How many years until we cross that threshold into natural decrease?
If the fertility rate stabilizes at 1.5, we probably can get to the end of the century
before deaths start
to exceed births.
If that happened, and that's what's currently being projected, we would be the last developed
nation on the planet to reach that point.
We would be last.
Most of our major trading partners will get to that point or have already got to that
point.
So China, most of Western Europe, Japan, South Korea, Canada, United States is a bit of an
exception, although Mr. Trump may not remain an exception, who knows, are well ahead of
us down the aging path and down the point to reaching the point
where debt succeed births.
So if we continue these levels of migration, natural decrease doesn't start until close
to the end of the century.
How long after that until the population started shrinking? If we can maintain net migration at 200, 250,000 per annum, we can shrink slowly for quite
some time.
The problem is going to be by that point, just about every country on the planet will
have debt-succeeding births.
The most anti-immigration leaders on the planet will be developing immigration policies, and
they will be competing for people, young people.
One of the most important things I've learned from reading you and Peter McDonald is just
how to think about net migration as a demographic tool and what its proper role is as a demographic
tool. And what I've learned is that its proper role is it's not to try to reverse population aging,
but it's to slow the rate of population aging.
And the reason for that is that net migration has diminishing returns for slowing the rate
of population aging.
And this is a somewhat technical point, but could you just help us build sort of an intuition for that mechanism or the mathematics there?
Yeah. Immigrants themselves, once they've migrated, also age.
You don't say.
A very large portion of our ageing population are in fact people who migrated in the 50s and 60s. So when our aged care
homes are looking after older people, they will often be looking after the previous waves of migrants.
Because migrants age, there is a point at which if you keep increasing net migration,
the return in terms of slowing the rate of aging slows, and all you get is population
growth without much aging or reduction of aging benefit.
Peter McDonald did the calculations, and he came to about 200,000 as the optimum level
for net migration. that was at a time
where our fertility rate was about 1.8.
I suspect if he ran that model again, he'd probably come to a figure of around 225, 250,
something like that.
The other problem with pushing net migration too hard, you start to lose public confidence.
And public confidence that you have control is important.
You've got to be able to show the Australian public, we are doing this in the national
interest, we have planned this properly, and we are doing it in a controlled and managed
way.
When net migration tends to get out of control,
like it did in the last couple of years,
that's when you get public attitudes against migration
rising, you get concerns about the capacity of infrastructure
to keep up, and you get concerns about the capacity of service
delivery to keep up.
And so I would be counselling any government to be restrained about net migration above
300, and try to get it in that range that gives us the optimum outcome in terms of the
rate of aging.
That would also tend to give us the best outcome from an economic perspective, probably also
a budget perspective.
Right.
So I'll come back to aging, but quick digression, because you've raised this question of control.
My sense is that there's this consensus among the political elite in Australia that there's
some sort of equilibrium between
being very harsh on illegal immigration and then maintaining quite a laissez-faire legal
migration program.
And I seem to kind of understand from you that you think that this narrative is important
as well, that if there's a perception that the government's in control, and that seems
not to apply only to illegal immigration, but also to legal migration, then the public
will be generous and will be willing to accept relatively high numbers of net migration.
To what extent is that narrative actually true, or what are the limitations of that
narrative?
Because if I think about, say, the United Kingdom, for example, it seems like people
are growing increasingly intolerant with immigration there, even when there's a semblance of control,
because the levels are just so high or the cultural mix isn't right.
So yeah, to what extent is the control narrative actually true?
And what are the limitations on that?
Political narratives always have elements of self-interest.
So in the United Kingdom, numerous politicians have talked about reducing net migration to
its irreducible minimum, I think, and that doesn't tell you anything. What's the irreducible minimum, I think, one... And that doesn't tell you anything, you know.
What's the irreducible minimum then?
And then when the net migration turned out to be much higher
than Treasury had forecast, they say,
well, that can't be the irreducible minimum, can it?
You lost control.
And that does create, I think, angst amongst people.
Admittedly, you think, angst amongst people, admittedly fueled by politicians pursuing
self-interest.
But there is an element of truth in the fact that if Treasury forecasts net migration to
be whatever, and whatever they decided was the ideal target the government
decided on.
And they missed that target by a long, long way, which they have done in the last two
to three years.
That inevitably leads to the narrative that's now being run, not just by politicians, but
by many social commentators as well, that the government's lost control.
And I mean, to some degree, it was true.
If you forecast net migration at 200,000,
it turns out to be 500,000.
You can't say, oh, yeah, we got it right.
And it was all good.
Yeah. Yeah.
OK. No, that makes sense.
So, OK, back to aging.
So we've learned that
We've learned that if you care about population growth ultimately you have to address fertility, right?
Net migration is not a substitute for natural increase. It just helps you
It just buys you time to deal with the problems of natural decrease
This is where I found your book very pessimistic.
So there's a point where, sort of almost in passing,
you mentioned that, oh, you know,
as nations like Australia enter the fourth stage
of the population shock,
we might have to redefine what we mean by recession,
because we're just going to be, you know,
in these kind of everlasting technical recessions.
I just thought, hold on a minute, you're describing a dystopia here.
Our society is sort of predicated on continuing economic growth.
And when the size of the overall pie stalls or starts shrinking, people start fighting
over the size of their slice, cooperation disintegrates.
And so I thought, you know, I was really curious to read how you thought about this problem
of fertility declines, whether, you know, how you diagnose the problem and whether you
thought it was something we could even address or turn around.
And my reading of you in the book was that you think it's largely driven
by two things. One is the introduction of contraceptive technologies, and then the other
is increasing education and workforce participation for women. I'm curious why you were so confident
about the contraceptive technology story. Because if I look at history, the demographic
transition predates the introduction of contraceptives.
So it begins in France, they switch over to falling birth rates by about the 1830s.
And then other parts of Europe, like England and Germany, start by about the 1880s.
So just tell me a little bit about how you think about fertility declines.
There have certainly been fertility declines in history, and they've been driven by all
sorts of different things.
But since World War II, there's almost universal consensus amongst demographers that fertility
decline was a function of the accessibility and affordability of contraception and the education of girls,
both of which took off in the 60s. And you can see the impact of that across many, many nations.
Now, they're not the only two drivers, but they are the two biggest drivers. The third obvious one is financial capacity. And in Australia, I think, leaving aside the housing issue,
the next biggest challenge to keeping our fertility rate at 1.5,
and that, in my view, should be an objective of government,
don't let it fall any further,
is the issue of childcare.
For a young couple, after housing, the next biggest cost is childcare.
Because the bulk of couples work and have to work because that's the financial circumstances
they find themselves in.
Right.
Is more low skilled migration the solution to that?
I'm not sure.
I mean, is that the way...I mean, we certainly
have to staff our childcare centres and we have to think about childcare, I believe
a lot differently to the way we do at the moment.
Will that need a workforce to assist? Probably.
But I wouldn't regard childcare centres as places Will that need a workforce to assist? Probably.
But I wouldn't regard childcare centres as places of low skill.
I think what we teach a child at two and three and four and five is just as important as what we teach them in year 10, 11 and 12.
So back to the demographic transition, it seems like, correct me if I'm wrong, but maybe a better way to think about fertility declines is in two distinct phases.
And there's that first phase, the one that begins in France by the 1830s.
Whatever is driving that, we don't know.
Maybe it's something so cultural, or it's to do with the modernization process.
And then there's a second phase which drives them, drives fertility down further beginning
around the 1960s.
And that's the phase characterized by contraception and education.
OK.
Yeah, interesting.
So all right, let's talk about, I'll call it acculturation.
I don't know what the politically correct buzzword is, but how we manage having different
cultures in Australia.
And one of the things that strikes me is just we seem to be world class at this.
So probably the most multicultural developed nation.
In terms of spread of nationality, that's right.
We would be.
Yeah. We have a greater spread of nationalities than anybody else.
And our percentage is much higher.
At 30%, it's high.
To me, honestly, this just seems like a miracle that we have so many people born overseas,
we maintain such high rates of social cohesion.
If I look at the latest survey done by the Scanlon Institute, I think it has support
for multiculturalism among the respondents at about 85%.
Correct me if I'm wrong, Anthea.
And so I'm curious, if you had to sort of boil it down to one factor, what is it about
what we do or the migrants we take in or Australia that makes us so successful at acculturation?
I would start with the politics of immigration since 1945. Mr. Caldwell and Mr. Menzies didn't
agree on many things, but one thing they agreed on was the importance of immigration, and they both agreed gradually
to keep broadening the range of source countries that we were relying on.
And they maintained that.
The first Prime Minister to say immigration is too high and we need to cut it back was actually Gough Whitlam,
who at the same time abolished formally the White Australia policy. We then had Mr Fraser,
who initiated a number of reviews, including by Frank Galbellally, that led to the development of a range of settlement
services and highlighted the merits of a multicultural society.
You know, it wasn't just Al Grasby who pursued multiculturalism.
Fraser did too.
I mean, Fraser and Whitlam didn't get on, but on the issue of multiculturalism
the two are actually quite on the same page. We then had Hawke, who was a champion of multiculturalism,
and indeed when Mr Howard talked to John Laws and said we need to slow the rate of Asian migration.
Hawke went into overdrive
and introduced into Parliament a motion
proclaiming the importance of a non-discriminatory migration program.
Two, I think, or three of Howard's ministers crossed the floor, including Philip Ruddock. That was important.
That was important.
When Howard became Prime Minister, he eventually accepted the word multiculturalism and used
it in his own fashion, but he used it.
He used it.
We then had the Labor government after that, who were still supporters of multiculturalism. Through the period of
the Liberal Coalition, Mr Abbott may have been inclined to be negative about
multiculturalism but he didn't do anything about it. He didn't actively
speak negatively about it. Turnbull was a supporter, as was Morrison.
He was a supporter of multiculturalism.
And the current government has continued down that path.
That has been probably, I mean, you can talk about all sorts of settlement services
and all sorts of things that we have done that have been positive
in terms of maintaining multiculturalism.
But the key has always been bipartisan support.
Now whether in the forthcoming election we abandon that bipartisan support, I don't know.
There's a risk we could.
But ever since 45, we've had essentially bipartisan support for multiculturalism.
And that has made all the difference.
Yeah, it still feels like a mystery to me.
I want to test because I wonder whether that bipartisanship is more sort of consequence
or a reflection of our success at multiculturalism rather than a cause.
I guess it can go both ways.
But I've sort of been playing around
with an explanation recently.
I want to test it on you and get your reaction.
So I have a friend who's an academic at LSE.
He's an Aussie, his name is Mike Mudakrishna,
and he specializes in, I guess,
the field of cultural evolution.
And his explanation for why Australia
is so good at acculturation is that actually the
immigrants who come here in some deeper sense already share the same culture.
And what he means by that is they are weird.
In the Joe Henrik acronym, it's a Western educated, industrialized, rich, and democratic, more of a consciousness-raising
tool than an analytical tool, but it describes the very peculiar Western mindset, a very
individualistic, sort of reductionist mindset.
And the argument is that education, even sort of high school education, primary school education,
doesn't have to be tertiary education, but it downloads a very specific set of cultural
beliefs, ways of thinking, and assumptions that are characteristically weird in the sense
of that acronym.
And so the migrants who come here, because they're very high skilled, they share that
kind of weird way of thinking.
And so that's why we're so good at acculturation.
That's one story.
It makes sense.
It makes sense.
It could well be right.
I don't know.
I'm no expert in that.
And I guess the problem with that story is that it doesn't explain why we've been so
good at acculturation all the way back to the end of the Second World War
Because the the increase in the the skilled migrants only comes more recently in our history. Yes. Yes. That's true
That's true and the students. Yes, you know educating our own skilled migrants
Does have an advantage. Yeah, exactly because they're coming here during their most formative years
Making going to an Aussie university. Right.
They learn Aussie things.
Mm-hmm. Yeah, interesting.
Okay, so that definitely feels like it could be part of the story.
So, looking forward for the permanent skilled program,
do you think it's enough just to be young, skilled and proficient in English?
Or should we be adding in other criteria?
Our skill stream is essentially composed of about four different major groups.
The most important major group in that is the employer-sponsored category.
We always manage that on a demand-driven basis.
Essentially, it's an employer doing the selection. Yes, we have some minimum criteria,
but the selection is done by the employer based on fit for their business. I think
bureaucrats trying to fiddle with that would not be a good idea.
I think bureaucrats trying to fiddle with that would not be a good idea. I think have the minimum criteria, let the employer choose above the minimum criteria
the fit for their business.
And we know from a budgetary and economic perspective that visa category easily outperforms
all the others.
We have another two.
One is, well, they're both state sponsored.
One of them is formally state sponsored.
It's state sponsored into Metro Australia where the state does the selection above a minimum based on what the state needs.
And we have another one which is a regional category where there are concessions against the standard criteria
but people are being encouraged to settle in regional Australia for obvious
reasons. That's where our biggest demographic problems are. Once again, that's the region
selecting the migrant for the skills that they need. That's quite granular and it eliminates
the Commonwealth bureaucrat from being involved.
We then have a fourth category where the Commonwealth bureaucrat is the dominant player,
and that's the points-tested category that everyone raves about.
Yes, you could fiddle around with the points-tested category more,
and you could give this some weight and that weight and that sort of stuff.
Ultimately, it depends on the pass mark you use.
The higher the pass mark, the more likely the migrant will succeed.
The lower the pass mark, the less likely they'll succeed.
We know that from 30 years of research.
Often politicians and academics will talk,
oh, we need to fiddle around with the points test again.
I've fiddled around the points test for years.
I didn't think it made that- Favorite pastime.
Yeah, I don't think it made that much difference actually.
Okay.
So from a demographic perspective,
Japan and Australia are like night and day.
They're the oldest population in the world.
You mentioned earlier, I think their median age is over 47.
Our median age is about 38,
one of the youngest developed countries,
if not the youngest.
When you talk to Japanese policymakers,
what kind of questions do they ask you about Australia?
And what could a country like Japan,
like what could they possibly be hoping to learn?
I mean, their first problem is their politicians
have talked about the importance of monoculturalism
for so long that it's very hard for those same politicians to now say, ah, well, you
know, that was in the old days and we don't believe that anymore.
That's hard.
Making that transition is hard.
We made that transition over a very long period of time.
When Mr. Caldwell announced the post-war migration
program, he assured us one out of 10 migrants would be Brits. He knew he was lying, because
he knew there was no way he was going to get the numbers he wanted from Britain. But he
felt he had to say that. So the Japanese have to find a way, the Japanese policy have to find a way of changing the mindset
within Japan. And the Japanese people know they've got a serious demographic problem.
You don't need to be a demographer to work that out. So over the last decade,
they have been changing their visa policies quite considerably and they have a points tested category now and they have an employer sponsored category.
They also have a number of low skill categories which I think are a bit worrying.
But interestingly I was talking to the Japanese Consul General on Wednesday night.
He invited me over for dinner and we just yarned for a while.
And the thing that he was most interested in was our settlement services.
Why?
He said success in settlement is going to be the most difficult thing for the Japanese
because the Japanese culture is so monocultural that adjusting to that is a challenge for many
people coming from overseas.
The Japanese language is hard.
It's a difficult language to learn.
Whereas many of our migrants come already with English
skills, it's hard to find migrants with Japanese skills.
So they are looking at things like our Adult Migrant English program and
replicating things like that. They are looking at our settlement services programs, particularly
our funding of settlement organisations at a local level. And we've had that since the Galbalia
though probably before the Gale Valley report,
but strengthened particularly during the Gale Valley report of the late 70s.
They're starting from scratch.
So they look at what we're doing and Canada's doing in particular.
And do you predict that they will, like how far will they adopt our policies?
Oh, all the way.
Really?
Oh, absolutely.
They have no choice.
It's just a function of arithmetic.
You either become extinct or you do something about immigration.
They're not going to get fertility up from, I think they're about 1.1 or 1.2. And when your median age is 48, that is half the population is past child-rearing age,
the arithmetic looks very stark.
So Japan is set to become much more multicultural.
Absolutely, as is China.
Right, because they've got massive problems.
They have no choice.
They have the same problems.
Indeed, China probably is worse off than Japan because of its one child policy.
Too many blokes.
Yeah, it's a problem.
So I've got three final questions, and then we will hear your questions as well.
So I'm doing six of these over the next seven weeks, different salon and different policy
issue each week. And as I've been sort of reading about these next seven weeks, different salon on a different policy issue each week.
And as I've been reading about these different areas, one of the things that stuck out to
me about immigration in particular is there seems to be a lack of really good research
and writing on immigration policy in Australia.
Obviously, a lot of notable exceptions, and your book is, of course, one of them.
But if I compare immigration policy to, say, something like defense and foreign policy,
it feels like every couple of years in Australia, we produce and then debate a really good book
in that area.
Why is this?
That's a very good question.
We have gone through periods where we did invest heavily in immigration research.
In Melbourne, we created the Bureau
of Immigration Research, which was an outstanding organisation. It was sadly abolished by Mr. Howard.
But most of the money that the Bureau of Immigration Research had was incorporated back into
the department. And so we continued to have a very substantial research function. We funded people like Peter McDonald and others
to produce extensive research for us,
which was as good as anything on the planet.
But ever since we went to the home affairs model,
the research funding in home affairs
is now almost entirely focused on law enforcement.
We don't fund immigration research, and we have very few immigration research-oriented faculties
in our universities. I find that very surprising. Our universities don't want to fund them.
Right. Yeah. Is it partly a function of the sort of bipartisan support
for immigration policy?
It just doesn't seem so contentious in Australia?
I'm not sure that's it.
I'm not sure it's the contentious nature of it.
Yeah.
That although, I mean, it's becoming more and more
contentious.
You know, we may well have our first or perhaps
our second immigration election after Tampa.
And we won't be armed with a lot of research, not a lot of recent research in that space.
I think in areas like defence, the funding that's available from industry to fund defense projects and
defense research is just, they drown in money.
But there's little interest amongst business lobby groups to fund immigration research,
very little interest, or amongst universities, surprisingly enough.
Yet they make so much of their money from overseas students.
They don't want to give back to the research.
Not to immigration research.
They put it to other research.
Right, right.
Yeah, international students are like the number one funding
source for university research.
So when Gough Whitlam became prime minister,
Bob Hawke, who was then president of the ACTU, So when Gough Whitlam became prime minister,
Bob Hawke, who was then president of the ACTU,
I think famously offered to tutor him in economics
or to arrange some ANU professors to tutor Whitlam.
I can't remember which one,
but I guess this would have been over the summer
at the end of 1972.
And Whitlam, of course, declined and the rest is history.
I'm interested in, okay, so imagine an equivalent situation for immigration policy. Say a new prime minister or a new minister for home affairs calls you up and they say,
Abul, I've cleared my calendar.
I have a couple of days over the summer holidays that I just want to dedicate to building up
my intellectual capital around immigration policy.
What – only two days, so very time constrained – what books or papers or sources are you
recommending?
So what's your syllabus for them?
And you're allowed to say population.
Well, let's leave my thing to one side.
There is excellent still work that was done by Professor McDonald
over the last 30 years that I think is still worth reading.
It's still of value.
Not outdated.
Not outdated.
Well, the statistics are outdated but the concepts are not.
And I would still recommend that.
I would also recommend that the politician read the other side of the debate.
And that's probably Bob Burrell.
You notice I've named two people who are well and truly into their 80s.
Peter and Bob.
Peter and Bob.
And I would encourage them to read both sides and come to their own conclusions from that.
Because you get two very different views from two very learned academics. to read both sides and come to their own conclusions from that.
Because you get two very different views from two very learned academics.
What do you think is the strongest argument that Bob makes?
In his work, what's the thing that you find most convincing?
Well, he comes from an environmental background, and I find it hard to debate population and
environment.
I'm not an expert in that space. I don't
know how to look at issues like emissions and population, and I don't know how you
would debate that. So I would put that to one side.
Bob worries about multiculturalism, whereas Peter does not. Bob worries about people rorting the system, whereas Peter does not worry about
rorts as much. He does worry about them, but not as much. Bob is fundamentally a small
immigration person. He would like to reduce immigration to its irreducible minimum.
All right. Let's do some audience questions. If you'd like to ask a question just put
up your hand and we'll get a microphone to you. So let's start with this gentleman here.
Just while we're waiting, maybe let me ask one final question. If you could change our current immigration system in one way, completely
unconstrained by politics, what would it be? I would encourage the Prime Minister to commit
to the development and debate and adoption of an actual plan. A population plan. Yes, let's have a plan.
Now you might think, well, that's bloody obvious, isn't it?
What a stupid recommendation.
Well, we've never had one of those, by the way.
Australia's never had a population plan?
Well, we've had politicians call booklets population plans.
Mr Morrison produced a booklet and he called it a population plan.
It didn't have a single word in it about the future population.
How's that a plan?
First question.
So how do you think high immigration changes an economy?
So if you have a lot of high immigration, how does it change the broader economy and affect low skilled workers in
the context of what we're seeing around the world where people with manufacturing skills
find themselves out of work, potentially have a bit of backlash against that either in our
country and other countries.
And I ask that because there's been a bit of work that I've seen online recently about the fact
that high immigration of high skilled workers
then changes the nature of that receiving country's economy.
And just wondering what your thoughts are
and the link between those potential effects
and the wider things we're seeing in countries like ours
in the US, out of similar economies?
If you have a look at our labour force
and you look at the cohort of unemployed,
the 4.0% unemployed,
despite the fact that we say we have low-skilled shortages,
80% of the unemployed do not have a post-secondary education.
If the objective of policy is to help as many of those people into a job,
high-skilled migration is often one of the best ways of doing that,
because a high-skilled migrant inevitably will mean
they need a range of support staff doing lesser-skilled work.
I won't call it unskilled work, but lesser-skilled work.
If you hire a doctor who runs a surgery,
the doctor will inevitably have to hire two, three, four
people to support that doctor in running that surgery.
And that is the case in many respects.
Now, eventually, we'll reach a point
where it becomes just too difficult to survive without filling the
unskilled jobs. And I thought we'd never reach that point, but about 10 years ago we decided
we had reached that point. So we started some low-skill, deliberately low-skill programs to fill low-skill jobs.
The danger of that is what's happened all around the world in those sorts of visa programs,
which is just extraordinary levels of exploitation and abuse.
We thought we could run such a program successfully
without such levels of exploitation and abuse.
We thought we were cleverer than everybody else.
Turns out we weren't cleverer than everybody else.
And those programs are now experiencing
extraordinary levels of abuse. And I think we can't abolish those programs are now experiencing extraordinary levels of abuse.
And I think we can't abolish those programs now because too many industries have become
reliant on them.
But we have to fix them.
We can't just continue with that level of exploitation.
That's just unacceptable.
Thanks.
Just moving back to the question, the questions around acculturation and social cohesion, I'm curious if you think there's merit
to the idea that a country has cultural values
or cultural ideals that need to be preserved
or maybe cultivated, and if so,
if an immigration policy should in some way reflect that or
take that into account.
I'm reluctant to advocate for governments getting involved in the business of culture culture. Because that more often than not just becomes an ugly debate about what is
the correct culture. Culture is something that evolves. It develops over time. And we
in Australia, as a result of waves of migration, have adopted all sorts of little habits,
cultures, call them what you will,
drawing on what we think were things
that were attractive for us.
And we did it.
We'd go out and have lasagna and pizza.
That was a function of the migration of Italians.
Lots of foreign words keep coming into our language as a result of the waves of migration.
I have no problem with that.
I like the idea that that sort of thing evolves naturally
and is not something that is determined by politicians.
They are the worst people to tell you about culture.
Could I ask a follow-up question there? So hypothetically, say you did want to start selecting people on some kind of cultural values criteria, how would you actually implement
that? Would you put in like five points in the points test?
For the right culture? Yeah, for coming from a country that plays
in the... If you could play a good on-drive, as good
as Greg Chappell, you're in. Yeah, how would from a country that plays in the— If you could play a good on-drive, as good as Greg Chappell, you're in.
Yeah. How would you do it?
I have no idea.
Okay.
I wouldn't go there. I would be desperately trying to advise the minister, don't go there.
Okay.
Don't go there. Let the sensible Australian population work it out.
Okay.
Because they will.
It's a good question, though.
I guess I was driving at this earlier
with the question around, is it going
to be enough for skilled migrants just
to be young, skilled, and proficient in English
going forward?
But as long as our politicians behave, yes.
Right.
Thank you.
You were talking earlier,
the story about sort of integrating with CETA
was really impressive, right?
Getting kind of coordination
with the international kind of logistics.
Australia does seem to be pretty good at delivering,
especially compared to sort of what we hear out of the States,
out of the UK to some degree.
What, especially I guess within immigration and within the public sector, what do you see as kind of the UK to some degree. What, especially I guess within immigration
and within the public sector, what do you see
as kind of the secret source to our state capacity?
Is it downstream of the heavy levels of bipartisanship
or is it something else?
And did you see that change at all
over the course of your career?
We established an immigration department in 1945.
I'm not aware of any other country that
established a standalone immigration department
like we did.
And that immigration department lasted until 2015-16.
It's a long time for a department of immigration
to survive in the way it did.
Much of that immigration department was staffed by people
who began their careers in immigration
and stayed there their whole lives.
That is both good and bad.
It's good because it means people get inculcated
in the culture of the organisation.
They have great corporate memory. On the other
hand, you might say those people get set in their ways and can't change. There's always
a balance in that. But until 2015-16, no secretary of the Department of Immigration had ever said,
our job is not any longer nation building.
In 2015-16, we had our first secretary of the department that said, the era of nation building is over.
We have stopped it now.
We will have temporary migrants who will come here,
do whatever needs to be done, and then we'll, you know, toodle off.
That same secretary said the primary objective of immigration policy is national security.
That changed everything.
That changed everything. Is that still the case?
Is that culture from that 2016 secretary, is that still the case?
Are we seeing a rebound?
He's moved on for various reasons.
Some of his own making. And the new person in charge is a very, very capable public servant, a lovely
lady, very intelligent, but her background is almost entirely in defence policy. The
immigration department is now staffed by a large number of people with a background in either defense or law enforcement.
That's not how we traditionally recruited to the immigration department.
This episode is sponsored by Vanta. Trust isn't just earned, it's demanded.
it's demanded. Whether you're a startup founder navigating your first audit or a seasoned security professional scaling your GRC program, proving your commitment to security has never been more
critical or more complex. That's where Vanta comes in. Businesses use Vanta to establish
trust by automating compliance needs across 35 frameworks like SOC 2 and ISO 27001, centralized security workflows,
complete questionnaires up to five times faster
and proactively manage vendor risk.
I have personal experience here.
Startups I've worked out in the past have used Vanta
and I've always found it reliable.
Vanta can help you start or scale your security program
by connecting you with auditors and experts
to conduct your audit
and set up your security program quickly.
Plus, with automation and AI throughout the platform,
Vanta gives you time back so you can focus
on building your company.
Join over 9,000 global companies like Atlassian, Dovetail,
and FireAnt who use Vanta to manage risk and prove security
in real time.
For a limited time, get $1,000 off Vanta
at vanta.com slash joe. That's v-a-n-t-a dot com slash j-o-e for $1,000 off.
You said, sorry, I've taken over the podcast. You said earlier, as you said just before,
that we had an immigration department with a large history and people had stuck around for a long time.
Who would you recruit into the immigration department or Home Affairs now?
I think I would recruit people who actually want to work in immigration for the purposes of nation building, of helping develop our future.
They were the people I'd look for. purposes of nation building, of helping develop our future.
They were the people I'd look for.
I wouldn't look for any particular qualification.
I wouldn't say, you know, you've got to be economists
or sociologists or whatever.
I think I'd draw from a wide cross-section
of qualifications, but I wouldn't focus
on defence and law enforcement.
Some is good, but not to be dominated by that is no good.
I yield the microphone.
Thank you so much for such an informative discussion.
You mentioned briefly exploitation of migrants who come to Australia.
I'm a journalist who sometimes covers migrant worker rights.
And I've spoken to people who come here on the student visas, they cycle through on student visas
in the hope to stay here.
They experience wage theft, rate wage reimbursement.
They might get a visa that you've just mentioned there
and then they still experience these things.
Some people would say that they're rotting the system.
Others would say that the system bakes in exploitation.
I would like to know which one you think that is.
Yeah.
The exploitation problem is more often than not the hardest part
of immigration policy and how to prevent the exploitation.
The best way to minimise exploitation is to give a greater level of agency and power to the individual migrant.
The government has made some changes that enable certain migrants in certain categories, such as the employer-sponsored categories, to be able to move employer much more easily than
in the past.
And I think that empowers the migrant a little bit more and reduces the capacity of the employer
to exploit a little bit.
Penalties for exploitation have been introduced, including criminal penalties.
But in my view, the criteria for a person, an employer to be found guilty of exploitation
is now, is still so opaque that I doubt many employers will actually be penalised.
And that I suspect is a function of compromise
between the unions, who are probably asking for stronger powers,
and the business lobby groups who are asking for weaker powers.
I think we'll have to revisit that issue.
I think it is important that if an employer has exploited someone, there is a genuine fear that they
will be penalised beyond, you know, a $5,000 fine or something. That's not enough. A slap
on the wrist doesn't work.
But do you think that the system bakes this in? Because I have heard that argument from
some politicians, in fact? It's an ongoing risk, absolutely.
One of the things that was introduced
in the employer-sponsored visa was a minimum wage.
That is, you could not pay an employee below a minimum wage,
and that wage had to be cash in hand.
It couldn't be, oh, here's the minimum wage,
and by the way, I've now deducted this and this
and this and this, and you've got nothing left.
There was a lot of that happening.
Between 2013 and 2022, no, 2023,
we froze that minimum wage for absolutely no good reason.
And as a result, the risk of exploitation just went up.
Increasing that minimum wage has helped.
There isn't a single solution here.
It's a whole host of things that you have to do.
One of them is we probably need to, in my view, empower unions,
and I know people will reel back in horror,
empowering unions, empower unions to be able
to assist temporary migrants, students and others,
and enable them, indeed encourage them to join a union and get that sort of protection.
Because the exploitation of workers, we know in the last 300 years, the biggest change has been
the empowerment of unions, has enabled the reduction in the exploitation of all workers, not just migrants.
Very few temporary entrants to Australia ever join a union.
So immigration provides one of the very few ways that politicians can directly influence the electorate,
as in which people get to vote and who don't via paths to citizenship. We also find that
Sentiments towards immigration skew with age. So people who are older tend to be, you know
More anti-immigration and people who are younger more pro immigration
Do you think that if you put?
to a vote
The immigration policy that you implemented in 2001 2001 to the same voters from 2001 today
that they'd vote for?
No.
Okay, thanks.
A follow-up question because...
Luckily no one noticed we did make that change.
It was regulatory, right? It was a regulatory change, yeah, no one noticed we did make that change. It was regulatory, right?
It was a regulatory change, yeah, no one noticed.
And everyone was talking about Tampa at the time anyway.
Thank you for addressing my follow-up question, which was, as they didn't notice,
we've spoken today about the importance of governments having control,
and in your writings one of the things that commends the points system
is that the right people get in.
There are those who write the opposite.
For example, US economist Brian Kaplan in his book,
Open Borders advocates open borders.
What do you think the consequences of an open border
would be if we did just take away all controls?
By open borders, do we mean anyone who arrives becomes a
citizen? Or do we mean anyone who arrives has work rights? Or
anyone who arrives has any sort of protections? Or has access
to Medicare or Social Security?
The open borders question is complicated.
You have to answer all of those questions
to define what it is you mean by an open border.
If you just mean let people come in
and live in sort of the shadows of society
constantly exploited for the rest of their lives,
I'm not sure anyone advocates that, do they?
Some US economists do.
LAUGHTER
I mean, I guess the argument would be if it raises the welfare
of the immigrants and it raises the welfare of the locals,
why not make it possible?
Because countries are more than economies,
they are societies.
And any society does not want to have, I think,
a permanent underclass of exploited people.
That's not Australia.
It might be America, it's not Australia.
Did you have a follow-up?
Very quickly, are those people not already It might be America, it's not Australia. Did you have a follow-up?
Very quickly, are those people not already living in the shadows, in poverty?
In another country?
Yeah.
Yeah, they certainly are.
But as a public servant, my responsibility is the Australian national interest,
not other countries' national interest. What other countries do you think are dealing with migration successfully?
And are any countries dealing with migration successfully in a way which is sort of fundamentally
different to Australia?
We've gone through a very difficult period in the last decade where I think governments
have managed the issue poorly. Usually if
anyone asked me that question I'd always point to Canada. But what Canada's done over the
last five or six years has led to the situation where Justin Trudeau was accused of having lost control.
He's now lost his position.
The Canadian government now is now projecting or forecasting negative population growth
for the next two years as a result of deliberate policy. I have never heard of a government ever pursuing
negative population growth as a deliberate policy before in my life. I never thought
Canada would. But that's where they've got to now. And that suggests to me poor policy
management. They let things get out of control.
And then the backlash came and now they're saying, well, we're going to drive a million
temporary entrants and students out of the country.
Well, luckily, they've got very high unemployment, so they might succeed.
How much of it was things getting out of control and how much of it was perceptions of things
getting out of control?
No, it was out of control. It was out of control and how much of it was perceptions of things getting out of control? No, it was out of control.
It was out of control.
They went to a size of a migration program and a student program and a low-skilled temporary
program that was just excessive and did not have the right protections. Right. I was interested that you mentioned
as a policy recommendation adding an exam
as part of getting a student visa.
I was wondering what problem that would solve
and what kind of criteria policymakers looking for
in granting student visas.
Right.
At the moment, to get a student visa,
you apply and are processed against what is known
as the Genuine Student Criterion, which is a highly, highly, highly subjective criteria.
It varies according to the risk level of the individual education provider that you're
going to. So if you're going to Sydney Uni, you get a
very light touch and through you go. If you're going to a lesser university, you go through
a much more difficult process where the chances of getting a visa or not are much more fraught. And I believe that approach has three flaws.
It leaves the question of whether someone is a genuine student or not up to the subjective
judgment of a visa decision maker, and inevitably different visa decision makers make different subjective
decisions and as a result you create an enormous amount of uncertainty.
Secondly the government tried to introduce caps for individual providers. I thought that was really poor policy.
But that was the best thing they could think of to manage numbers.
In my view, having a bureaucrat determine, you know, Sydney Uni, you get 14 and Melbourne
Uni, you get...and every year we go through that process again and we decide how many
you're going to... everyone's going to get. That's just
fraught because you'll just have a massive bun fight with 1,400 providers every year
with a bunch of bureaucrats who probably don't know beyond Sydney Union, the big Melbourne
Union and everything, probably don't know a great deal about the providers. It's an awful way of doing it.
Whereas if you had someone sit an exam,
you either pass or fail.
Yes, you can have flaws in the exam and that sort of stuff.
But at least it's a standardised test.
It's what we do with domestic students,
so it can't be entirely bad.
So it gives you a standardised test,
it gives the student certainty,
it makes for better visa decision-making,
and it enables the government to control numbers
in a much more sensible and logical way
than just deciding every year,
oh, here's the magic number.
And last year they came up with the magic number was 270,000.
Never explained how this magic number was arrived at.
And then they decided how much of the 170,000
would be divided to individual providers.
That's no way to run an industry.
I have two questions,
but if we can't get through them, that's fine.
First of all, thank you so much to both of you.
It was a really wonderful conversation,
especially as a non-economist.
I have a question about the global fertility crisis.
You mentioned that the dominant belief among demographers
since the 1960s has been that the crisis
has been driven largely by female participation
in the workforce and the rise of contraceptive technologies.
And I'm wondering if you put on a bit of a contrarian hat, what do you think is
maybe the most compelling alternate hypothesis for it? Are there any that are
particularly compelling? And what would it take for demographers to change their mind about that?
That's a good question.
First, I should say I'm not a demographer.
So I just read them and I know no more than what I've read of their work. The third thesis, or the third and fourth thesis that come out are cultural.
There have been cultural changes, and I don't know the truth of this or otherwise,
in Japan and in South Korea that have contributed to this.
I don't know what those cultural changes are, but allegedly there are cultural factors that have led to women
deciding not only that they will not have a baby, but they'll remain single.
Another factor is women putting off the age of the first child, often for career education reasons or financial reasons. They're waiting
till they have a house in which they can bring up the child. That's often a factor. And certainly
in Australia, and I don't know about elsewhere, childcare comes up often as a factor. Okay, thank you.
A slightly stranger question.
You decided to take up a PhD in 2017.
What drove you to take up a PhD at that point in your career?
Well, I'd retired from the public service
and I thought two to three days a week of golf
was probably enough, and I had
to find something else to do.
Fair enough.
Some people take up hobbies, but...
Well, it was a kind of hobby.
I guess.
Okay.
So raise your hand highest if you think you have an unusually good question.
Okay, so that Jeff.
Okay, thank you gentlemen, this was absolutely wonderful.
Most, well, some of us, me in particular,
knew very little about immigration
and you've helped a great deal.
However, it felt a bit like an episode of
will all be ruined, said Hanrahan,
as in it's bleak and you want us all to go home and weep
So I was going to ask if you'd heard of a carnival at Bonkuklu Talha 13,000 years ago
You've heard of that?
First known piss-up was at Bonkuklu Talha in Eastern Turkey
13,000 years ago really with? With lots of drinking, dancing,
and we think maybe some romance as well.
So my question to the pair of you is,
could you please organize a few more festivals
and not so much depressing immigration stuff?
I can take that one.
So, well, thank you for that, Jeff.
I'll take that one. So, well, thank you for that, Jeff. I'll take that more as a comment.
But on the topic of more salons we have,
so we're back in Melbourne on the 6th of March.
We'll be here with Judy Brett
talking about Australia's political culture
and compulsory voting.
I can't promise it'll be a piss up
of the level of the one 13,000 years ago,
but should be an interesting discussion.
We've got, you know, many of you may need to head home now,
but if you can stick around and join us,
we're gonna debrief and mingle back
in the Burke and Wills room downstairs.
We have some more food coming out.
And last but not least, please join me
in thanking our guest, Abel Rizvi.
All right. Thanks, everyone. Thank you. Thanks, Abel. Thanks, mate. That was a very enjoyable
pleasure.