The Joe Walker Podcast - Eight Things I Learned From My Aussie Policy Series
Episode Date: May 11, 2025I share the 8 biggest things I learned from my Australian policy series. The conversations totaled more than 12 hours of discussion. Grateful to my guests and to everyone who attended the live events.... Was really fun to meet and hang out with you all!See omnystudio.com/listener for privacy information.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Hey everyone, I'm doing something different this episode.
This is a compilation of the biggest things I learned from my 2025 Policy Salon series.
A quick recap, during the first few months of 2025, I hosted seven live events in Sydney
and Melbourne.
For each event, I sat down with an expert guest to discuss a different Australian policy
issue ranging from immigration and housing to taxation and defense.
Altogether, the series totaled more than 12 hours of discussion.
In this episode, I've stitched together just eight excerpts that taught me the most.
My two criteria for choosing the excerpts.
Number one, I only chose ideas that surprised me,
things I didn't know before the discussion.
If you've listened to the whole series, you might choose different insights for yourself.
You might find mine either too naive or too niche, but that's fine.
Everyone has their own set of prize. I can only share what I've learned. Second,
these are strictly on the spot learnings.
They're not insights I picked up while preparing for the conversations.
They're things I learned in the room during the chat.
So with that, let's begin. So first up, one of the most under discussed policy problems in Australia,
at least outside of education policy circles, is the long slide in high school math and literacy
scores. In this excerpt, I'm speaking with Andrew Lee, a member of the federal Labour government and a former ANU economics professor.
There are several plausible explanations for Australia's declining test scores,
but Andrew shares a surprising one that I hadn't appreciated.
If educational outcomes crucially depend on teacher quality, maybe Australia
had better quality teachers on average in the past because of gender pay
discrimination, which meant that talented women chose teaching. And when that discrimination
receded, teaching wages never kept up. And I was kind of shocked to learn that
at least since mid-century, we've been doing poorly on math and literacy scores and then since the early 2000s our PISA
scores have been deteriorating as well. So what explains this? What is going
on with Australian test scores? So one of the challenges is that we had a way of
getting very talented teachers in front of Australian kids throughout the 1960s and 1970s.
And the main way in which we did that
was rampant gender pay discrimination across the professions.
The consequence was that you had very few talented women
going into law, into medicine, into dentistry,
and you had lower quality service in all of those fields as
a result. Just as you'd get if you kept half of the talented applicants out of any occupation,
you got worse doctors, worse dentists, worse business people. Where did those talented
women go? Well, overwhelmingly they went into teaching and nursing. And that meant that the caliber, the academic aptitude of those going into teaching in the
1950s and 1960s was artificially increased.
Now through the 1970s and 1980s, you had a reduction in gender pay gaps and in the rampant
gender pay discrimination in those other sectors. Gender pay discrimination is legal
before the equal pay cases of 1969 and 1972.
And there's a change in norms as well.
It sees a lot of reduction in gender pay discrimination
in those other fields.
Talented women then flow into those fields.
And the question is, what does teaching do as a response?
Does it significantly increase the wages
in order to continue attracting the same level
of academic talent that it has beforehand?
No, it doesn't.
Indeed, there's teaching wages slip a little behind
the wages of other professional occupations.
So you see this in the academic aptitude of new teachers.
Chris Ryan and I look at trends from the early 80s
to the early 2000s and some other evidence,
although not quite as good in the decade since.
So that's, not surprisingly, correlated
with Australian test scores going backwards to the
tune of somewhere between half a year to a year of achievement over the course of the last couple
of decades. Which is that's huge, right? Yeah, no, it's massive, right? So the OECD's PISA test
comes into test year nine. Year nine, so the typical year nine now is scoring about where
the typical year eight student would have
scored back at the start of the century.
Next excerpt comes from my Sydney conversation with Sam Roggeveen, director of the Lowy Institute's
International Security Program and author of The Echidna Strategy. Sam argues that the
US won't fight China for strategic dominance in Asia because the US lacks any vital interests
in the region.
One thing I learned in our conversation, which didn't appear in Sam's book, is how little
America's intellectual or cultural leaders seem to care about China in contrast with
the all-consuming anti-Soviet mindset of the Cold War. Since China's rise as a great power really began in the early post-Cold War years, no
American president has stood before the American people and said that this is now our national
mission.
This is now the thing we devote the entire country to.
And that's what it would take right in your
Introduction you you you pointed to the fact that no other power or constellation of powers has ever approached 60% of American GDP
China's well past that figure. So this is a much bigger challenge than the Cold War in most respects
and economically already a bigger challenge than China than
Imperial Japan and Nazi Germany.
So it would take a whole of nation effort, not just whole of government, whole of nation, bigger than the Cold War.
And you can't do that on the quiet. You can't just sort of slip that in. It can't be just a beltway project.
It has to be a whole of nation effort. And that starts with the American president saying
to the public, listen, we've got to put our shoulders
to the wheel and do this now.
And none of them have done that so far.
One other sort of straw in the wind that I would point to
that's not in the book, but it's worth actually adding.
I wish I'd thought of it at the time,
but it came to me much later.
The intellectual environment in the time, but it came to me much later. The intellectual environment in the US, to me,
does not indicate that the United States is primed for a contest like this. It's not there
in the popular culture. I don't see for it just as one indicator, I don't see popular commentators like Joe Rogan obsessed with China.
And the intellectual heft is not there either. So look, my bookshelf's grown under the weight
of American scholars, think tankers, political advisors,
military analysts writing books about China,
and the Foreign Affairs,
which is the sort of in-house
journal of the American foreign policy establishment,
is chock full of articles about the China challenge
and the China threat.
But I don't see it coming from beyond that Beltway crowd.
I don't see David Brooks and Ross Douthat, just to name two,
writing books about the China challenge.
It doesn't resemble the Cold War in that respect,
where Cold War liberalism was an entire, you know,
school of thought, an entire genre
that developed in the Cold War.
Samuel Moyn wrote a book about it recently.
It doesn't even compare to the war on terrorism,
where you had figures like Andrew Sullivan, Christopher Hitchens,
Paul Berman, Michael Ignatieff, the New York Times editorial page, all obsessed with this
question of, well, how do you maintain a liberal democracy in the face of the radical Islamist
threat?
I don't see anything like that in the United States at the moment.
So the intellectual ferment is just not
there to support the scale of the challenge that the governing class in America claims to be
embarking upon. My next excerpt comes from another Sydney conversation, this one with the economists
Richard Holden, Professor of Economics at UNSW, and Stephen Hamilton, professor of economics
at George Washington University.
We discuss Australia's state capacity.
State capacity refers to the ability of governments to achieve their policy goals.
In preparation for this conversation, I worked with the economist Peter Bowers to produce
a literature review of Australia's state capacity.
We found that Australia has one of the highest levels of state capacity in the world.
Steven Richard are two very smart economists and friends of the pod.
And I hadn't yet had a chance to discuss just how they thought about
Australia's level of state capacity until we had this conversation.
So I was very curious to hear how they thought about that question.
In the excerpt that follows, there's no one big aha moment,
but a series of four different insights I picked up
speaking with them about this question for the first time.
Those insights include that if you take out sheer spending,
Australia might start to look like number one in the world
on state capacity.
Second, how voter expectations create pressure
for competent service delivery. Third, how voter expectations create pressure for competent service delivery.
Third, how Australia's political system makes it easier to get things done.
And then finally, how Australia's egalitarian culture means that wealthy people don't opt
out of the bureaucratic state in Australia in the way that they do in America. You had to boil it down to the most basic scarce resources, traits, factors that mean
Australia has relatively more state capacity than say, I don't know, the median developed
country.
What are those scarce factors, traits, resources?
Just say quickly, I have a conjecture about that.
But I looked at this excellent research about and I wasn't familiar with these indices,
but I was sort of like, hang on, like, I'm surprised to see like Sweden or Norway and
you know, Australia's behind, you know, we're fourth, but you know, they're high.
And I think a lot of those indices are really sort of saying, well, if the state does more,
it gets a higher score.
So I tried to recut some of those a little bit. And I got Australia coming out pretty
much first, undeniably, if you said like, we've made a political decision about what
we're going to do, how well do we do it? So I think we're kind of like number one. But
in any case, what makes that the case? I think there's a lot of things that go into it. I
mean, one, we pay people who work
at like Surface New South Wales a lot more
than people who work at the DMV in Houston, Texas,
or Boston, Massachusetts.
But I think probably the biggest thing is
we have come to expect it in Australia.
And we think of our administrative state
as like an Apple product. It's meant to come out of the box and work.
And if it doesn't, someone, a politician,
gets in trouble for that.
So, you know, if your Medicare claims
weren't getting processed, someone's gonna,
you know, be grumpy about that,
and someone's gonna pay for it.
I went to service New South Wales this morning
with my daughter to do a certain thing.
And there was a lot of demand and they were under pressure,
but it worked really quickly.
It worked really effectively.
It was like, it just works.
And I think if people had had to wait an hour,
when I first got a driver's license in the US,
in Boston, Massachusetts,
so this is a big wealthy town in a big, wealthy state.
And it took me from the time that I had to get there
to queue up to the time that I'd been processed
to all I had to do was, you know, like, take the test
to get a license that would allow me
to go take the actual driving test.
It took eight hours.
If that happened here, like, Chris Minns would be out
of a job by the end of the week. Right? actual driving test took eight hours. If that happened here, like Chris Minns would be out
of a job by the end of the week, right?
Oh, yeah, ABC would be on about it,
Shari Markson would be on, everyone.
It would be a bipartisan across the board
shellacking of somebody.
You know, or I guess the Transport Minister
already got run out of town this week,
so they'd find somebody,
probably would be Mink in this case.
So I think when you come to expect
as bit what Steve was saying about equilibrium,
the equilibrium is we expect it to work.
So there's a deviation from that.
There's gonna be punishment.
Nobody expects it to work in the US.
I was like, yeah, the pot, I mean in Chicago,
like there are potholes in the roads everywhere.
It's a wealthy town, right?
And people just go like,
oh, you should expect to get a flat tire
like once a month here from hitting potholes. When I moved And people just go like, Oh, you should expect to get a flat tire like once a month here from hitting
potholes. And when I moved there, I was like, What do you mean you get a flat tire once a month? Well, that's just how it
works. Like they all have been a corrupt and blah, blah, blah. And we just come to expect it. And so I think we expect a
lot. And if you don't get it, then there's trouble. And so we've created an equilibrium with really good political
incentives.
really good political incentives.
So I think you should think, and this is consistent with that,
but I think you should think about
what are the barriers to getting legislation passed?
In order to have smart gate
or single touch payroll or any of these things,
it may not have been legislation,
it depends how it was passed, but ultimately the parliament approved it. Right. And so
I think you ought to ask, why does the parliament approve these things?
Or delegate the authority to it. So I don't know what would have happened to happen for
smart gate or single touch payroll, but it may well be that a relevant administrative
agency just has the authority to do that. But you know But in the US, maybe Congress doesn't delegate that authority.
No, there is a system.
I think in Australia, there are just fewer barriers than in many places.
I mean, a lot of this stuff would happen with supply through the budget process.
And that was only ever blocked once, as far as I remember.
We just pass the budget every year. Now some
pieces of legislation are passed separately. But a lot of the
budget measures just get passed through, they just get waved
through, right. So we have a system where the legislature and
the executive are one, right, which is very different to where
I live. Where basically the system is designed to literally,
literally designed on purpose
to prevent the passage of legislation, right?
And that just takes, I mean, I'm sure, you know,
that just, the friction's just lower, right?
We just do it.
And I think it means that if people, you know,
if Richard's right and people have preferences
for those sorts of things,
there are just fewer impediments
for the system to deliver them.
That's also important, not just on spending measures,
but on revenue measures.
It's very easy for Australia to raise revenue.
So the equilibrium point makes sense,
but for me, it just pushes the question back one level
because it doesn't explain why our administrative state was so
effective to begin with such that those expectations developed. Is that just due to randomness
or?
Yeah, I mean, the cheap answer is it's path dependence and it was due to randomness. I
think I have a sense that it was kind of more important for Australia than some other countries
to have highly functioning administrative state in some areas.
Now, why is that in say Medicare versus other things?
That's maybe a harder answer, but go to Steve Smarr.
So when Steve said, you know, I said,
are you here?
And he said, yeah, you know, it's 30 minutes, blah, blah,
blah, the anecdoty related.
I said, you know, a smart gate's awesome.
It's a good example of state capacity.
And then I said, and you know why we have that, I reckon,
is because we get a lot of money from tourism,
a lot of Australians travel,
and a lot of high profile business people in Australia
travel a lot, and almost all of them fly commercial.
Like in the US, wealthy people kind of have opted out
of the administrative state in a major, major way,
which is they don't give a crap about the TSA because they fly private.
They don't, you know, they live in communities where they have their own garbage collection.
They have their own trash collection. They have their own security.
They have their own police forces. I mean, it's like they've opted out and there's just no pressure for it.
I think we have this maybe isn't about state capacity, it's more about service delivery.
But if I think about the fact that we have a health care system,
and I've written about this quite a bit before, which is, you know, we have all these, I think,
excellent carrots and sticks for people who can afford to have private insurance.
But everyone has a stake in Medicare
because it's the baseline for everything
in our healthcare system.
So really wealthy people, not so wealthy people,
we're all subject to Medicare.
A lot of people, not everyone,
but even a lot of people who send their kids
to very fancy and expensive private high schools
send their kids to the local public school until the end of sixth grade.
We have maybe not a perfect stake in public education in Australia, but a lot of us feel
like we have a stake in public education.
I think Australians across the board, across the income spectrum, across the... it's related
to income, you know,
wealthier people maybe have more time or more power or more
privilege or whatever you want to call it, to be able to
intervene when they see stuff not going right. I think we've
got that balance really right. And it's, I contrast it with,
it's not like single payer like France, say in our healthcare
system, it's this hybrid, but it's not the
disaster that is in the United States.
And I think you can ask why is Medicare in the US, which for older Americans, that's
got very low administrative costs, seem to work very well, even though it exists in a
totally dysfunctional health care system.
They actually kind of works pretty well.
Why?
Because if that didn't work well, you get voted out of it.
Why is Trump not gonna cut that?
Because that's political suicide.
So I think some of those elements are kind of true
as to how we got there.
And I think those things have been important for Australia.
One is about tourism and travel and stuff like that.
Some of that us stuff, I think it's just important
as to how we see ourselves.
We see ourselves as we wanna have universal healthcare,
but not single payer universal healthcare.
That system leads you to the kind of thing
that I described with those kinds of equilibrium properties
and those kinds of political incentives.
That's my take.
So if we take Richard's point from that last excerpt,
that Australians have high expectations
of government, it still doesn't give us a deep explanation of where those expectations
come from.
Richard made the follow-up point that these expectations might flow from, for example,
the kind of healthcare system we've chosen for ourselves, but then that too requires
explanation.
I'd submit that the dark matter of Australian state capacity,
the stuff that operates quietly in the background
to make it all work, is something to do with our culture.
There are two long running and intertwined cultural strands
that seem relevant here.
The first is Australia's egalitarianism,
and the second is our deep faith in government.
If you're interested, I've written an essay on these two strands,
which you can find on my website, www.jnwpod.com.
In the next two excerpts,
I'll share something I learned about each of these two cultural strands.
First, we return to my conversation with Andrew Lee.
I asked Andrew about the historical explanations for Australia's remarkably egalitarian culture. I offer Andrew two plausible stories for that culture, and Andrew adds a third, which I
hadn't properly appreciated.
The role of the gold rushes in the mid 1800s, which attracted a massive amount of immigration
to Australia, shook up Australian
society like a snow globe and diluted hierarchies.
So where do you think Australia's egalitarian culture comes from historically? So I can tell
at least two stories. The first story would be the kind of story we find in Manning Clark, which
is that there was a limited supply of labor in the early days of the colony. So land is plentiful, labor is scarce,
and accordingly workers have a relatively more even balance
of power with capitalists,
certainly much more so than in Europe or North America.
The second story is that when the colonists leave Europe
to set up a new settlement,
whether that's in Canada, America, or Australia,
they kind of carry a shard
of the European political culture with them
that gets frozen at the time.
And so when America is setting up
their political institutions,
the dominant political philosopher is probably John Locke.
By the time Australia is doing the same,
it's Jeremy Bentham.
And so there's much more kind of,
much less, you know, Gladstonean liberalism and much more kind of Benthamite utilitarianism in the air that's kind of flowing through to our egalitarian ideology. Which of those two stories seems more important to you in explaining why we have this egalitarian culture? Or am I missing some kind of other story?
why we have this egalitarian culture, or am I missing some kind of other story?
So I think your first one is the more important,
and I'll add one more, a third theory.
In Australia in the 1800s,
you have a country in which labor is scarce
and land is plentiful.
It's almost the opposite to what you see in Europe,
where it's possible to drive down wages
because there are many, many workers around to do the job.
Whereas when you get to Australia,
you simply can't mistreat your workers
because there's not very many of them.
And so as a result,
you see a lot of the early trade unions forming here,
the eight hour day emerges.
In the 1800s, workers in Sydney are earning significantly
more than their counterparts in Chicago and London
because workers are more scarce.
I'm kind of less attracted to the theory of political philosophers,
but I do think that one other factor is the role of the gold rushers.
So the gold rushers are a moment where essentially luck determines your wealth.
And so regardless of the skills that you have or the hierarchy that you've occupied, you're
able to make it based on the chance of whether your particular plot has enough gold in it.
That shakes things up, as of course does migration.
When countries are settled for very long periods, then hierarchies can emerge. You think about the way in which
the hierarchies entrenched themselves in Venice, the stories about long French aristocratic
families. None of that exists in a secular society like Australia in the 1800s, where
apart from the First Nations people, basically everyone's just gotten off a boat.
The Gold Rush story is interesting.
I hadn't considered that, but that does make sense.
So I think it's in his book, Australia,
but the great Australian historian, Keith Hancock.
So if anyone hasn't heard of this book, Australia,
it's kind of our version of Topphil's democracy in America
or Budgets, the English Constitution.
It's kind of like a book that just captures
the spirit of Australia at the time.
It took me about two weeks to get a secondhand copy.
It's out of print.
There's definitely some kind of interesting project there in republishing this book.
But in Australia, there's this, if I remember correctly, there's this line where Hancock
says something like, you know, within a decade of the Gold Rush, basically the whole Charterist
program had been implemented in Australia.
So that would support the Gold Rush story
because the timing is so tight there, right?
Yeah, so you've got massive immigration.
So you have this decade in which the Gold Rushes,
in which the Australian population triples,
in which the population of Melbourne
goes up by a factor of seven.
And that's got to create social fluidity
and a whole lot of mixing.
And it means that those workers are coming in
and essentially setting up a society around what they want.
If egalitarianism is one hallmark of Australian culture,
our faith in government is the other.
In Melbourne, I spoke with Judith Brett,
Emeritus Professor of Politics at La Trobe University, about her book, From Secret Ballot to Democracy Sausage.
Her book shows how Australia's system of compulsory and preferential voting was shaped
by our majoritarian and bureaucratic culture. In this excerpt, we speak about the historical
forces that shaped that culture in turn. We start by discussing how Jeremy Bentham's utilitarianism was in the air when
Australia was setting up its political institutions.
But then we go on to discuss how colonial Australia's unusual relationship to the
British government gave Australians a benign view of the role of government in
their lives. I was expecting Judy to place more weight on the first explanation about Benthamite
utilitarianism, but she surprised me by emphasizing the second.
One of the things that I'd sort of overlooked until I read your book was this second historical
explanation for our Benthamite society, which I think John Hirst wrote about as well. And
that is that for about the first 100 years of Australian history, the British government
paid for our governments and taxation was accordingly pretty low here, whereas that
was not the case in America.
And they had the problem of taxation without representation and that sort of inspired the
Declaration of Independence.
So the attitude Australians developed towards government
during the colonial era was it was this sort of thing
that just gave you stuff without really costing much money.
And I was curious of those two reasons,
the kind of Benthamite philosophy being in the air,
so to speak, and then the low taxation environment,
which one do you think weighed more heavily on our political culture? Look, it's a bit hard to know because I think
on that other one, like W.K. Hancock, who wrote that little book called Australia in the 1930s,
he wrote that Australians look at government as a large public utility
for the service of individual interests.
That is, they don't see government
as the big problem of government being,
yes, we need it for law and order,
we need it to defend the borders,
but we've given it this authority,
but it's potentially coercive,
and we have to make sure it doesn't coerce us.
That didn't seem to be what...
And we'd have to make sure it doesn't take
too much of our property to pay for itself, you know?
And as you say, because Australians weren't paying
that much towards the upkeep of the government.
And the government was essentially building a colony,
so it was borrowing the money to build the infrastructure. Like in America, the railways were put through
by private enterprise.
In Australia, the railways were developed by governments.
The land was sold by governments,
and that's how they were raising money.
They were raising money from the selling
of the Indigenous peoples' land, essentially.
But roads, ports, if productive life was to be possible in this new society, this new
colony, well then infrastructure was needed and the infrastructure was provided by the
government.
So I think what that does is it means that there's a certain trust in government as potentially
benevolent rather than as potentially oppressive, which is the more influential, I think probably
that latter, I would say, the fact that we depended on government for the development
of the infrastructure and also a lot of the also a lot of migration,
a lot of the migration was assisted migrants, the government helped them get here.
Speaking of immigration, my next excerpt comes from my second Melbourne event, this time
with former Deputy Secretary of the Department of Immigration Abel Rizvi. The biggest thing
I learned in this conversation relates to how Australian policymakers think
and have thought about the objectives of immigration policy.
I hadn't realized that probably the dominant rationale of Australian immigration policy
over the past couple of decades has been to slow our rate of population aging.
I knew it was part of the mix of objectives, but I hadn't appreciated the full weight
that policymakers place on it.
As Apple explains to me, slowing population aging comprised about 80% of the motivation
for the 2001 changes, which massively increased Australia's intake of skilled migrants, especially
overseas students.
So my next question is about the sort of objectives of immigration policy.
So you have, you know, one objective or one rationale would be slowing the rate of immigration policy. So you have one objective or one rationale
would be slowing the rate of population aging.
Another would be filling skill shortages.
But then you have all these second order consequences
as well, like the diversity of the Australian population,
fiscal benefits of migrants.
What do you think is the right set and balance of objectives
for immigration policy? What are we actually trying to achieve
with it?
Right. You're absolutely right. In my thinking, the primary or the initial objective of our
immigration policy should be to, over the next 50 to 100 years, slow the rate at which
we age. We will age. We will get older. We'll get a lot older. But if we years slow the rate at which we age. We will age, we will get older, we'll
get a lot older, but if we can slow the rate of ageing our ability to adjust to that is
much better than if the rate of ageing was very, very fast. If we were ageing at the
rate of China or Japan or South Korea or much of Western Europe, the adjustment processes are much
more difficult.
Businesses would find it much more difficult to adjust.
Government agencies would find it much more difficult to adjust.
So I think a primary objective should be demography.
And indeed, it was demography when Arthur Call will start the post-war migration program.
He was thinking demography.
And so back in the late 90s, early 2000s, when you were advising Ruddock and Costello
and then persuading Howard to implement the changes that we did, how much of that decision
was about slowing the rate of population aging?
Was that the main motivation?
Probably 80% was demography.
Oh, interesting.
It would have been 80% demography.
And it would have probably been 10% pressure from universities.
We need a way of making money.
And we can't fund ourselves unless we can make money.
And so we had to open up the International Education Program.
It just happened to be the case.
That was the best way to also increase the migration program
in a manner that it contributed skills to Australia,
it contributed export income to Australia,
and it slowed the rate of ageing,
and it was a budget benefit.
Put all that together and it was too attractive for any government to refuse.
Of course, high levels of immigration over the past couple of decades have interacted
with inelastic housing supply to push up house prices and produce a housing affordability crisis
in Australia. In Sydney, I asked Peter Chulip, chief economist at the Center for
Independent Studies and a former RBA research manager, how quickly a deregulatory agenda
could increase supply and thereby bring down prices. My big update from the conversation,
in fact this was probably my biggest update from the whole series, is just how long it
will take to resolve the housing crisis by focusing
on supply. According to Peter, to bring prices down in Sydney and Melbourne by about 40%
using an extremely ambitious supply side policy, that is a hypothetical policy even more aggressive
than the National Cabinet's target of 1.2 million homes over five years, would still
take 10 to 20 years.
I'll share two excerpts from my conversation with Peter, which build on each other.
One from early in the conversation and another from the end of our chat.
I'm conscious in this conversation, both you and I will probably use zoning to refer to
really the broader set of what might be called planning restrictions. But the kind of what can you use this land for is traditionally what's meant by zoning.
So you're adding zoning, heritage, height restrictions.
So then, Gabe, we cut these things.
Change all of those.
So those estimates of the zoning effect, we called it,
I mean, I think they are a reasonable approximation
to what would happen to housing prices in
those cities.
If you were to completely liberalize the markets.
Now, but that's not what we're suggesting.
To be politically realistic, our aims are much more moderate than that.
But ultimately, that's the if you would take it to
extremes, that's where it would hit. Yes. And so how much more moderate are your aims than that?
So I think the National Cabinet target of 1.2 million homes over five years is sensible.
That is the numbers that we were talking about before with this pure free market deregulation
would involve something like a 10 or 20 percent increase in the housing stock in Australia.
And you clearly can't do that overnight.
In fact, you can't do it within any reasonable planning period,
but you can build a lot more.
And the national target of 1.2 million homes
essentially takes the previous peak in construction
that we saw before the pandemic and said,
let's hope we can do that on a sustained basis.
And that strikes me as a feasible, short-term objective.
Feasible both economically, because we've built
at that rate before, but also politically,
in the sense that the community accepted those rates
of construction in the past.
I can run the numbers on what that would mean for affordability if you want.
Yeah.
Okay, so one million homes is sort of a baseline neutral, is a neutral baseline.
And that was the original target. And so the national cabinet target of 1.2 million homes is 200,000 on top of it.
We have a national housing stock of 11 trillion homes.
So those 200,000 is about, with a bit of rounding, 2% increase in the national housing stock. As a rough rule of thumb, every percentage point increase in the housing stock reduces
the cost of housing by about 2.5%.
So that 2% increment that National Cabinet is targeting would give you a 5% reduction
in affordability.
Okay. That is relative to a baseline of housing prices trending up.
So in real terms, house prices outpace inflation by about 2.5% over a very long average.
It's more or less than that depending on exactly when you take the average from. So you take 5% over five years from that and we're still and prices are still
increasing in nominal terms.
Right. So it's not 5% lower than today's prices. It's 5% lower than the counterfactual in five
years. Yeah, 5% lower than what was a pretty unattractive counterfactual of continually deteriorating
affordability. So earlier in our conversation, you mentioned that to get those kind of 40%
price falls in Sydney and Melbourne, it would require increasing housing supply by, do you
say 10 to 20%? Yep. How many years would that take, roughly speaking?
If we got rid of those zoning regulations
on the chopping block?
As a simple calculation,
if we increase the housing stock 1% a year,
it would take 10 to 20 years.
Okay.
That's doing it over and above what we'd normally do.
Okay, so over and above the current baseline normally do. Yeah. Okay. So over and above the current baseline?
Yeah. Yeah. Okay. And- But even that is extremely ambitious. I mean, so what the national target that we talked about before is an increase of 200,000 above baseline over five years.
over five years. Okay.
So that's what, 40,000, just 40,000 a year.
Yeah.
So if we removed all of the zoning regulations on your chopping block, how quickly do you
think we would get that 10 to 20% increase in supply?
No one has bothered to do that calculation.
I think for good reasons. What are the reasons?
It's just not realistic. It's not realistic and it's not on the agenda. Right. And no one is
proposing it. Yeah. I don't, I'm not proposing substantial or immediate changes to the legislation or the process or how we approve houses.
But all we need to do is relatively simple.
Under existing processes, we need to set higher targets for local councils that will add up
to 1.2 million homes.
So that's being done in the New South Wales and Victorian governments. And that just means local councils need to start approving
a block of flats in every third or fourth suburb
every few years.
Relatively modest changes in the built form of our city
will over time amount to a substantial increase in supply.
And you don't need any change.
I mean, there are good reasons for changing the process, but they're not necessary to
deliver housing affordability.
We just need councils to stop saying no and start saying yes.
And that can be achieved.
I think what the New South Wales
and Victorian governments are doing is basically right.
They've set, they're setting ambitious targets for councils.
The next step that they need to take
is to announce how they will be enforced,
which hasn't been done yet.
And there is a real worry that once these plans
are lodged before councils, councils will start saying no.
And then you do get a fight
between the state government and the councils.
And it's not clear that the state governments
have the stomach for that.
Right.
So I'd like them to pre-announce automatic remedies for councils that don't
make satisfactory progress towards their targets.
But even if we do achieve that national cabinet target of 1.2 million new homes over
five years, you're saying that it's only going to lower prices
about five percent relative to the counterfactual. And that is ambitious. I mean, if that's and
I kind of I'd buy your point that realistically that's probably as good as we can expect from
our political system. I'm now just kind of feeling a bit deflated listening to it. It
feels like we're not we're actually not going to solve the housing crisis. All the people who say we should be cutting
immigration, they're probably right. Like that seems like the only solution now.
So 5% reduction after five years, but then you do it again the following five years.
And that adds up to a 10% reduction. Right.
And so on. I mean, this was a problem that built up over generations. So it is going
to be very difficult to solve it quickly. It will take time, particularly as it requires
a very substantial increase in our construction industry, which has difficulties. I mean,
we can do it. Other countries have done it. Auckland doubled its construction workforce, but it will take time and requires changes
to training and immigration and accreditation and wages.
Do you think over those five-year intervals, we can ratchet up the amount of supply we
provide each time?
Is that the kind of base case?
I would hope so.
Okay.
And do you think that's more likely than the opposite?
I guess maybe people come to accept it
or people realize it's working
so you can add more supply each time.
That's a good question.
I mean, so what's happened in Auckland
is you've had two effects. One is people have seen that it works, that
rents are substantially lit, have risen substantially less in Auckland than in other New Zealand cities. but at the same time, you've got a backlash. That some people think that the new buildings going up
are ugly and there's this fear of change element
we talked about before.
And it very often happens that when you change
what people are used to, they're uncomfortable with that
and they object.
And how those two balance, we don't know.
The reason Peter's answer worried me so much is that even a decade strikes me as too long to wait.
The housing crisis is causing problems, for example, for productivity and fertility,
which will continue compounding into increasingly terrible outcomes if given decades to run,
even if prices are gradually moderating
over that time.
So what's stopping us from adopting a maximally ambitious policy for speeding up new supply?
The constraints seem to me to be mostly political.
For one, housing has, for better or for worse, become the way the middle class gets rich
in Australia.
Without offering the home-earning constituency an alternative
vision for wealth creation, I worry that the supply-side agenda entails a slow, decades-long
grind. If the thing we care about is affordability, not the price level per se, then what we really
care about is the price to income ratio. So is there a way to get incomes growing more quickly,
to improve affordability from the other direction and potentially make price falls more politically palatable?
This raises what I call the joint problem of housing and productivity.
To improve national productivity, it's vital that more people can afford to live and work
in our major agglomerations, but equally to prepare the nation to bear falling and lower
house prices, we need rising
incomes and therefore stronger productivity growth.
To end the series, I spoke with Ken Henry, former Secretary of the Treasury.
Ken raises capital deepening and increasing total factor productivity as two primary ways
to fix Australia's stagnant labor productivity growth.
Ken seems to prefer focusing on capital deepening
as the way to improve productivity growth,
but in this next excerpt,
we focus on total factor productivity.
One of the things I love about talking with Ken
is I can ask him almost any random question
about Australian economic policy,
and he'll say something like,
oh yeah, we looked at exactly that question
in treasury back in the 1990s or whenever.
And that's what happens in this next excerpt.
I asked Ken, how close Australia could plausibly get
to US total factor productivity?
On productivity, if we take total factor productivity
in the US to represent the kind of technological frontier
and other countries can measure themselves against that benchmark. I think generally Australia sits
around 80% of the US level. That might have peaked a bit above 85% in the late 90s, but it came back
down. How likely is it that a mix of policies exists that could help us achieve parity with the US level?
Or do you think we'll always be constrained by other factors like
geographic isolation from major economies?
The kind of geographic fragmentation of Australia, the small size of our national market.
Yeah, yeah, yeah. No, that's a really good one. So we did some work on this in the late 1990s asking exactly that question.
Oh, yeah, well we did. And we came up with the view that 95 percent is about what we could, the best we could hope for.
Yeah, yeah, yeah. Yeah, because, yeah, because the other...
What explains the five percent?
The last stuff that you were talking about, geographical isolation, separation, blah, blah, blah. We figured that simply putting a rope around the Australian continent and towing it up
to city adjacent to California, that alone would lift productivity by at least 5%.
Just doing nothing else.
Mainly through building all the tugboats. I don't know. And that's what the, and there is some literature on this,
right, is the impact of geographic location
on national productivity.
And that's basically, that was the consensus position
of the literature back in the,
and look, you know, your AI assistant
would be able to answer this like that right now,
but whereas it took us months to figure this out.
But so, but realistically, took us months to figure this out. But realistically you'd
have to think 95%. I would still think 95%. And who knows, the US could be falling off
dramatically at the moment. And so maybe something far in excess of that is feasible, not that's a good outcome necessarily
for the world, right?
But anyway, which means that we can do a lot better.
So it's exciting to know that that ceiling is there and that's what it is and that's
how much better we can do.
Yeah.
Anyway, I think that's a reasonable aspiration for policymakers in Australia.
So that final excerpt shows just how much better Australia could be doing,
how much more innovative we could become.
I'll leave you with the following lingering question.
What would it take to close that gap, to raise our level of total factor
productivity all the way to its potential ceiling?
Answering that question will be a major theme
of future episodes, but in the meantime,
I hope you enjoyed this tour through my policy series.
Full transcripts and the complete set of conversations
are available on my website, www.jnwpod.com.
That's J-N-W-P-O-D.com.
Thanks for listening and until next time, ciao.