The Joe Walker Podcast - Daniel Kahneman — Dyads, And Other Mysteries

Episode Date: April 13, 2023

Daniel Kahneman is widely regarded as the most influential psychologist alive. He won the Nobel Prize in Economics (2002) for his work on judgment and decision-making under uncertainty, much of it don...e jointly with his late collaborator Amos Tversky. He is the author of the bestselling books Thinking, Fast and Slow and Noise: A Flaw in Human Judgment (written with Olivier Sibony and Cass Sunstein). Full transcript available at: thejspod.comSee omnystudio.com/listener for privacy information.

Transcript
Discussion (0)
Starting point is 00:00:00 Ladies and gentlemen, boys and girls, swagmen and swagettes, welcome to a new season of the Jolly Swagman podcast. This episode kicks off our 2023 season and not a moment too soon. A couple of items before I introduce our guest. First, I will be publishing episodes every two weeks. If you don't want to miss episodes like this one, make sure you subscribe to the show. Second, because you're a listener of the show, I wanted to share the good news that I'm officially an Emergent Ventures Fellow. I'm grateful to Tyler Cowen and the Mercatus Center at George Mason University for picking me in the 24th cohort alongside some truly exceptional peers. As well as getting access
Starting point is 00:00:56 to Tyler's network and support, the fellowship comes with a grant. I'll be using that grant to expand the show in 2023. That includes more video content, some live events, and trips overseas to record in-person interviews. Most excitingly, what all this means is the opportunity to expand the show's impact. And if you're a long-time listener, I also couldn't do that without you. So thanks. I don't take your support for granted. To introduce our episode, our first episode for 2023, let me begin by saying that our guest has loomed over the podcast virtually since its inception. His work, much of it done with a close collaborator, spreads through much of the social sciences like a nebula, and it's been referenced explicitly or implicitly on many, many episodes of this show.
Starting point is 00:01:46 You may know him for his best-selling books, Thinking Fast and Slow, or the more recent Noise. He is the most influential psychologist alive, a kind of latter-day Freud in terms of his status. I met Daniel Kahneman on an unusually warm winter's day in February in New York, and it was a privilege to sit with him and ask some questions I was burning to ask. Questions I don't think he's been asked in any interviews before. Danny's a mensch, he was incredibly generous to me, and a terrific conversational partner. Enjoy. Daniel Kahneman, welcome to the podcast. Pleasure to be here.
Starting point is 00:02:28 Danny, there are many qualities of yours I admire, but perhaps the quality I admire most is your intellectual honesty. And a couple of moments exemplify this for me. First was your response to the replication crisis with respect to priming. Obviously, there was a quite famous and emphatic chapter in Thinking Fast and Slow. And there's this blog post where you really graciously and humbly retract that chapter. And then more recently, there's this incredible lecture you did on the topic of adversarial collaboration for edge.org. And reading it, I was just stunned by how intellectually
Starting point is 00:03:06 honest you were. And let me quote a couple of pages from the essay. First referring to priming, you say, quote, it turns out that I only changed my mind about the evidence. My view of how the mind works didn't change at all. The evidence is gone, but the beliefs are still standing. Indeed, I cannot think of a single important opinion that I've changed as a result of losing my faith in the studies of behavioral priming, although they seemed quite important to me at the time, end quote. And then later you go on to make the general point that, quote, to a good first approximation, people simply don't change their minds about anything that matters.
Starting point is 00:03:45 And I guess my first question is, I find it hard to fathom that you can be simultaneously so self-aware and also, as you admit, and just like the rest of us, not good at changing your mind when challenged. Have you gotten any better at changing your mind as you've gotten older? No. I think I'm actually known for changing my mind. This is one of the traits that all my collaborators complain about it because I keep changing my mind. But I keep changing my mind about small things. Then what I discovered actually in part while preparing that talk on adversarial collaboration, there are things
Starting point is 00:04:33 on which I just won't change my mind. And some of these I've believed since I was 17 or 18, so certainly I'm not going to change now. And what are some of those beliefs? Well, there are tastes more than beliefs. So there is a kind of psychology I like and a kind of psychology I don't like. There are methods that appeal to me and methods that I find sort of repugnant.
Starting point is 00:05:06 Many tastes like that. I prefer, you know, among the competing psychological theories of the 20th century, there was a holistic Gestalt theory, and then there was a behavioristic theory, to which I attributed sort of false precision. And since I was 18, I had a very clear preference for the holistic over the falsely precise,
Starting point is 00:05:39 and I've kept that taste all my life. And, you know, it's just a taste. It's not any better than the other tastes. It's just my taste. I see. I see. I actually had a question around the topic of tastes, and that was, should psychologists worry less about how descriptively accurate their models are and more about adopting positions that are stronger and starker than what they might actually believe in order to contribute
Starting point is 00:06:12 to like an intellectual dialectic you know there is among matters of, there is a distinction between people who prefer to be precisely wrong or approximately right. And I'm on the side of those who'd rather be approximately right. I was married to my late wife, Ann Treisman, who was an eminent psychologist. And she very clearly was sticking her neck out all the time, theoretically, taking extreme positions. And often she was wrong. Sometimes she was wrong, but she defended those positions and found ways of defending
Starting point is 00:06:59 them. Whereas I'm sometimes not very easy to refute because I'm fairly vague, but I think I'm approximately right a lot of the time. I see. I see. Who's the most intellectually honest person that you've met or interacted with in your life? Oh, that's a hard one.
Starting point is 00:07:33 You know, I think most of the people I've interacted with have assumed they were intellectually honest. I mean, if you, and all of us, clearly ourselves, we defend ourselves. I mean, all of us are not honest in more or less the same ways. We're defensive. So I find that a difficult question because it's not a trait. You know, the default is to be honest. And I can't think of people I've interacted with whom I consider dishonest. There are a few, and I won't name them. I see. honest there are a few and i won't name them i see so the undoing project has my favorite ending
Starting point is 00:08:09 of any non-fiction book in fact i think i teared up when i was reading it but i was watching an interview with michael lewis and he said that that that story of you kind of waiting by the phone and then when it didn't ring you sort of finally allowed yourself to think about what it would be like to win the Nobel Prize and sort of what you would do and how you would do for Amos, what he had never done for you or had never had the chance to do for you. You only kind of told him that story after like seven years into your interaction with Michael Lewis?
Starting point is 00:08:40 I don't remember when I told him that story. I mean, you know, it was pretty straightforward. And the story of waiting for the phone call, it was actually quite amusing. I don't remember what he wrote about it. The true story is that I did know that this was coming up. There had been an audition for the Nobel Prize, which there sometimes is, sort of a workshop where clearly, with the Nobel Committee, where clearly they're sizing you up. And that had happened the year before, so I knew that either I was going to get it or very likely I just wasn't going to get it.
Starting point is 00:09:21 And so we were waiting by the phone, because you know when it's going to happen. And the phone didn't ring for a long time. And my wife went to exercise and I went to write a letter. I still remember a reference letter for somebody. And then the phone rang and they take elaborate precautions so you'll believe that it's not a prank. And I walked into my wife who was exercising and I told her I got it. And she said, you got what? And that was the beginning of a very exciting day. Was there anything important that the book missed? You mean Thinking Fast and Slow?
Starting point is 00:10:02 The Undoing Project? Oh, the Undoing Project. Well, you know, The Undoing Project, it's not fiction. It's nonfiction. But the characters are drawn to be quite extreme. And there are quite a few things where I would have written that differently. In what specific way? Well, there is an incident at the very end of the book
Starting point is 00:10:39 when Amos, who had been my closest friend and was then, he was like a brother to me, of course. We had been for each other, I think, the most important person in each other's life. Because we had done so much to change each other's life. And we were having a conversation. That must have been a couple of days before he died, for three days. And he said, I wanted you to know that anybody I've known, you're the one who caused me the most pain. And I answered without hesitating, ditto, the same. And Michael couldn't bring himself to write that.
Starting point is 00:11:30 He softened this, although I had told him ditto. I was quite annoyed with him because the ditto was, that expressed our interaction. Of course, Amos expected me to say ditto, and we went on and talked as if nothing had happened. I see. So that's the kind of thing where, that's the one thing actually that I felt Michael shouldn't have done. Huh. So when you say that was characteristic of your interaction with Amos,
Starting point is 00:12:08 is that like an Israeli thing or was that special about your interaction? I mean, it's an Israeli thing, but we were really very close and very open with each other. So it didn't come as a huge shock when he told me what he told me, and I'm sure it didn't shock him to hear my answer with the kind of interaction we had. I have some questions I really want to ask you about the concept of great partnerships. And speaking here about great partnerships, like world-class partnerships, as opposed to merely
Starting point is 00:12:51 good partnerships. So, you know, Watson and Crick, Lennon and McCartney, Amos and Danny. In a strange way, I almost feel jealous of your partnership with Amos. Like, I wish that I, I hope that I can find that at some point in my life yeah i i think you're right to be jealous it's an extraordinarily fortunate thing when it happens yeah so i want to ask whether we can systematize the formation and and maintenance of of world-class partnerships, or whether, on the other hand, there's just something kind of mysterious and ineffable and unpredictable about them?
Starting point is 00:13:33 Well, I mean, it's clearly unpredictable, and I'm not sure that it's the same everywhere, although quite possibly it's true for the better ones. And the mechanism in my interaction with Amos, I think, what happened was that very often he understood me better than I understood myself. So there is a stage in creative thinking when you say things that later turn out to be important, but you don't yet understand what you've said. You have a glimmer. And he would immediately see through the fog of what I was saying much more clearly than I did.
Starting point is 00:14:22 And that is an intense joy, and it also really allows a kind of creativity that a single person doesn't have. Yeah. And was that the key way in which you were complementary? Were there any other ways? Oh, I mean, we were complementary in many ways. We had different styles. Oh, I mean, we were complementary in many ways. We had different styles.
Starting point is 00:14:49 I was better at intuition, I think. He was better at precision, and that was very clear. At the same time, I could understand his precision, and he could appreciate my intuition. I had a lot of precision, and he had a good intuition. So it was, but we were to some extent, you know, we were different people, although we could complete each other's sentences. Have you read Montaigne's essay on friendship? I must have done when I was a child, but I wouldn't remember.
Starting point is 00:15:22 There's this lovely passage where he talks about his best friend. They only became friends as adults. His best friend's name was Etienne de la Boetie. Oh, Etienne de la Boetie. Oh, yeah. Yeah, yeah. Okay. Yeah, he's obviously famous in his own right.
Starting point is 00:15:39 Yeah. And there's this lovely line where Montaigne is trying to articulate what made their chemistry so special. And he says, I feel that it cannot be expressed except by replying because it was him because it was me. And that, that reminded me a little bit of, of your partnership. That is beautiful. And indeed, there is something, you know, that feels unique about the interaction. But at the same time, it was fairly clear where it was happening,
Starting point is 00:16:17 that, you know, why we were. And clearly we were better as a pair than either of us was. You know, we did good work individually, separately, but the work we did together clearly is one step beyond. And in a combination of sort of amusing, amused creativity and a fair amount of precision, and that combination really came from the interaction. Yeah so that leads me to our next question and that
Starting point is 00:16:52 is are pairs the fundamental creative unit? So all else being equal would it actually be better just to have two people working on a problem or a new idea than say three or four? I think it would be very unlikely to. It would be very difficult to imagine, you know, a threesome interacting in that particular way. So, I never thought about it that way, but I'm inclined to agree that this particular kind of interaction where you build on each other and you improve each other in the interaction, that feels like a pair interacting.
Starting point is 00:17:55 Yeah. There's this really cool book. I actually have a copy there, which maybe I'll give to you at the end, called The Power of Two, about this idea. But I was also reflecting on it in the context of, so as I told you before we started recording, I'm interviewing Katalin Kariko tomorrow in Philadelphia. She actually did her work in partnership with a guy called Drew Weissman at the University of Pennsylvania.
Starting point is 00:18:19 And they worked together intensely for almost a decade, but only as a pair. And that was because they couldn't get grant funding to support more researchers joining their team. But I think if you reflect on it, it probably turned out that that was a good thing for their research. Yeah. Uh, you know, I mean, uh, I thought later of the work that I, you know, I did quite a bit of work without, but, but I always had the feeling that if I'd done it with him, it would have been better.
Starting point is 00:18:58 Hmm. Hmm. So should, should researchers should startups think more about where possible creating teams of two, as opposed to adding more people to a problem? I'm not sure that, you know, that teams can be created by somebody else. I mean, teams have to develop and pairs have to develop. But as a unit, taking two people, that I think may be a good idea. And you may want a team that consists of several pairs. It's not. Right.
Starting point is 00:19:45 Because two is not, for many projects, two isn't large enough. Yeah. There are some things that can't be done by two. Sure, sure. I'd like to talk about rationality. So in my view, and obviously the view of many others, your work with Amos is a knockout blow to the idea that von Neumann and Morgenstern's theory could be a description of real human behavior. So homo economicus is clearly descriptively inadequate.
Starting point is 00:20:14 Is it also inadequate as a norm? Or how has your thinking on the correct normative model of rationality changed over time? Well, you know, it's important to see what consistency of beliefs and preferences, which are the essence of rationality in that model, it's important to see what it implies. And it's not the same thing as reasoning correctly, that is of having two of the same thing that are consistent with each other in the same conversation. It's that your beliefs, the whole system, your beliefs and preferences taken one at a time make up a consistent system. And that is psychologically a non-starter. And that's simply because our beliefs and our preferences are so context-dependent, and the context is highly specific and momentary,
Starting point is 00:21:14 that this type of consistency is not conceivable. And being inconceivable, it's not a very useful norm either, in principle. I mean, Amos and I never, we, let's put it this way, there were many attempts to create a looser model of rationality that would accommodate certain paradoxes of choice. And we never believed in that. That is, we never thought that there would be an alternative, sort of more tolerant model of rationality that would be usefully descriptive. So that never tempted us. Yeah, interesting. Okay, so do you have any kind of hunches as to what a better normative model of rationality would be? No, I mean, I don't use the word.
Starting point is 00:22:12 Right. And I really prefer to avoid, for me, rationality is a technical term. Yeah. It is rationality in the von Neumann-Morgenstern or in decision theory or in economics. And that's it. Otherwise, I think I would ask people that they be reasonable because rational, that word is taken, so far as I'm concerned, and it's taken in a very precise way by something that is descriptively
Starting point is 00:22:43 a non-starter. Right. taken in a very precise way by something that is descriptively a non-starter. Right. So does that, without putting words in your mouth, does that imply that the sort of rationality versus irrationality debate is just not very useful? Well, you know, it's been very productive. I mean, there are debates that will never be resolved, but they're sort of exciting. It sounds like an important issue to debate whether man is rational, or man-humans are rational or not. It sounds like a worthwhile enterprise.
Starting point is 00:23:20 And a lot of good stuff came out of that. Our work, to a very large extent, came out of taking a stance against the idea that people are against the technical definition of rationality. So some debates can be productive without any hope of resolving them. And I think the rationality debate belongs to that class. Yeah, I guess it's all about the dialectic. Yeah. So I want to ask some questions about an evolutionary approach to biases and heuristics. Are you familiar with Corin Achapella's experiment on the endowment effect among the Hadza? I probably saw it, but you'd have to remind me.
Starting point is 00:24:12 At this stage, I don't store experimental results as well as I used to. No, no worries. So the Hadza obviously being one of the last hunter-gatherer societies on earth who live in North Tanzania. And in the experiment, participants are randomly given one of two colored lighters that they use to light campfires. And then they're given the opportunity to exchange the lighter for one of a different color. So in similar experiments on Western populations, as you well know, because you've done some of the most famous ones, about 10% give or take of people trade whatever object or item they're given. But for
Starting point is 00:24:54 the Hadza in this experiment, they traded about half of the time, 50% of the time, which is what you'd expect for perfectly rational traders. So there was no endowment effect, although there was some endowment effect for Hadza living in more market integrated camps. And so my question is, to what extent are biases and heuristics the products of culture rather than biology? Well, that separation of culture and biology is tenuous. I mean, they clearly are in interaction. You can clearly overcome a lot of biological tendencies through culture. I mean, you know, we do not act naturally, you and I, in this situation. Our interaction is conditioned by culture.
Starting point is 00:25:47 And I can readily see that in certain cultures, you might have a norm of exchange where the polite thing is to exchange and not to hold on to what you have, even if people's tendency, and I think that's true of babies, when you try to snatch something from a baby, there will be a reaction. I mean, the baby hangs on to, and so in a certain way, I think people don't like losing things that are under their control. And I do think it's very likely that there is an asymmetry between the importance of grabbing something that you don't have and the importance of holding on to something you do have.
Starting point is 00:26:36 And that's, that's how I think of the endowment effect. I don't think of it as a law of nature. I mean, clearly it's possible to overcome culturally. I see. But the cultural norms are kind of overriding the biological programming. You know, I think there have been experiments.
Starting point is 00:27:00 I mean, you know, it's very clear that other animals, there are some instances of trading among animals, but it's not very common. I mean, the primary typical animal response is to hang on to what you have. Should evolution be the unifying theoretical framework behind the heuristics and biases research program? There have been attempts along those lines to say that, well, if you assume that we have evolved to be as good as we can be, then if we have biases, then the biases must be functional. I don't much see the point of that
Starting point is 00:27:58 because I think of biases of judgment and the heuristics that lead to them, but I think of biases of judgment and the heuristics that lead to them. But I think of biases of judgment as side effects of the kind of mental operation that in general works very well. But it's an inevitable side effect of the way that we do things. So I wouldn't segregate the biases and the flaws as a separate thing that you need a separate mechanism to explain there is a mechanism that mostly explains behavior that is quite functional but under predictable conditions it leads to predictable errors But if some cultural norms can override our biological programming, and earlier when you were talking about the distinction between culture and biology not being so clear,
Starting point is 00:29:00 you were maybe gesturing at dual inheritance theory and gene culture co-evolution. Well, I was, but I must say this kind of thinking has never been part of my thinking. I have never found it particularly useful to the kind of thing that I was doing. It has sometimes been used to defend rationality. In those claims that people are ecologically rational and that they're adapted to their environment, this may or may not be the case.
Starting point is 00:29:41 That's not the way I think about it. So that's one of those matters of taste that we were talking about. I see. I guess I think more of Joe Henrich's research than Gigerenzo's here. Well, they don't exactly have the same position, but if you start from the point of view that what people do must be good, otherwise they wouldn't be doing it, that can lead you to find some productive research. And I think it has led Gigerenzer in some productive directions. Heinrich, his emphasis on culture, again, is extremely compelling, but it doesn't account for everything. And I think you can exaggerate the extent to which everything is culturally changeable. So there is here a difference, for example, between preferences, we were talking about the endowment effect earlier, and judgment and heuristics of judgment.
Starting point is 00:31:11 And the preferences, well, they're preferences. You want one thing or you want another, it's fairly straightforward. In judgment, there is an issue of complexity and of truth and of achieving, understanding reality the way it is. And it sometimes demands a level of complexity that we don't have, that people don't have. So those are very different issues, whether you can overcome changed preferences by culture, that's one thing. Whether you can improve people's judgments by culture, much beyond where we are, you know, where educated people are today, that I think is very doubtful, simply because culture, it is not going to change the limits of our attention. It is not going necessarily to change the fact that there are limits to our computational ability.
Starting point is 00:32:16 So there are limitations that culture, that are constraints so far as culture is concerned. And they impose limitations, I think, on how much can be accomplished or how much can be improved by thinking about culture or viewing every flaw as a cultural fact. I think many flaws in our reasoning are responses to the fact that our brain is limited. Okay, so speaking of improving people's judgments, do you predict that as AI systems are developed and adopted, they will reduce the effect of biases? And do you think that they'll kind of consistently reduce the effect of biases, or will some biases be impacted more than others? Well, I think anybody who tries to predict how the AI story will develop…
Starting point is 00:33:17 There is a saying in Hebrew that prophecy was given to fools, and I think really forecasting the developments of AI makes very little sense. One thing that we can be fairly sure of is that collaboration between humans and AI doing the same thing, like diagnostician with a diagnostic tool, with an AI diagnostic tool, which is an ideal that many people have in mind about the future of AI, human-AI interaction. I think that is very unstable. That is likely to be unstable because if you have a human and an AI operating at approximately the same level, the AI is going to be better than the human in very short order simply because the ability of AI agents, AI, artificial intelligences, and they all report and teach each other. They all learn from each other's experiences.
Starting point is 00:34:33 So this is something humans cannot match. So anything that we predict about how humans are going to control AI, I wouldn't venture to go there. Okay, so I actually have some questions about prediction, prophecy, and forecasting. So I want to ask you about reference class forecasting, and maybe you can, in your answer, firstly, I guess, explain what that is.
Starting point is 00:35:04 But my question is, how do you go about defining the correct reference class because say if you're trying to make a personal forecast ideally the best reference class would contain people identical to you but then obviously the sample size is just one so how do you like how do you choose the scope of the reference class well um first let's define our terms, you know, with what the reference class is. So, and I don't know a better way of doing this than telling the origin story of that idea in my experience, which is that many, many years ago, like 50 years ago approximately, I was engaged in writing a textbook with a bunch of people at Hebrew University, a textbook for high school,
Starting point is 00:35:58 teaching of judgment and decision-making. And we were doing quite well. We thought we were making good progress. And it occurred to me one day to ask the group how long it would take us to finish our job. And there's a correct way of asking those questions. You have to be very specific and define exactly what you mean. And in this case, I said, hand in a completed textbook to the Ministry of Education. When will that happen? And we all did this. And another thing I did correctly, I asked everybody to do that independently write
Starting point is 00:36:46 their answer on a slip of paper and we all did and and we were all between a year and a half and two and a half years but one of us was an expert on curricula and he and I had, I asked him, you know about other groups that are doing what we are doing, and how did they fare? Can you imagine them at the state that we're at? How long did it take them to submit their book? And he thought for a while, and in my story it blushed, but he sort of stammered, and he said, you know, the first place, they didn't all have a book at the end. About 40%, I would say, never finished,
Starting point is 00:37:39 and those that finished, he said, I can't think of any that finished in less than eight years. Seven, eight years, and not many persisted more than 10. Now, it's very clear when you have that story that you have the same individual with two completely different views of the problem. And one is thinking about the problem as you normally do, thinking only of your problem. And the other is thinking of the problem as an instance of a class of similar problems. And in the context of planning,
Starting point is 00:38:19 this is called reference class planning. That is, you find projects that are similar and you do the statistics of those projects This is called reference class planning. That is, you find projects that are similar, and you do the statistics of those projects, and it's absolutely clear. It was evident to us at the time, but idiotically I didn't act on it, that that was the correct answer, that we were 40% likely not to succeed.
Starting point is 00:38:54 Because I also asked a friend, a curriculum expert, I asked, when you compare us to the others, how do we compare? And he said, we're slightly below average. So the chances of success were clearly very limited. So that's reference class forecasting. Now, how do you pick a reference class? In this case, it was pretty obvious. I mean, we were engaged in creating a new curriculum, so that effort is. In other cases, when you are predicting the sales of a book or the success of a film,
Starting point is 00:39:26 what are the reference class? So if it's a director and he's had several films, is the reference class his films or similar films of the same genre or whatever? And there isn't a single answer. I mean, the answer is actually, you you asking how do you choose the reference class. My advice would be, and today I'm not the expert on that. The expert on that is Ben Flitberg at Oxford. And I think what he probably would tell you
Starting point is 00:40:06 is pick more than one reference class to which this problem belongs. Look at the statistics of all of them. And if they are discrepant, you need to do some more thinking. If they all tend to agree, then you probably have got it more or less right. In making predictions about the future, the reference class could also be,
Starting point is 00:40:34 I mean, you could think of it as like the prior probability in a Bayesian formula. Is that like an inappropriate tool in a context of radical uncertainty? Well, I don't know what you mean by radical uncertainty. So a context where you don't know what all the possible outcomes are, let alone have the ability to attach probabilities to them. Then I don't understand your question. So, okay, maybe let me try and explain it another way. So are you familiar with Jimmy Savage's distinction between small worlds and large worlds?
Starting point is 00:41:21 Yeah. And so small worlds, like, well, you know, in like simple terms so small worlds like well you know in in like simple terms small worlds like worlds where you can look before you leap large worlds you have to cross that bridge when you come to it um so i guess like quintessentially large worlds would be like choosing a romantic partner or macro economy or you know the chances of war between china and the u. US in two decades. Is reference class forecasting like a category error in those contexts? Well, I mean, there are experiments on that type of forecasting. Phil Tittle and Bob Mellows have those experiments where you ask people questions with considerable uncertainty of the type of what's going to happen. Now, when you're looking at the distant future,
Starting point is 00:42:15 people succeed so little that it's hardly worth talking about. When you're talking about the intermediate, you know, relatively short-term predictions, some people are quite good at it, probabilistically. And these people quite often do look for reference classes, and they do look for more than one. This is part of the standard procedure of superforecasters. No, there is a good way of doing it. There's a better way. There's no good way of forecasting that will give you a very high degree of success in complex problems,
Starting point is 00:42:54 but you can do better than others. Let me ask you about super forecasting. So as you alluded to, Phil Tetlock's research suggests that up to a horizon of about six months, you seem to be able to help people make better forecasts. But beyond that, as you said, Danny, the future is just shrouded in the mists of uncertainty. Presumably, that time horizon of roughly six months isn't etched into the laws of the universe. So do you predict that it'll shrink, say, to like two or three months or whatever, if productivity growth picks up for a sustained period of time and society becomes more dynamic?
Starting point is 00:43:39 Like, in other words, should we short-fill Tetlock's ideas as innovation or complexity increases? Well, that's a very interesting question. What you remind me of is the claim for which there seems to be a lot of evidence that, at least in the domain of technology, change is exponential. So it's becoming more and more rapid. And it's clear that as things are becoming more and more rapid, the ability to look forward and to make predictions about what's going to happen diminishes. I mean, there are certain kinds of problems where you can be pretty sure there is progress and you can extrapolate.
Starting point is 00:44:26 But in more complex prediction questions, at a high rate of change, you really have no business, I think, forecasting. So I want to ask you about bubbles, and my question is how you weigh the relative importance of cognitive biases like the representativeness heuristic, which has had a big impact on behavioral finance because it provides a natural account of extrapolation versus social biases and things like conformity, hurting, memetic desire? Well, I wouldn't know how to answer this question. I mean, clearly, both are important. I mean, clearly, you could get bubbles from either one of these alone, and very likely both of them are operating. So there is a strong tendency for people to look where other people are going
Starting point is 00:45:29 and to go the way other people are going. This is the herd tendency, and it clearly exists and is clearly powerful. It's also the case that people extrapolate much too easily. And they see trends and they sort of, it's not that they expect them to last forever, but they expect them to last more than they're actually likely to last. That almost defines a bubble. So both of these could explain bubbles by themselves, and both of these are probably operating.
Starting point is 00:46:07 And how to weigh their importance, I wouldn't know how to do that. Right. And maybe the stories that tap into and reinforce the extrapolative tendencies are spread socially as well. Yes, clearly. I mean, again, the distinction is not clear. Why is everybody running and how did that begin? And it's not an accident. It is something that people have in common to begin with. Okay. So because I'm an Australian, I'm really interested in the link between national culture and innovation, but specifically between an egalitarian national culture and innovation.
Starting point is 00:46:53 And what's interesting to me is that you've lived in both the United States and Israel. And the United States is relatively inegalitarian, but obviously incredibly innovative, the home of Silicon Valley. And Israel is famously egalitarian, like a culture of debate and criticism. People aren't always so respectful of elders or people in positions of authority. But it's also super innovative. It's famously the startup nation. And so, I mean, firstly, do you agree with my characterization
Starting point is 00:47:31 of the cultural differences between the two nations? And what is the link between egalitarianism and innovation? Well, I mean, what you can definitely say, I think, is that where people are intimidated and the culture of intimidation, a culture of fear, a culture of conformity, of extreme conformity, is unlikely to be optimally innovative, although you find a lot of innovation in high conformity cultures. It's not. I don't define the distinction of the difference between the United States and Israel in terms of egalitarian or non-egalitarian. If it's in terms of questioning authority, there's a lot of questioning authority in
Starting point is 00:48:41 the United States as well. So there's probably more of it in Israel. Right. You know, you question everything. You suddenly question each other more. You push each other more in Israel than you do in the United States. And to some extent, when you look at creativity in Israel, you think, oh yes, this is Israeli creativity in the sense that these are people who,
Starting point is 00:49:16 the fact that other people haven't been successful at doing something just doesn't intimidate them. They think they're better, and if they try to do it, they're going to do it. So there is that kind of arrogance which drives a lot of innovation. So it's, oh, sure, I can do it. It's a piece of cake. That is in the spirit of the...
Starting point is 00:49:41 I think it's more Israeli than it is American. It's not an essential condition for creativity. It's a type of creativity. When you look at it, you say, oh, they're creative because they are like that. But you can be creative in more than one way. And creativity doesn't line up with arrogance. Yeah, I see. You mentioned lack of respect for authority being important.
Starting point is 00:50:12 We could potentially distinguish two types of authority. There's authority in terms of elders and tradition, but then there's impersonal authority at governments and institutions. In Israel, is there a lack of respect for both types of authority? I mean, it's not... I don't think that they question institutions more than in many other countries. It's more at the individual level. I see.
Starting point is 00:50:44 I mean, these days you're seeing a lot of ferments in Israel, but... Yeah. Because in Australia, there's like not a lot of conformity. We're a highly sort of individualistic, weird society. But there is a lot of, like famously, a lot of sort of individualistic, weird society. But there is a lot of, famously, a lot of obedience to impersonal authority, quite similar to Germany in that respect. I feel like that is somehow connected to extreme versions of egalitarianism, which people often call the tall poppy syndrome.
Starting point is 00:51:22 I'm speculating here. Yeah, I don't have speculations on that okay so let me ask you some questions about noise so in noise uh you cast and olivia anticipate seven major objections to noise reduction strategies. And I want to get your reaction to a possible eighth objection. So there's this book, I'm not sure whether you've heard of it, called Seeing Like a State by James Scott. Yeah, I read it actually. Oh, wow.
Starting point is 00:51:57 Okay, awesome. So in the book, as you know, Danny, he talks about legibility and one of the key ingredients for authoritarianism is highly legible states. States where things are well-organized and indexed, which allows governments and possibly even totalitarian powers to better exert their control. Obviously, one example of this that he discusses in the book is Holocaust survival rates. And he discusses some evidence around the fact that the greater legibility of the state, the worse it was for the Jews. So in the Netherlands, one reason the Jewish,
Starting point is 00:52:43 according to Scott, one reason the Jewish survival rate was low was the Netherlands, one reason the Jewish, according to Scott, one reason the Jewish survival rate was low was the Netherlands had very accurate census records. And so I guess the potential objection here is that noise reduction strategies increase legibility and open societies and countries up to possible exploitation by people with totalitarian ambitions. I'm conscious that that comes across as a very paranoid objection, but I just wanted to get your reaction to that. Well, you know, you're thinking bigger than I do. When I think of noise as a phenomenon, I think of it within a particular system where there is variability of opinions that really shouldn't exist and that is costly or damaging or doesn't serve a purpose. want certain kind of judgments to be shared, that you want to reduce the noise of, say, in sentencing by judges.
Starting point is 00:53:53 Those are narrow, specific objectives. I don't quite see, I don't go as far as saying that if you control or reduce noise in some specific cases, because noise is always in a specific system, the way that we define it, that's thinking very big indeed to think that noise reduction is going to cause those problems. I don't quite see the... We're not at the first stage of people recognizing that noise is a serious problem. So before noise reduction becomes a serious societal problem, we've got a long ways to go. Okay. Maybe that's an objection for a few decades. All right, I'll save it. For a few decades of considerable success in noise reduction effort,
Starting point is 00:54:48 which I do not foresee. Right, right. And why are you pessimistic about noise reduction efforts? Well, I'm pessimistic about everything. So that's not... That's not... Because noise reduction efforts, they're quite costly. And they're costly when you have individuals doing things and following their intuition.
Starting point is 00:55:20 They have a feeling that they're expressing themselves and a feeling of individuality and so on. And by emphasizing that you want people to reach similar judgments, you're doing something potentially that people will resist. People don't like to admit that there is noise. And the very existence of variability is surprising. And the essential thing about noise as I see it, the insight to me, was that every one of us, each of us is in a bubble where, and I think I see the world as it is, as I do, because that's the way it is. We have what the late psychologist Lee Ross called naive realism. We see the world the way it is. And if I see the world the way it is, I expect you to see it in
Starting point is 00:56:26 precisely the same way as I do. That turns out not to be the case. It turns out that the variability among people in how they see complex things is much bigger than any of them can see, because each of them feels that they're seeing reality the way it is. That to me is the interesting problem of noise. So we were talking earlier about the difficulty, if not impossibility of forecasting the distant future. And I want to try and tie that into this discussion of noise. So let me try to do this.
Starting point is 00:57:09 So in the book, you argue that in any organization, in any specific context, there may actually be an optimal level of noise. And you write that, quote, whenever the costs of noise reduction exceed its benefits, it should not be pursued, end quote. And I guess that raises an interesting question as to how we cope with uncertainty where it might be hard to quantify costs and benefits. So say in an evolutionary system like entrepreneurship and startups or science or the common law where there's benefit to noise
Starting point is 00:57:46 because it generates variation which then can be selected, it's difficult if not impossible to know ex ante which variations will prove to be the most successful. And so if I try to give a concrete example of this, like maybe you want to improve academia. And so take the awarding of academic grants. Maybe you want to introduce a rule to reduce noise in the judgments of who gets grants. A rule that says you should award grants to researchers with lots of citations or whose
Starting point is 00:58:26 ideas seem promising according to some other metric. But it's just really hard to know which ideas will turn out to be important. So doesn't this just sort of collapse back into the debate of how to quantify uncertainty? Well, in granting in particular, I mean, there are systems where a certain level of unpredictability is important. Scientific grants are a good example of that in the sense that we don't know what we don't know. Some randomness could potentially be useful, and at the same time, a lot of randomness makes the system radically unfair. so finding a balance and it may not be a matter the question is whether
Starting point is 00:59:29 currently things are biased one way or the other way whether there's too much noise or not enough I think there is too much noise in granting but I agree that if you eliminate the noise, if you had rigid rules about
Starting point is 00:59:49 what gets granted, then society in the long run would lose quite a bit. Yeah, I guess my question is maybe more specific than that. And it's just like, how tractable is a cost-benefit analysis when you're dealing with uncertainty if that's the framework for judging the optimal level of noise I haven't thought much about this problem, so I don't have crystallized thoughts. The question is whether there is any sensible way of quantifying the costs and the benefits in a system like that. I don't know enough about how one would quantify success and how one would define the goals of the system.
Starting point is 01:00:52 So I wouldn't know how to do cost-benefit analysis on noise reduction. I have just a few miscellaneous questions and then a final question. These are high variance questions. Some of them might provoke interesting answers. Some of them maybe not. You and I are similar in that we both finished high school at the age of 17. Do you think on average boys should actually finish a year later than normal rather than a year earlier? I've heard success stories both ways.
Starting point is 01:01:49 Something has happened. I mean, it just reminds me of the fact that this may be dependent on culture and on time. So when I grew up, rushing to adulthood was the norm. You were rushing to adulthood, you were rushing to adulthood was the norm. You were rushing to adulthood. You were rushing to financial independence. You had to take responsibility for your own life. And I look at my grandchildren. They have all the time in the world.
Starting point is 01:02:16 And I can't quite, you know, I think they're blessed because, you know, they feel protected. And that gives them time and they feel safe. I think it's quite wonderful. I don't completely understand how they can be so patient because I wasn't at their age. As you know, Nassim Taleb argues that we underestimate tail risks. Does that contradict prospect theory?
Starting point is 01:02:47 Well, no, I would say. In prospect theory, you overweight the low probabilities which is one way of compensating now what Nassim says is and correctly is you can't tell you really
Starting point is 01:03:17 cannot estimate those probabilities and in general it will turn out it's not some of the probabilities, it's the consequences. The product of the probabilities and consequences turn out to be huge with daily events. I see a prospect theory doesn't deal with those,
Starting point is 01:03:39 with uncertainty about the outcomes. So what Nassim describes, as I understand it, is you get those huge outcomes occasionally, very rarely, and they make an enormous difference. This is defined out of existence when you deal with prospect theory, which has specific probabilities and so forth. So prospect theory
Starting point is 01:04:12 is not a realistic description of how one would think in Nassim Taleb's world. Certainly not a description of how one should think in Nassim Talib's world. I see. Does that diminish the descriptive't think prospect theory is as much as scripted. I think of it as a bunch of ideas.
Starting point is 01:04:54 And really it's quite interesting when you look at the way formal theories like prospect theory play out. So they are valuable for one or two ideas that actually travels well and get completely detached from the rest of the theory. So loss aversion is an idea. Overweighting low probabilities is an idea. Thinking of reference points and changes rather than final states, those are ideas. It turns out that in order to be able to state
Starting point is 01:05:37 those ideas in a way that will influence thinking, you've got to pass a test of, now you've got to develop a formal theory that will impress mathematicians that you know what you're doing. Constructing the theory, so far as I'm concerned, this is very iconoclastic what I'm saying now, but constructing a theory, like prospect theory, is a test of competence. It's not, and once you demonstrate competence, what makes the theory important is whether there are valuable ideas that can be detached from it completely. So it's not that the theory is valid. Some ideas are more or less useful.
Starting point is 01:06:24 And that's the way I think about it. I see. I see. Are there any subfields or results in psychology that have weathered the replication crisis so far but you think are very vulnerable? No, I can't think right now of any area. You know, the thing that is most striking about the replicability crisis is how the field has responded.
Starting point is 01:07:03 And it's extraordinary. I mean, the improvement and the tightening of standards that have occurred in the 10 years, and it's exactly 10 years since the crisis began. You know, the way psychology is done, scientific psychology is done, has really changed top to bottom. It's a different field.
Starting point is 01:07:28 And that's what's impressive to me. And so the field as a whole is much less vulnerable, I think, than it was to those kinds of mistakes. That's good to hear. Okay, so my final question is you famously left the happiness literature um you you kind of realized that people are very confused when they talk about happiness and just wasn't a particularly tractable problem to work on. Have you learned anything else about happiness and the experiencing
Starting point is 01:08:09 and remembering selves since abandoning that project? What have you learned about the good life since then? I haven't completely abandoned that project. In fact, the latest paper I've done is an adversarial collaboration on happiness. All right. I had a particular idea, which turned out to be wrong, and then that's what happened. I had the idea that you want to measure emotional experience, and that what people think about their life is not all that important.
Starting point is 01:08:52 And I thought that this is normative weight and that this is a way of maybe redoing the happiness literature. And then I realized that the basic flaw in this is that people by this don't want to be happy. This is not what they really want. They really want to be satisfied with their life. They want to have a good story about their life. And so, and at the same time, clearly the quality of experience is relevant, They want to have a good story about their life. And at the same time, clearly the quality of experience is relevant, but I didn't know
Starting point is 01:09:31 how to go on from there. And I was not impressed by the measurements that were available. There was a lot of talk about 20 years ago of measuring well-being. And there has been a lot of improvement, but it has not been along the lines that I was thinking of then. I mean, I wanted to measure experience. In fact, what has taken hold
Starting point is 01:10:00 is a definition of well-being in terms of life satisfaction, which there's a lot of progress in that field, especially in the UK. And there are some very interesting things happening. And this was one area where probably my pessimism was exaggerated. Better things have happened than I would have imagined 20 years ago. Right. So how specifically have your views changed since then?
Starting point is 01:10:38 Well, you know, as I said before, they haven't changed all that much. I mean, I'm still interested in experience and I'm still interested in emotions. But what is happening is an actual movement towards having happiness as a criterion for social policy. And I can see, I can see this developing. It's beginning. And the key figures in this, I think, is somebody who is not well-known, not as well-known as he should be in the US,
Starting point is 01:11:29 and that's my friend, Lord Richard Layard. And he is really the driving force behind a movement, especially in the UK, towards giving happiness measurement a role in policy that it hasn't had using happiness for cost-benefit analysis. So there are exciting ideas. There's a book by him and a colleague coming out within the next couple of months,
Starting point is 01:11:58 which I expect will have a lot of impact. Awesome. I'll look out for it. Yeah. Danny, thank you so much. It's been an honor. It's been a pleasure. Thank you. You're a very good interviewer.
Starting point is 01:12:16 Thanks so much for listening. Two quick things before you go. First, for links, show notes, and the episode transcript, go to my website, thejspod.com. That's thejspod.com. And finally, if you think the conversations I'm having are worth sharing, I'd be deeply grateful if you sent this episode or the show to a friend. Message it to them, email them, drop a link in a WhatsApp group. The primary way these conversations reach more people is through my listeners sharing them. Thanks again.
Starting point is 01:12:45 Until next time. Ciao.

There aren't comments yet for this episode. Click on any sentence in the transcript to leave a comment.