The Joe Walker Podcast - Ken Henry — An Economic Odyssey
Episode Date: May 9, 2023Dr Ken Henry is an Australian economist who served as Secretary of Australia's Treasury from 2001 to 2011. He was instrumental in helping Australia avoid recession during the 2008 Global Financial Cri...sis — Australia was the only major advanced economy to do so. Full transcript available at: thejspod.comSee omnystudio.com/listener for privacy information.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Ladies and gentlemen, boys and girls, swagmen and swagettes, welcome back to the show.
Before we start, a quick housekeeping item to say I love getting
correspondence from you, so I want to take a moment to encourage it further. I'm continually
shocked and humbled by how impressive this audience is. Some truly brilliant people listen
to the show and that makes engaging with you all particularly fruitful. So if you have suggestions,
things you think I should read, ideas you want to share, please get in touch. You can reach me by
email joe at the jspod.com or on Twitter. My handle there is at Joseph N Walker. Okay, to this episode, our guest is Ken Henry. Ken Henry is an Australian
economist who has held roles in academia, the public service, as a political advisor,
and in the public sector as chairman of National Australia Bank, one of Australia's big four banks.
But his most prominent role was as Secretary of Australia's Treasury
Department from 2001 to 2011, which effectively made him the most powerful bureaucrat in the
country for a decade. That decade included, of course, what we Australians call the GFC,
or Global Financial Crisis of 2008. Australians don't speak of the Great Recession since Australia
was the world's only major advanced economy to avoid recession during that period. That success
was in no small part thanks to Ken and his treasury team who engineered Australia's fiscal
response to the crisis. Ken's immortal advice to then Prime Minister Kevin Rudd
was, go early, go hard, and go households. So it was a real honour to chat with Ken about his career,
about economic policymaking, and economic theory. Now, for non-Australian listeners,
such as my British and American swagmen and swagettes,
this episode partly focuses on topics within an Australian context, which might seem parochial.
However, if you enjoy learning about other cultures and about economic policymaking in specific contexts, you will find this episode extremely enriching. At four and a half hours, this is my longest
podcast ever, and it remains fascinating right up to the very end. So a word of advice,
if you come across a topic during the conversation that doesn't interest you personally,
keep listening because many other subjects are covered throughout the discussion that you will probably find interesting. Like all my episodes, this episode comes with an
amazing resource that is a transcript complete with helpful hyperlinks to things mentioned
during the conversation. Except this episode's transcript is the length of a small novel. And you can find it on my website,
thejspod.com. That is thejspod.com. Finally, please excuse any dogs barking or other background
noises you might hear during the conversation as we recorded this at Ken's farm. The recording
took place on Thursday, the 4th of May, 2023. Enjoy.
Ken Henry, welcome to the podcast.
Good to be with you.
So Ken, I have questions about treasury as an institution and the process of making policy.
I've got philosophical questions and I have questions about specific policies,
but first I want to start with some history. Okay.
You joined Treasury's Tax Policy Division in 1984 and then you moved across to Paul
Kidding's office in 1986 while he was Treasurer to be one of his senior economic advisors
and you were there until 1991. What was it like to be in the engine room of Australia's golden era
of economic reform?
Well, it was an absolute blast.
You know, for some years before that, I had been a junior academic
having just completed a PhD, and I went into the Treasury
in I think it was August of 1984, and I was naive but curious.
I went in because of what I could see happening within government, that there was a hell of a lot going on.
The whole Keating reform era that had commenced, I guess, really, well, pretty much after they were elected in
March 1983. I mean, they got straight into it, but by early 1984, it was clear that this was
going to be a reformist government. I thought, well, I wouldn't mind finding out what this is
like, stepping out of academia. But I thought, I can't step out of academia for very long. And
all my colleagues said to me, you're nuts.
If you step out of academia, you'll never get back in
or you get back in but you take one year out.
It's like going to sleep for five years as far
as your academic career is concerned.
And I thought, oh, well, okay, I'll put a limit of two years on it.
I reckon after six months of being in the Treasury in that reform period, I knew that I was never going back to academia and that policy was going to, and policy work, was going to dominate my life.
I knew that after six months. and of course I was working as part of the team
through the first half of 1985 that put together
that draft white paper on tax reform that Keating,
without cabinet authority by the way,
that he took to the National Tax Summit in June of 1985
without any support from within,
from amongst his colleagues, on the basis of work
that had been produced by a very small team of Treasury people.
Maybe you'd need two hands to count the number, maybe, who had produced a reform package that had the support
of nobody outside of the Treasury.
Nobody.
Like not in academia, not amongst other government departments,
and certainly not in the media.
And yet Keating had the courage to take that all the way
to the National Tax Summit, knowing beforehand that he was almost certain
that he was going to lose the argument.
And I just thought, God, it can't get any better than this, right? And so when in the middle of 1986 he asked me to join his office
as a senior advisor and get even closer to the action,
which actually I think from my perspective it really meant
get closer to him, well, it was irresistible.
It was an irresistible invitation.
And as you say, I stayed there for five years.
But I would say that whole five years was just a blast,
just one continuous amazing experience.
I don't think the adrenaline ever stopped flowing, not for a second.
Do you have any Keating anecdotes that you can share?
No.
I've got Keating anecdotes.
I'm not sure that I've got ones that I would share.
I think, I mean, maybe one, which is maybe give you a bit of a flavour
for the sort of person he is.
And I won't mention...
No, I'll give you two.
I won't mention names, but I don't think these stories
have ever been told publicly, and there's no reason
why they should be.
And I was the only witness to these two.
But on one occasion, it was shortly after I joined Keating's office,
so we were still in the old Parliament House,
one of his senior colleagues, very senior minister,
came in to see Paul.
And I happened to be sitting in Paul's office across the desk from him.
I'd been briefing him on some policy issue.
And the senior minister came in and he said,
look, Paul, I really need to talk to you before question time.
And I got up to leave and the fellow said, no, no, no, look,
honestly, it's all right. You stay. It doesn't matter. And Paul said, what is it, mate?
And he said, well, you know, I'm taking all these decisions.
And I find myself waking up at 2 o'clock
or 3 o'clock in the morning just worrying about whether I was taking,
whether I'd been taking the right decisions or not and, you know,
questioning my own judgment on the decisions that I'd taken the previous day
and days before.
And he said, I'm just in turmoil over it.
And I think these are the precise words Paul said.
He said, well, mate, it's time to go.
Wow.
Yeah, like, wow.
And I thought, God, I don't know anybody else,
and I'm sure I've never met anybody else in my life who would have responded in that way.
And I mean, it wasn't as if Paul was unfeeling at all.
It was just, in fact, probably quite the opposite.
Because they then went on to discuss why Paul had said what Paul had said.
And shortly after the minister did, he stepped down.
So there's a, I mean, it can come across as almost brutal,
but it's, there's a method, sorry, there is, there was more to it than that.
I mean, Paul wasn't being unkind at all.
He understood the situation absolutely perfectly,
but his assessment was the right one, and I'm sure that minister came to the,
well, he obviously came to the same view, that yes, yes, this is the right assessment.
You're absolutely right.
So the implication being that the reality of power is that you have
to be able to sit with these decisions and make them confidently.
Yeah, exactly.
Yeah, yeah.
And if you find just, exactly.
And if you find yourself questioning your own judgment
then this is not the place that you should be you should not be you should not be putting
yourself in this position find a a more peaceful existence doing something else, helping out in some other way.
And this particular minister had had a long career as an advisor and official in various capacities and, you know,
a highly successful career and was much loved by all of his colleagues,
including Keating, right?
So this was not a person without talent, far from it, far from it.
But he'd found himself in a position in which he was uncomfortable
and a position of power, and the power was,
or the exercise of the power was, I guess, killing him,
slightly, but killing him, right?
Anyway, the second anecdote I'll tell,
this is now in the new Parliament House,
but two very senior business people came in to talk Keating as Treasurer,
and he was probably also Deputy Prime Minister by this time. I'm not sure, but anyway, certainly Treasurer, and he was probably also Deputy Prime Minister
by this time, I'm not sure, but anyway, certainly Treasurer, obviously,
to inform him of a decision that they had reached
to merge their two national institutions, both large corporate entities.
And this was the first Paul had heard of it.
But he was a bit curious as to why the two had sought a meeting with him
and a meeting under, you know, it was a time constraint
and we have to see you today. And they didn't say why, at least in the meeting and, you know, it was a time constraint and we have to see you today.
And they didn't say why, at least in the meeting request, but we have to see you today.
It's very, very important, critical.
And so when they arrived, he asked me to step in to really just to be a witness to the meeting.
And I was blown away. The two, you know, since I've been in very senior positions
in the corporate world myself, but as a young policy advisor,
what I saw was these two people who were absolutely certain
that what they were doing was in the national interest.
It couldn't be questioned.
It must have been.
And they were merely, as a matter of courtesy, informing the Treasurer that they were going to do this.
I don't know if they knew that the Treasurer, under various bits of legislation, one in particular, had the power to prevent them
from doing what they'd already decided they were going to do.
I don't know if they knew that.
But when he said to them, you're going to do what?
I saw them sit back, colour drained from their faces,
and they went on, explained it again.
And he said, you think you're going to do that?
Well, yes.
And he said, like hell you are.
You're not going to do that.
No way are you going to do that.
They were absolutely shocked.
And Paul had had no briefing on this issue.
He didn't know what was coming.
But he had this, look, it's more than instinct.
By then, he had such a robust policy framework in his head that he himself was capable of bringing some pretty sophisticated analysis to the issue that had been presented to him.
And knowing, perhaps it was instinctive, I don't know, but knowing anyway that this can't possibly be in the national interest for this to happen.
And he blocked it.
And that was that.
And they were both furious and devastated, these two,
the two CEOs, when they left the room.
And I thought, well, I thought a lot of things.
I learned a lot from that.
But it was another, it's another anecdote in the exercise of power that I'm sure has never been recorded anyway.
Well, not publicly.
It tells you a bit about the sort of person that Keating was. when he took a decision, he would be absolutely comfortable
with the decision that he took.
And he had that ability.
He didn't always get it right.
But I would say over the years that I spent with him
and working closely with him, and of course,
even after I left his office,
because he six months later became Prime Minister,
I continued to work with him in a different capacity, obviously.
But I rarely saw him take a poor decision.
Now, he did take some, but it was rare.
People tend to focus on those that were poor, and that's understandable.
But amongst the plethora of huge decisions that he found himself having to take
on the basis of necessarily limited or incomplete advice.
He was, in my view, he stands well above any other treasurer
that I've ever come into contact with.
Wow.
Raises a couple of questions.
One is, so he obviously left high school at the age of 14.
Yeah.
And that was sort of the end of his formal education.
Yeah.
Didn't have any economics education.
No.
Learned it all on the job.
Yes.
And obviously, as you've described,
had an incredible intuitive grasp of the economy.
How far can intuition take you in economic policymaking?
Is it necessary and sufficient?
Oh, it's certainly not sufficient.
Is it necessary?
Is it even necessary?
Helpful.
Certainly helpful.
Good intuitive instinct is certainly helpful good intuitive instinct is uh is certainly helpful but then relying upon it to
the exclusion of analysis and the exclusion of engagement with uh with advisors uh would be uh
very very dangerous i mean there's a lot of things that make good intuitive sense
that I've seen in my career that are just nuts, you know, just nuts.
And so you wouldn't want to rely on it.
So is kidding the exception to that rule?
Uh, in my, uh, I've seen others who have pretty strong intuitive grasp.
So I wouldn't say that he was the exception,
but I would say an absolute standout.
Yeah, an absolute standout.
You know, but people's minds work differently, right?
Some are extraordinary intuitive thinkers i had a um
and i won't mention a name either but i had in the department uh as an advisor uh somebody who
um these days is a very very wealthy highly successful person in the private sector, and has quite a profile.
And he was working in the Treasury, and he was deeply,
most days he was upset.
I mean, deeply upset, like often in tears.
And I spent quite a bit of time with him because he was clearly brilliant
and discovered eventually that the reason for him being upset
was a frustration in...
He saw it as a frustration in the capacity of people
he was talking to to understand why he was right.
Fair enough.
And I saw it, I think the true, I think it would have been
more honest of him to admit that his source of frustration
was that he couldn't explain to others why
he was right.
And we're talking about really complex stuff, right, without going into the subject matter.
It was really complex stuff.
And he could see the answer just like, no, bang, that's it.
That's what you got to do.
But he couldn't explain why. And so he was forever finding himself in heated arguments with other people who, you know, also had first-class honours degrees in several disciplines, if not PhDs, who, you know, had always been top of their class right through school and university and blah, blah, and who couldn't see what he could see
and who would not accept that he had it right,
and particularly because he couldn't explain why he had it right.
And it got to the point, you know, where I had a hunch that his, I don't know whether it's inductive reasoning powers.
I'm not sure that that's what I was seeing.
But anyway, I had a hunch that he was kind of, he was unbalanced in the sense that his intuition was really, really strong, but I had a suspicion that the linear analytical abilities were not so strong.
Because after all, if they were, how come he wasn't able to explain it to other people whose minds work in that linear sequential sort of fashion, you know.
And so I took one of the debates that he was engaged in and I produced the algebra and the calculus that, to me, constructed the formal argument that analyzed the thing.
And I came to the conclusion that he was 95% right, which blew me away, actually, because
I thought that's highly improbable.
Like, I thought he might be 50% right, but he was 95% right.
And I gave it to him, and I said, look, could you just
check this? And weeks went by and eventually he came back to me and again, he was in tears.
And I said, I just don't understand what's wrong. And he said, I can't understand your mathematics.
And I said, well, I don't understand.
I just do not understand.
How the hell on earth could you be capable of analysing this complex problem
without being able to understand this, which to me was a relatively routine bit of
analysis, you know?
And he said, well, I just can't, right?
So, can you rely on intuition?
He can.
He's a fabulously wealthy person, done incredibly well.
He can rely on intuition.
Yeah.
Would I want him to rely on intuition and run the country?
I'd be a bit worried.
Okay.
By the way, I think I know who this person is.
We can talk about it afterwards.
Okay.
Right. Okay, right.
Okay.
Another reaction to your second anecdote about Keating.
Your description almost reminds me of someone like an expert cellist
or pains or a basketball player in flow state.
Yeah, like someone in flow state yeah yeah completely confident has almost a grace in what they're doing grace is a really good word
yeah there was but it was almost like he'd made an art out of the use of power
oh that is so insightful and I reckon that's dead right.
And it did look graceful to me, even the brutality,
there was grace in it.
Even, yeah, and the way that he would wield that sword and the damage that he would do with it.
There was artistry in it, theatre.
Yeah, and grace.
And it's, you know, that comes through most of the things that he got involved in,
because he wasn't involved exclusively in economic policy, right?
I mean, a great appreciator of art and architecture, of history.
His command of those disciplines too was, well, anyway,
relied to a very large extent upon instinct and intuition.
And if he were here, he would say it's all the same, mate.
He would.
It's, you know, being able to see the big picture.
He would say it's all the same.
He would find that the sort of, the way that academics approach issues,
where they find themselves getting narrower and narrower and narrower,
and they say, well, of course,
we need to in order to be able to dig sufficiently deep to make real progress.
I doubt that he'd find that.
I doubt that he'd even understand what they were talking about.
Yeah.
For him, it's all about finding the the patterns and the truth is in the patterns
did interacting with australian political leaders in canberra make you more or less
inclined to believe in the great man or woman view of history uh but i guess you've got this
dialectic between it's yeah people who influence history or it's like forces that shape history.
So both.
And we've had leading politicians who have said things like, the times suit me.
And I think that's quite revealing.
And generally, I think when they have said it, it's been true um like they haven't said it just to
inflate their own egos i think it's probably been true generally that the times have suited them
but but of course the other way of putting that is that other times probably wouldn't
have suited them there might have been absolute disasters at other times. And yet there are also leaders that we've had who were able
to change the times to suit them, right?
And I think Keating was in both camps.
I think he was capable of taking, really maximising,
maybe not maximising, maybe that's too strong,
but exploiting as much as anyone could possibly imagine,
exploiting the opportunity presented by the times as they were.
But then he was also capable of shifting the narrative, changing the narrative, you know, from like he created
the debt and deficits narrative, right?
He created that.
That wasn't there.
He created those times.
And then he used what he had created to enormous effect,
to build support for extraordinary economic transformation
or a set of policies that were going to produce
and did produce an extraordinary economic transformation, right?
Now, of course, it is likely that had he not cast the challenge
in the terms he did, you know, the Banana Republic and so on, had he not done that, at some stage we would have found, Australia would have found itself in a crisis and having to make those big changes anyway.
And so, you know, maybe you could argue that, well, he was only 10 years ahead of his time.
Well, God, if only we had leaders who were 10 years ahead of their time, right?
Now, the debt and deficits narrative was a sub-narrative of a broader narrative, which you termed the Australian mercantilism narrative.
Yeah.
And Keating kind of unleashed both of them.
Yes.
They were effective in his time, but they've obviously plagued the Australian political discourse in decades since.
Yeah, yeah, yeah.
Can you just talk about the origins of those narratives, why he constructed them?
Yeah.
Yeah.
Okay. one um his his concern was that um having um taken big steps to open the economy up and and really
the steps that that had been taken at that stage were to float the currency
um and to abolish capital controls so to allow capital to flow into the economy and then, of course, to flow out of the economy.
And he was – and so we had a bumpy ride, right?
I mean, the economic outcomes, the macroeconomic outcomes
were quite volatile in those years following those two things,
floating the currency and abolishing, removing capital controls. And there was no,
at least by 1986, which is when he made the Banana Republic statement, there wasn't a lot
to show for it right in terms of improved
economic performance sure we'd come out of the recession but we're going to come out of the
recession the drought had ended in early night in the early 1980s right um but things had not
improved so much that the budget was showing any signs of getting back or getting anywhere toward balance. So we still had a big budget deficit.
The currency was under continual downward pressure.
We had what appeared to be a widening current account deficit.
Should that have worried him?
Look, I don't know, but it did.
I mean, he did worry about these things right um it didn't it wasn't part of
a narrative that he could wasn't part of a nice positive narrative that he could construct right
it was a was uh something that that really worried him and there was this uh concern I
don't think he would I don't think he was the person who first articulated the concern about Australia's increasing reliance
upon short-term capital inflows from offshore, particularly debt flows.
But he was deeply uncomfortable with it, that Australia had,
because it was continually running current account deficits,
it was therefore relying upon the rest of the world to finance those current account deficits.
And a lot of the funding was coming in in the form of short-term debt financing.
And if it wasn't coming in in the form of short-term debt financing, it was foreigners
wanting to buy up property and, oh God another that's also not very comfortable and and um
and he got it the way that he chose to frame it or frame the narrative was that
at some point if we didn't get on top of this at some point australia would lose flexibility and maybe even sovereignty
in respect of its economic policy settings.
And so that it was better that we take matters into our own hands,
take the decisions ourselves about how we were going to respond Being a small, open economy in a world of very large flows
of global capital and how we could insulate ourselves
against the risks associated with that.
And his answer, and look, he wasn't the only person
who came up with this answer, and there were a lot
of academics too who said you know uh or what you're talking about is a and this is true it's
just a tautology you're talking about um a gap between national saving and national investment
that's right so it's just a simple piece of arithmetic that the current account deficit
is simply equal to the excess of national investment
over national saving. So maybe Australia's got a chronic saving problem, right? And that's in two
parts. There's a public saving problem. Well, that was clear from the budget papers, right?
Succession of budget deficits getting worse and worse and worse and worse. And we've also got a private saving problem. And it was true that household saving on international standards
were pretty low.
Of course, the irony is that in addressing his efforts
to lifting public saving,
i.e. reducing the budget deficit,
and also to some extent lifting private saving,
although that really came later with superannuation,
private superannuation.
But certainly that first bit in fixing the,
or appearing to fix the structural budget position,
what do you know?
Capital flows into Australia increased.
And the capital flows were financing a spectacular investment boom
because the rest of the world said, all of a sudden,
Australia's a great place to put your money,
to invest in an enhancement of productive capacity, right?
And so there were all these new investment opportunities
that opened up in Australia.
And that's his true legacy, in my view, on the economic front,
is that we had this enormous investment inflow.
And then even though there was a recession in the early 1990s,
as we came out of the recession, it just kept powering on, right? And it powered on because
of the way in which he had educated the world or re-educated the world about the sort of
place that Australia is and how they should think about Australia. Australia is actually a great
place to invest. And the current account, deficit just widened and widened
and widened, right, even though the budget deficit had closed.
So deeply, deeply ironic, but nevertheless,
and the narrative in and of itself is flawed, right?
I mean, the debt and deficits thing.
Well, it's incomplete, but it's seriously incomplete.
I mean, it's so incomplete that in the wrong hands it's deeply flawed.
Let me put it that way.
But nevertheless, and it did lie behind the extreme measures
that were taken in the late 1980s
or early 1990s that actually did tip the economy into recession.
And, you know, there's no resiling from that.
I don't think there's any resiling from that.
Yet it is also true that it supported an extraordinary investment boom
that actually rebuilt the economy, restructured the economy,
and allowed the economy to produce rates of productivity growth that hardly,
through the 1990s, that hardly any other economy
in the world had ever produced at any time, including us.
Is the debt and deficits narrative not long for this world,
given that as of 2019 we've been in a current account surplus?
Well, no.
So why are we in a current account surplus?
And the reason we're in a current account surplus
is because investment has collapsed.
That's the reason, yeah.
And that's the problem.
I mean, the problem, we shouldn't see this as a good thing.
And would Keating see it as a good thing?
Would he say, ah, you know, this is a triumphal moment for me.
We've actually converted a current account deficit
into a current account surplus.
I think if he were to, and I haven't had this conversation with him,
but I'm pretty sure if he were to look at Australia's rate of business investment,
he would be absolutely appalled. And he would understand that with the sort of business
investment rates that we've got in Australia now, the sort of investment rates that, I mean,
investment as a proportion of gross domestic product, so low. The only other times in our history that we've seen rates of investment this low is in the depths of recessions.
And yet we've been here for years now with these investment rates.
He would be appalled and he would understand that that's the principal reason for declining productivity growth in Australia, the undermining of living standards, the lack of growth of real wages.
He would get all that and he would be appalled by that.
So he wouldn't regard it as a success story at all.
He would want to see that investment rate lifted.
Now, by the early 2000s, I think I had at the time,
and I think all of my colleagues in official circles
would have had a similar view, was that, look,
provided you've got high-quality domestic policy,
we took it for granted, right?
I mean, this is ridiculous, but we did.
We did.
Until the beginning of this century, we just took it for granted that we were always going to have high quality domestic policy
settings, right? And an absolute commitment to first rate transparency with respect to policy
setting and so on. We've got an independent central bank and all this kind of stuff. Provided you've got that, you don't need to worry
about the rest of the world financing your current account deficit,
even if it is going to increase to significant proportions
of GDP from time to time.
Who cares?
They will do it because you're such a good target,
such a good place to invest, right,
because you've got those wonderful policy settings.
And that's what I thought.
And I thought that I was thinking that right through to 2006,
2006 as part of a program of work that really began
after the Asian financial crisis in 1997-98,
which really didn't affect Australia at all. And that kind of confirmed the view that, you know,
well, our policy settings are so good, look, we didn't even suffer contagion in the Asian
financial crisis. And actually, our economic performance during that period was so good that
North American commentators, including very senior ones, started dubbing Australia the miracle economy. program run by the International Monetary Fund that came out of the interminable meetings
that followed the Asian financial crisis, we in Australia received a visit from a very
smart team of IMF officials.
I remember I was a member of the Council of Financial Regulators at the time because I
was Treasury Secretary.
It's a four-person council that's chaired by the Reserve Bank Governor.
The Treasury Secretary sits on it.
The Chairman of APRA and the Chairman of ASIC sit
on this four-person council.
And we had a preliminary meeting.
It was like day one of this group being in Australia.
And the mission leader said, look, and we'd supplied them
with boxes and boxes of documents before they arrived in Australia.
So they were incredibly well briefed, you know.
And he said, thank you for all the material you've provided.
And I'm pretty sure, like I can't prejudge this,
but I'm pretty sure that in six months' time when we come back
and talk to you, we're going to say the Australian financial system
is very robust, you know.
You're doing everything right.
But there's one thing that worries me.
Oh, what's that?
He said, the one thing that worries me is your reliance upon short-term debt flows
to finance what's going on in this place and it's all intermediated or largely intermediated by
your domestic banking system and he said i don't actually quite know what to make of it, but it has me a bit worried.
And I'm thinking, oh, he's a debt and deficits guy, right?
That's what he is.
Anyway, we politely wished him well and off he went.
And six months later, he came back with his team and he said, well,
you know, this has turned out very much as I thought it would. Australian financial system is in really good health. You've got very well regulated
institutions. Your regulators are world-class. You've adopted all these relevant international
standards, blah, blah, blah. But there's one thing that worries me. And he said, after six months,
it worries me even more. And that's your reliance upon
short-term debt flows. So then we had a conversation about it. And I remember saying to him,
let's think that through. So in what circumstances, so this is 2006,
in what circumstances should we be really worried about that?
We've done everything we possibly can in terms of policy settings
and institutional settings and so on.
So in what circumstances would we have to worry about the fact
that we are reliant upon this flow of capital from offshore,
short-term debt, even if it is short-term debt.
You know, why should we be worried about it?
And we had a bit of a discussion about it, and I remember saying to him,
I think what you're saying is that this is something we really should worry about if the global financial system collapses.
And he just smiled, right?
And we just smiled at one another and had a bit of a chuckle,
and that was that.
But anyway, they printed the report in 2006, and it does,
you can go back, you can dig it out, and it has that concern in it.
It is in it.
It's sitting in there saying that I'm a bit worried about it.
That's 2006.
And two years later, Lehman's collapses and bang.
And what do you know?
That was our Achilles heel.
That was the thing that was problem number one for us.
And a huge problem was this reliance upon short-term capital inflows.
It was the debt and deficits issue, recast, but nevertheless,
there it was, was our Achilles heel.
I have three specific questions about that FSAP report.
Yep.
And then I'll come back to the narratives question.
So the first question is, does it really matter
if the debt isn't denominated in a foreign currency?
Ah, you've got, okay.
So we did see this as a big advantage for us
that we were able to sell debt in Australian dollar,
in Australian dollar debt, right?
The issue, though, is that if the debt is denominated
in your currency, then at some point the interest rates
you pay are going to reflect expectations
of bilateral currency movements, right?
So if the people lending you the money think, oh, there is a risk,
a substantial risk that the Australian dollar is going to depreciate,
right, then they will demand a higher interest rate, right,
to cover the currency loss in the value of the asset that they hold,
you know, debt for us asset for them.
So it can be reflected in interest rates.
Of course, and the reason for your question is that there's no question
about your ability to repay the debt in Australian dollar terms
because you can always print money, right?
Yeah, exactly.
The Reserve Bank can be a lender of last resort.
Correct, correct.
But it can only – oh, well, look, if you were borrowing in US dollars,
to some extent the reserve bank could also be a lender of last resort,
right, provided it's got sufficient reserves.
But pretty soon it's going to run out of those reserves, right,
of US dollars.
So, and you want to avoid that.
So it makes sense, obviously, to be able to issue debt
in your own currency.
So you are then in control of
the question of whether you can ever repay that and um creditors those lending you money they
they can drive some comfort from the fact that they will uh get their money back but they're
going to get it back in australian dollars and what are those australian dollars going to be worth
and they may be worthless and And so, I mean, relative
to the dollars that matter to them, which is generally US dollars. And so
those, and so they, in
order to protect their own interest rate, are going to be demanding higher and higher interest
rates. And so that's how the cost is reflected. So
yeah, it matters. Yeah.
My second question about the FSA report is to what extent is offshore wholesale borrowing
still the key vulnerability of our financial system?
Yeah. Yeah. And that's why I said in response to your earlier question
that even though we're in a current account surplus position,
I don't think we should be sanguine about the debt
and deficits narrative.
I mean, we've got to be careful about the way
in which we interpret it. The – one day, hopefully, our investment rate will bounce back.
And when our investment rate bounces back, our reliance upon offshore capital, including short-term debt, is going to increase.
Now, look, that doesn't necessarily imply that we're going to have the sort of extreme volatility ever again that we had
in the global financial crisis.
And it may very well be that, and I know, I mean,
there were people, including in the Reserve Bank
and very senior people in the Reserve Bank,
who even in the middle of the global financial crisis said,
well, you know, it makes sense for the government
to guarantee these debt lines as a form of insurance,
but really are the capital markets going to remain closed for an extended period
or is this just going to be a short-term thing
until people sort out, you know, who they can trust
and who they can't trust, you know?
And as soon as they get around to figuring out
who they can trust, they're going to look at Australia
and say, well, we can certainly trust them, right?
Because they never miss a payment and, you know, look at their track record.
But the general view taken at the time was that it was worth
taking out quite a lot of insurance,
even if the insurance was going to be expensive.
Turns out it wasn't expensive for the budget at all.
We actually made money out of it.
But, I mean, would I be courageous enough to say
that we should never expect to see a repeat of anything
like the global financial crisis, which at its core, it was all about counterparty risk or really about people's views on whether they could, the extent to which they could rely upon undertakings that were being given by their counterparties in the financial system.
And they just lost confidence lost trust lost trust and
it's trust that you know holds the whole thing together really i mean contracts of course but
really in the in the moment it's trust when you're picking up the phone and doing a deal can you trust
the person on the other end of the line um and that's what that's what fell apart really in the global financial crisis.
Turns out the activities of governments were sufficiently swift and large
as to be able to rebuild a sufficient level of trust in quite a short period of time,
will that always be the case?
I don't know.
And I just think that, well, I don't think we should assume
that that will always be the case.
And there is therefore, I think, a risk that's inherent in, well, you know, what I was going to say is that there's a risk that's
inherent in a world of mobile capital flows. But even if you cut yourself off from the rest of the world, this risk of one part
of the system losing confidence in another player
in maybe the same part of the system or even a different part
of the system upon which they rely, that's still
a fundamental question, right?
So it's really at base how confident can you be that the claims being made
by your counterparties and the undertakings that they're giving you
that they can be relied upon?
For the most part, it's been good, I mean, more than good, right?
I think actually the ability of the global financial system
and national financial systems to be able to, you know,
mediate flows of capital that go into building productive capacity
and allowing people to buy houses and, you know, everything really, is an extraordinary success story for economics, really.
But there is that fragility or is it a fragility?
Anyway, look, there's a risk that's inherent in it
and you can do a lot, of course, to manage that risk,
but there will always be residual risk, always,
sitting out there in the tail somewhere, right,
that most times you can ignore.
It turns out you can safely ignore what's sitting out in that tail,
but every now and again that tail is going to whip you.
My third F'sSAP question is, by the time the financial crisis struck,
only three of the 183 IMF member states hadn't completed their F-SAP.
Yeah.
And one of them was the United States.
Yeah.
How much would it have helped the US if they had that F-SAP report
or was the pain already baked in?
They wouldn't have taken any notice of it because of the politics.
Well, I don't know if it's – it's certainly not big P politics.
There's, right, it is that the IMF, I think generally the IMF is incapable of criticising the United States in any meaningful fashion.
Right.
Well, at least it was.
I don't know if that is still the case.
So that's the first point.
Second point is, were the IMF to do so,
I don't think the United States would have taken any notice. And why? Well, I just, look,
I just think the domestic scene, and you can call it politics, the domestic political scene then
in the United States is impervious to international criticism. And that's what this would have been
seen, would have been seen as an international organisation
taking a potshot at us.
And I think that's generally true of international organisations,
just the general.
I'm no expert on the psyche of the United States as an entity,
if it's legitimate to talk about such a thing,
but I think they're pretty impervious to international criticism, right?
Maybe this is part of the, when people talk about US exceptionalism,
maybe it's part of what they're talking about,
is that the United States sees itself as standing apart.
And there's, I mean, I delivered a speech at the ANU in 2004,
which was a Bretton Woods sort of function.
And I reflected in this speech that on the history of the Bretton Woods institutions
and what I saw as their declining effectiveness,
in part it was a consequence of their own success,
which is that, remember, when they were established,
they were established in a world of fixed exchange rates.
And the IMF and its principal lending programs
were actually designed to forestall or deal
with a balance payments crisis in a country
that's got fixed exchange rates, right?
Where, as we were talking about before,
it experiences capital outflow,
and a central bank for some time can actually meet the outflow
from its reserves, but then the reserves are drained very quickly.
This is what we saw in the Asian financial crisis.
You know, Bank of Thailand, I don't know how many days
of reserves they had, but it disappeared pretty quickly, right?
And then the Thai bar just tanked.
And when you move to a world of flexible exchange rates,
it's just much less likely that anybody's going to need
to rely on the International Monetary Fund for support,
for financial support, because how do you have a balance
of payments crisis in a world of flexible exchange rates?
I guess it's possible, but it's just very unlikely.
It's probably not the problem you're going to be dealing with.
And so did countries really, in this world of flexible exchange rates,
did they really have to pay that much attention to what the IMF was saying?
One of the good things about Australia was that in that period,
certainly up to the global financial crisis,
we were as a community, broadly defined,
highly sensitive to international criticism,
whether it was the OECD, the International Monetary Fund,
the World Bank to some extent.
Not the United Nations somewhat deplorably, but anyway,
I mean, that's, like, it criticises all they like about the treatment
of asylum seekers and so on, and nobody seems to give a stuff.
But if you're talking about financial matters,
then Australia has historically been quite sensitive
to that sort of criticism.
You don't see it in a lot of other countries,
but you most certainly don't see it in the United States.
So, yeah, you're right, the United States was one of only three.
Anyway, in that 2004 speech, I said that, you know,
I pointed out that there's no reason for the United States
to take any notice of the IMF, and yet I said that, and this was true at the time,
that the United States was, had become,
the biggest debtor nation in the world, right?
And it was borrowing from the rest of the world
to fund its current account deficit.
And, of course, it was actually borrowing certainly more than half.
And in some months, all of its borrowings were being funded
by the People's Bank of China, right?
So it was selling US treasuries to the People's Bank of China
that was just rapidly building up huge stores
of US treasuries.
And I just said, and I thought it was kind of obvious,
that the biggest risk to the global financial system right now
has to be the United States and the quality
of its domestic financial system.
That was in 2004.
And the IMF had drawn attention to this earlier in 2004.
This was not a novel proposition.
It's just nobody took any bloody notice of it.
And certainly in the United States, they didn't.
But when I said it in Australia, a lot of commentators got stuck into me.
They said, what the hell are you talking about?
Blah, blah, blah.
It's unnecessarily alarmist.
Anyway, it's not true.
Blah, blah, blah.
The United States should have been acting on its financial system fragilities
through those early years of the 21st century.
When I, after the collapse of Bear Stearns,
found myself accompanying Treasurer Swan on meetings in Washington and New York, so this was early 2008.
It was before Lehman's collapsed.
And I had, we had, we had, it was actually the Treasurer, of course,
who was the principal interlocutor in the meetings, obviously,
and I was there supporting, but I was absolutely amazed
at the things I learned about the poor quality
of US financial system regulation.
I mean, absolutely gobsmacked.
And I did say to, and I remember we were walking down the steps
of the Federal Reserve and I said to Wayne Swan,
because we were reflecting on the rescue that the Federal Reserve
had been instrumental in or had organised the rescue for Bear Stearns.
And I said to Treasurer Swan, I said, God,
heaven help the next US investment bank that gets into trouble.
And he turned to me and he said, why do you say that?
And I said, they're going to let it go.
They're going to let it go.
And so when Lehman's got into trouble and they let it go,
I was not at all surprised.
You knew that because they'd been so defensive in the meeting?
Hugely defensive.
I couldn't believe how defensive.
And, you know, I'm not going to name names of who we were talking to,
but I could not believe how defensive they were.
And it was, anyway, I formed the view that they had been so beaten
up over what they'd done by, I don't know, by whom, I have no idea.
But anyway, so they were so shell-shocked they wouldn't do it again.
Today, of course, they would do it again, right?
I mean, I think they're different now.
It's a different institution.
But in those days, and you remember in the UK as well,
I mean, it was Northern Rock that was earlier,
if my memory serves me correct.
And before Northern Rock collapsed, you had Mervyn King
as Governor of the Bank of England talking about the evils
of moral hazard, right?
And he was trying to get out.
I think he was actually trying to get out ahead of all this.
He saw that there was a possibility of financial institutions collapsing
and he wanted to lecture the policymakers in the United
Kingdom. And I understand they took umbrage at this, small wonder, but he wanted to give them
a lecture about the evils of moral hazard. And there were people in the United States who
had a very similar perspective, were also convinced that moral hazard was such an evil
that you had to be prepared to allow even systemically significant
institutions to fall over, even if people's lives were ruined
as a consequence.
People had to learn, even if learning the hard way,
about the risks that are involved in the economic system that we have
is gobsmacking.
Before we move on, what if I grab your dog's blanket over there
and hang it on the window so the sun's not shining in your eyes?
It's kind of irritating, really.
Do you want me to try something?
Yeah, and while you do that, take a look at Ned.
There he is.
Oh, my God.
That's wonderful.
Actually, it will probably move around that way because the sun will go in that sort of arc, won't it?
No, no, no.
I can move a little if that's okay.
If I move this around.
Oh, that's great.
Yeah.
I reckon that'll be fine for a while.
Yep.
Oh, that's much better.
Move as much as you like.
You can take the mic with you.
Oh, okay.
To go back to the mid-'80s when Keating was constructing
the Australian mercantilism narrative and the debt
and deficits narrative.
Yeah.
At the time, did you have any sense that these narratives
would eventually metastasise?
No.
No, I didn't.
No, no, no.
Oh, God, now you make me feel really uncomfortable.
So because I'm now asking myself the question, suppose I did,
what would I have done about it?
And I was so impressed by what Keating was doing.
I think if I'm to be honest with myself, I don't think I would have
dissuaded him or sought, not that it would have been effective, but I don't think I would have sought to dissuade him from using it.
Even though, even had I seen how it was going to be brutalized really by the Australian political system subsequently.
I mean, that's, I've never reflected on that question before, so thank you for asking it.
And I feel a bit uncomfortable answering it,
but I think that is the truth.
I think, I mean, I don't, I'm not generally in the ends justify
the means camp, not generally, because I think that so many of the things we regard as means
are significantly important ends in their own right.
Yeah, but I think I would have forgiven him this one.
And I forgive him in retrospect.
I mean, I don't think one should blame him
for having constructed that narrative just because others have used it for base political purposes.
What gives a politician a talent for crafting compelling narratives?
Because presumably it's not like smarts or intelligence isn't sufficient.
So then plenty of very smart politicians who've failed miserably at this.
What gives one the ability to be good at crafting political narratives?
Again, I feel like I almost have to answer this question the way I imagine
Paul Keating answering it. And I think he would say you've got to be a storyteller
and you've got to be comfortable with telling stories.
I mean, more than comfortable, you have to like telling stories.
And it's more than being a raconteur.
It has to be stories that expose people's minds to things that,
either things they would never have thought about or to thinking about things in a completely different way, in a way that they'd never
thought about or to thinking about things in a completely different way, in a way that they'd never thought about them before.
And he had the capacity to do that, right?
To just completely wrong foot you, then to get you to think about an issue
in a completely different way, and then to make you feel comfortable and safe again.
And that's a really, I think it's quite an extraordinary ability,
but if you're not drawn to the storytelling business,
then it's probably not a game for you.
Actually, my younger brother said to me somewhat unkindly the other day,
and he's a mathematician, a theoretical physicist,
and he said to me somewhat unkindly, he said, and yet it's true,
he said, is economics really anything more than storytelling?
Well, it's probably not.
Not really.
Storytelling through models.
Yeah.
Yeah, yeah.
Storytelling through models, yeah.
Yeah.
Well, it's the models that give you some confidence that there's an inherent logic in the argument.
Okay.
Even though you have to accept that the model itself
is going to be flawed.
I mean, it's going to be flawed necessarily in respect of scope
because a model can't possibly incorporate everything
that you see out there, and it would be of no use
if you tried to construct such a model.
But it's also going to be flawed in respect of the assumptions
upon which it has to rely, right?
And so it's necessarily going to be fought in those
respects but even even accepting all of that it's the model that's going to give you some confidence
in the intellectual rigor of the argument but then you have to convert that formalized model
into something which is uh a really compelling story,
a story that grabs people's attention.
And more than that, and it's not just a story.
There's something quite unusual about these stories
that we've been talking about, which is that you want the listener
to become a part of the story as it unfolds.
You're not telling an historical story.
You're not telling a story in history.
You're actually talking about a story of, yes, the present,
and to some extent the past, yes, but more importantly about the future.
And you want these listeners to be a part of that story,
players in that story, participants in that story, and feeling good about the development of that story as they go along.
It's quite an unusual story telling quality, really, that is needed of our leaders.
But it's always been true.
I mean, I think it's always been true. I mean, I think it's always been true. And you go and read Shakespeare's words on the great leaders,
you know, on which he spent a lot of time,
all flawed characters, of course.
But nevertheless, their stories were largely about encouraging others
to be part of a different future from the one that was actually confronting them,
whether in the near term or the distant term.
Yeah.
That's really interesting.
I mean, you're right.
That's what separates political narratives from history.
Political narratives connect past, present, and future.
That's right.
Yeah, yeah.
I want to ask you some questions about Treasury and the public service,
but let me segue to that from narratives by asking this question.
So traditionally there's been this distinction between the sort of work
that a government agency like Treasury would do which is almost like the object
level policy analysis and then the storytelling aspect or the crafting of the narratives is left
to the politicians to the government in recent years economists like bob schiller have started
talking about the importance of narratives in economics as like something that should actually belong
in the object level economic analysis.
Yeah.
Bob has a book called Narrative Economics.
Yeah.
Should Treasury actually be prepared to provide advice
to the government on economic narratives
and which economic narratives will work?
Yes.
And my answer to that's unequivocal.
Did that happen when you were in Treasury?
Yes, it did.
Yeah, it did.
It did.
I mean, that's actually what motivated a lot of the work that we did
on wellbeing, right?
That was about us.
I mean, we weren't asked to do that.
Nobody said to us, oh, we'd like you to think about a wellbeing framework to guide the way that we, the government, think about economic, social and environmental policy.
No, we constructed this wellbeing framework ourselves to be able to recast narratives that we presented to government
in the expectation that the government would then change its own narrative or broaden its
own narrative to deal with some really, really difficult issues. Think of entrenched Indigenous disadvantage, for example,
where, and that's not a success story, right,
but the narrative did change.
The narrative did change.
I think it, I think, look, it did, I think without the change
in the narrative, it would have been really highly improbable
that the Closing the Gap narrative would have been constructed.
I just don't think it would have.
And the notion of, which has not been well respected,
but nevertheless is understood within government and has been for a long time,
the notion of involving Indigenous people at the grassroots level
in discussion of, sorry, policy design, the design of policies
that will improve their circumstances.
That notion, I think the wellbeing framework did make a contribution
to that as well.
Not that it's a novel notion.
I mean, it certainly wasn't a novel notion at the time.
Many Indigenous leaders had been banging on about it for decades, right?
It was just that there was a tin ear in Canberra, really, I think,
until we started having those discussions about a broader framework
for thinking about progress, economic, social
and environmental progress, but particularly economic and social.
And so, yes, I do think that should be a core competency of an economic policy agency.
And that was my view at the time.
I remember, here's an interesting thing I had shortly become what's called a band two SES officer
In most government departments in Canberra these days
That position is referred to as a first assistant secretary
In the military it's a two-star general, right?
So that's the level we're talking about
I mean in the army it's a two-star general
Major general right so that's the level we're talking about i mean in the army it's two-star general um
major general and um i attended a residential uh leadership course uh in i think was in bower
if my memory serves me correctly it was five days and um one afternoon we had a fellow come in full
of uh enthusiasm with uh literature that had been that had come out of the Harvard Business School
and it was all about strategic alignment.
And he had this, and I don't know whether this,
I don't know whether he was relying on any literature
or whether this was just his own bright idea,
but the proposition that he was putting to these relatively senior public servants was that we should think about
strategic alignment in the same way that businesses think about strategic alignment.
And of course, what he was talking about was businesses identifying their customer base
and then understanding everything about their customers.
You know, what does it make some tick?
If you want to be successful as a business,
you've really got to understand your customers, right?
These days it's called customer centricity.
I mean, who would have thought, right?
As if this is a really amazing idea.
But then he was saying, and what that means is that in the private sector, that means you should think
about even your organisational structure in terms
of how you can best match the personality.
You can see where this is going, I suspect.
But anyway, match the personality of your customers, right?
And then he said, and that's how you should be thinking
about your own departments.
And he went into it, you know, you've really got to understand
what makes the minister tick, everything about the minister.
And I was getting increasingly uncomfortable, right?
There were 22 or 23 of us sitting around the table.
At some point I put up my hand and I said,
excuse me, what if your minister is an idiot?
And, you know, he was uncomfortable.
I think everybody in the room was uncomfortable, right?
But seriously, what if your minister is an idiot?
And then, look, actually he dealt with the question.
I thought I was surprised at how well he dealt with the question.
But then I said, so are you saying, I said, sorry, let's take this up one other level, another level, right?
So what then about the minister?
How should the minister be constructing his or her own persona?
I mean, who is their customer, right?
Or is it even valid to think about a minister as having a customer or a set of customers for whom they are seeking
to deliver high-quality product?
And maybe it's the case that ministers are just responding in the main,
just responding to events.
And this was, I know, quite a radical thing to say, but I said,
is it never appropriate for a public servant, even a senior public servant,
to go out into the public arena and construct such an event?
The narrative for such an event anyway, right?
Because maybe that is, in certain circumstances,
the way to have maximum impact.
In certain circumstances, maybe you should be seeking
to influence the truly external environment,
the one in which both you and the minister are operating, right,
and not just rely on a conversation between you
and the minister as to what should be happening.
And I think, I mean, I've got some support
for that view subsequently, not in that room, not at that time.
I think everybody said, not everybody.
There was a rear admiral who thought it was quite
a reasonable proposition, although he didn't disclose that at the time.
He disclosed it to me the following morning at breakfast
when he said, I didn't realise how similar Treasury
and Defence are until you made that comment.
And I said to him, well, you shouldn't assume
that this is Treasury speaking, this was just me.
But it is a really...
But subsequently, I think there was, at least for a period,
there was an acceptance of senior public servants
having voice in the public square, provided they're
not embarrassing the government, nor embarrassing the opposition, you know, not embarrassing the
political players, but nevertheless, talking about the challenges confronting the country,
and in general terms, about the sort of policy directions that would probably have to be followed if we were to
avoid the risks the traps associated with with those challenges or make the most of the opportunities
that those developments present for the nation there was there was some uh level of comfort
with that i would say that during the 10 years of the former government,
there was no comfort with that,
excluding in the national security and defence space,
which is quite extraordinary.
But I do think that's the case.
And I think we lost a hell of a lot because of that.
You see, one of the things, one of the deep flaws,
is it a flaw?
Let me talk it through, see if it's a flaw.
I think one of the deep flaws in our system of government is that we rely upon adversarial instruments for almost everything, right?
So, oh, well, our political system is adversarial.
Our legal system is adversarial. Our legal system is
adversarial. Actually, the capitalist model is adversarial in its construction, right? That
you've got businesses out there doing nothing other than seeking to maximize profit. It's up
to the rest of us. Actually, that was the phrase that Milton Friedman used, right? The rest of us
to use our agency as citizens in a democracy. He didn't quite use that phraseology,
but that's what he was talking about,
to force these, oh, to elect politicians
who would frame rules and regulations
and would resource regulatory agencies
and the judicial system such that it would force profit maximising businesses to operate in a competitive manner without fraud or deception being inflicted upon the public. that in its construction is adversarial.
It sets the corporation up against the rest of us, right,
and the rest of us having to get in there and muscle it.
So much of it is adversarial.
And one of the consequences of that is that the sort of institutions of civil society
that you necessarily have to rely upon to keep the political actors honest,
or at least to call out the bullshit,
is that they get seduced into reporting the contest rather than what is at contest, right?
So they become no more than enthusiastic commentators
of a gladiatorial spectacle, right?
You even think about, as I have done and had to,
the way that the Financial Services or Banking and Financial Services
Royal Commission was constructed.
It became, and I think quite deliberately, a reality TV show.
And what was reported overwhelmingly wasn't the substance
of what was being discussed, but rather the arguments
that were being put on either side and who performed better.
So who won the gladiatorial contest? contest uh and you can understand why but you need to have uh a voice of the experts that's
external from all of that and which precedes all of that that is calling out the bullshit when the
bullshit is being espoused by the politicians or whoever they are, really,
the redneck commentators or whoever, right?
And I think we've lost a lot of that.
And maybe there's a lot of people who point to social media here
and say, well, it's the fault of social media. It's just kind of
oxygenated the place so much that considered analysis from respectable commentators and
even considered reporting of what's going on by responsible journalists. It's just all too hard, you know.
And, you know, that's probably true, but only to some extent. I remember even before I entered the public service
when I was still a junior academic, I was a junior academic
in New Zealand in the last years of the Muldoon government, right?
There was no social media.
There was media.
There were two publicly owned television stations,
TV1 and TV2, right?
And when Parliament was sitting,
every afternoon when Parliament was sitting,
Sir Robert Muldoon would call a press conference.
There were two TV cameras in the room
and TV camera operators
and maybe one or two or three journalists.
And he would say something outrageous.
And it would lead the evening news, both channels.
So when New Zealanders were sitting down, tucking into their dinner,
watching the evening news, they saw Sir Robert Muldoon saying
something really outrageous but quite entertaining,
usually highly divisive, you know, disparaging his opponents
and quite often disparaging Australians, by the way,
because it worked really well in New Zealand.
Punching up.
Yeah, punching up.
Exactly.
And at the time I thought, you know, at the time I thought,
this is just populist crap.
How can these journalists allow, why do they even show it?
Right now, I know you showed it because he healed the purse strings, right? But actually,
I think there's always been a temptation on the part of even good journalists to report
on the punches being thrown more than the reason for the punches being thrown, right? So it's a real trap. And I think that in Australia over many years now,
we've lost something that I think we once had.
Maybe I'm just looking back with rose-tinted glasses, probably am, I think there was a time when we had media that were less inclined
to be seduced by that kind of stuff and more interested
in the substance of the issues.
But we also had academics who were in the public place,
experts, I mean genuine experts, right, who were in the public place, experts, I mean, genuine experts, right, who were in the public space seeking to educate the public about these things.
Now, we haven't lost that entirely.
And publications like The Conversation have gone a long way.
And I think, I mean, what you do, right, what you do in getting to the heart of the issues
and not just the personalities, right?
That kind of stuff, I think, is really, really important.
And we need more of it, right, to hold this show together
because there are dangers inherent in the adversarial contest
that really could blow the whole place up.
This is what Trump was doing in the United States.
Sure, he was being advantaged by social media.
I would wake up, as you would, every morning in Australia,
but in the probably 12 months or 18 months in the run-up up to the last presidential election,
you would have woken up every morning to the lead story
on the news being something amazingly ridiculous
that Donald Trump had tweeted overnight, right?
The whole world was.
I miss those days.
Yeah, right.
See, I think a lot of people do, right?
They do miss it because of the entertainment in it.
But here's the thing.
So Robert Muldoon thing tells me that even without social media,
you would have been waking up to that stuff.
He would have found a way of getting it on the TV cameras
and we would have got it.
If it's sufficiently outrageous, we would have got it, right,
because people are just so drawn to the drama and the theatre
and the, you know, as much as they say, oh, I hate politicians,
they love the entertainment content in the political argument.
And then the last thing I'll say on this point, well,
I should never say it's the last thing I'll say, but you know what? I have had very senior ministers open up to me and tell me things as troubling as, you know what?
I've never had any interest in policy.
The only reason I came into parliament was because I was a good barrister and I enjoy the argument.
Because if you're going to have that sort of adversarial system where what's valued
is the perceived quality of those engaged in the combat, those are the people who are going to be drawn to it, right?
Think also of the dumbing down of debate that you get
when interviewers, unlike what you do,
because you've let me rabbit on and on and on and on,
but when interviewers say, look, we're about to go to a break, by which they mean we're about to earn
some money from advertisers, we've only got a few seconds. I'm going to ask you a really
complicated question, and I want you to give me a three-word answer. And what are you going to get?
Well, you're going to get a three-word slogan
and small wonder that eventually australia ends up with a politician like tony abbott
right what do you expect um so there are real risks in this and we've got to be
alive to those risks and we've got to make sure that the other institutions of society are capable of
and really do contribute to a better informed public.
And I do think that leaders of public institutions,
including institutions like the Treasury,
do have a role to play here.
That comment that Minister made to you is disturbing.
For me, it's also indicative of this kind of culture of individualism
that emerged in the West beginning around the 1970s where now you have
this whole class of politicians for whom a seat in parliament is a prize rather than a responsibility.
Sure.
That's the goal.
Yeah.
Yeah, yeah.
And hanging on to it at all costs is the goal.
Yeah.
No matter how many deals you have to do with the devil.
Yeah.
And regardless of what policy you actually get done.
Yeah, yeah.
A few more questions about the public service.
Yeah. A few more questions about the public service. So when I was preparing for this conversation,
I read a Canberra Times article about you from 2006
that mentions you putting in 100-hour weeks
at the Treasury in the 80s and the 90s.
Yeah.
And it also mentioned this anecdote about how in the mid-80s
you would slip a tax draft under your division head,
David Morgan's door at like 3am.
Yeah.
By 8am, he's up and he's read it and responded to it.
Yeah.
$100 a week is a lot.
Yeah.
Was that A, something unique to treasury because it's got things like budget week it has to
deal with, B, something unique to the reform era and the sort of esprit de corps of the
80s and 90s, C, something unique to senior officials or D, something unique to the reform era and the sort of esprit de corps of the 80s and 90s,
C, something unique to senior officials,
or D, something unique to Ken Henry?
B and A, and probably in that order.
Wow.
Because I was not unique.
It certainly was not unique.
There were a team of us who were working those sorts of hours.
And look, not all the time, obviously.
I mean, you can't work those sorts of hours all the time and survive for very much time.
But there were several times in my treasury career going
for several months at a time when, yes,
I did work those sorts of ridiculous hours.
And the only reason I know it's 100 hours is that during the 1985 process
when, you know, I referred to this earlier where there was just
maybe a bit more than one handful of policy officers
who were working on the content of what became called
the Draft White Paper on Tax Reform. officers who were working on the content of what became called the draft white paper on
tax reform.
And at some point, Paul Keating, observing the sort of hours that we were working, said
to somebody more senior than me in the department, are these people getting paid any overtime?
And actually, I don't know if you know this, but at a certain, once you reach a certain
level in the public service, you don't qualify for overtime.
Anyway, we were all at that level.
No, there was one person in our group who was below that level, but all the others were at that level or above.
So we didn't qualify for any overtime at all.
And so the answer was, oh, well, actually, no, I don't think any of them are being paid overtime.
And he wasn't aware of how many hours we were working,
but he knew that it was ridiculous.
And so somebody senior in the department said, well,
I think you'd better keep timesheets for the next three months.
Keep timesheets, right?
And we'll see if we can do something.
We're not compelled to do anything.
You don't deserve overtime.
But we'll see if
there's something that we can do. And that was when I, and so I did. And then I trotted it all
up and over the three month period, it averaged a hundred hours a week. And that was, ironically,
and I should have been smarter. I should have figured this one out. But, of course, when you calculate how much overtime
I would have been entitled to for that three-month period,
it was larger than my annual salary, right?
So it was so big that I didn't get a cent.
I should have been smarter, right?
I should have said I was 70 hours, you know, or 60 hours.
Even 45 hours, I would have got something.
Yeah.
But at 100 hours, I got nothing, right?
But during budget week, or more than budget week,
during the run-up to the preparation of the annual budget,
there are people who do work those hours in Treasury.
Yes, there are.
And then at particular times like that 1985 tax summit,
yeah, it does happen.
And it's, of course, it's not appropriate, right?
And yet there is something in it that speaks volumes
about the sort of organisation that that place is, at least was, and I'm sure still is.
And there isn't a spread of core in it.
And look, some politicians are working those sorts
of hours too, right?
I mean, most people have no idea of the hours
that politicians work.
And maybe it's not all work either.
I mean, maybe it's not all what you and I would regard
as being worthwhile work, but it is part of their job.
Or they won't survive in their job if they don't do it.
And so that kind of stuff does happen.
But, I mean, it's also true, the D is also true
because I could have opted out, you know, obviously.
And I could have said this game's not for me.
And, of course, there were times when I had that feeling, of course,
but you go on and it's for the reason that I mentioned in answer
to your very first question, you know, it's just those periods
are just a blast, an absolute blast.
And you are full of adrenaline and you just go on and on and on.
And, you know, it's probably both a good thing and a bad thing
that humans are capable of, that sort of thing.
You see it all over the place, not just in policy development, right?
And sometimes it's for the good and sometimes it's actually for the bad.
So, Ken, you can correct this if it's wrong,
but I heard a story that you famously wrote Prismod in 1991
on about 20-odd sheets of paper one night.
And those sheets of paper may have even been a translation
from like the back of a
coaster or a napkin um you know hastily hastily written on uh late one night in a canberra
restaurant is that is that anecdote correct and how much of policy happens like that um you know
like a brilliant public servant just kind of whipping something up versus like a slower,
more formal process?
I don't know the answer to that question.
Oh, sorry.
The first part of the question, that's broadly correct.
It's the architecture of Prismod.
Of course, Prismod is a huge model.
It ended up being the, I think the OECD certainly described
it as the most detailed economic model
that had ever been constructed.
It probably was.
But there's a reason for that, which we can go into if you want to,
but it doesn't really matter for this question.
But so it's broadly correct, the architecture.
How much of what happens in policy circles happens like that?
Yeah, I really don't know. But I do, I mean, I've seen enough instances of people having brainwaves and those brainwaves
subsequently translating into big things that, you know,
I can say it happens a bit.
It probably doesn't happen enough. into big things that, you know, I can say it happens a bit,
probably doesn't happen enough.
I mean, it's easy to say that the public service is structured
in such a way that it has insufficient flexibility
and gives people insufficient authority to be able to behave in that manner.
That's probably true, but it certainly wasn't true of the Treasury,
not from the day I first joined it.
One of the strengths of that institution was that you could be a,
well, you could be a graduate recruit and you could have an idea that challenged orthodoxy
and you could expect people to take notice of it i mean they might tell you it's complete crap
you know and go away and grow up and that's also part of what well was was a strength of the department was that um whether you're going to be listened
to or not whether notice is going to be taken of your idea or not dependent upon rank not at all
i mean just not at all so um i mean i hope that's still true but but it was true. And, yeah, I saw enough of those people having a brainwave
and things happening as a consequence to know that it is quite a feature
of or was, has been quite a feature of public policy.
So Prismod took you and about five other people
about five months to build.
How long would such a project take nowadays?
And what was the main constraint back in 1991?
Was it software, hardware?
Oh, actually, I think it would take longer now.
Really?
Yeah.
Because I don't think people would work those hours. But also that, I mean, even when that project was launched,
those launching it knew and everybody involved in it knew,
all five of us knew that this was just quite unreasonable, right?
I mean, you couldn't, you wouldn't have been able to.
John Caron gave you about four months.
Yeah.
Yeah, and that was in a, you know, a written document.
I mean, it was a letter to the secretary to say this is what I want
and I wanted to have this capability, blah, blah, blah, blah, blah.
Now, look, in truth, we could have done a slimmed-down version
and we could have achieved, well, I guess, an acceptable outcome
in a less stressful way, but, uh, several of us, several of us, the total
was five, um, a couple of us had been involved in, um, uh, a similar sort of exercise back in 1985.
And we were aware, we carried scars from the,
I've used this word a lot today, but brutality of the battles
that were fought around the modelling that we had done back in 1985.
And having survived that experience, we were determined that what we produced in 1991 would
be technically unassailable, that nobody would be able to say, this is shonky, you've cut corners, you've ignored blah, blah, blah.
And so, you know, the data demands were absolutely immense.
A lot of data, what you would call data, had to be constructed from scratch.
So, I mean, think about this, right?
Maybe this is one way of describing the challenge.
So, imagine a matrix that's got 109 different industries identified.
So, that's your columns, 109.
Yeah.
And then it's got 1,400 rows.
And those rows identify commodities that are purchased
by those 109 industries.
So 1,400 commodities purchased by 109 industries, right?
That's got some scale.
That's big.
And then you just say to somebody, and this is in the days before the GST,
so we had, I think at the time it was the world's most complex
indirect tax system, multiple rate wholesale sales tax, excises,
and these things were not just levied at final point of sale, right?
I mean, wholesale sales tax is obviously not. excises and these things were not just levied at final point of sale right i mean hostess hostex
obviously not um so they applied to industry purchases of commodities of products and
uh we had to know with some level of precision
how the wholesale sales tax revenue was distributed
across all those cells, right?
Well, nobody would have done that before, and why the hell would they, right?
It took months for a couple of people.
It was only a couple of people because we couldn't afford any more in terms of resources.
It took them months to get their head around that question.
And it's just a, I mean, you could say, well, it's just a statistical exercise.
But they had to do it with a high level of precision.
It had to be unassailable.
And, of course, what they discovered, I mean, they discovered all sorts of things like we should be collecting more household sales tax revenue. If the base is really that big,
then how come we're not collecting enough household sales tax revenue? And then in other
cases, we're getting more household sales tax revenue than that um that suggests that the
the abs's input output data are wrong uh and so we had this toing and frying with the abs
and they did amend the input output data on several occasions because of this exchange
it just doesn't make sense we can't make sense of this.
So we ended up creating data sets that had never previously existed,
and we ended up helping the ABS revise.
I'm not saying a complete transformation, don't get me wrong,
but nevertheless revise, in important ways,
data sets that had been around for quite a while. Now, it probably helped us that one of the members of the team, and indeed a fellow who,
a very close colleague of mine, unfortunately now deceased, but who went through the 1985
exercise.
We sat shoulder to shoulder working those 100-hour weeks through the 1985 exercise, and he was also a member,
key team member of this exercise.
And at an earlier time in his career, he had spent 10 years
as head of the input-output section in the Australian Bureau of Statistics,
and he actually compiled Australia's first ever input-output tables.
And that is, I mean, it's just chance, right?
Just extraordinary.
Actually, to clock back a bit, because this is,
I think this is actually part of the answer to your question
or maybe your earlier question, but in the 1985 exercise,
we needed to answer questions like this.
Well, suppose you replace the household sales tax
with a broad-based consumption tax that applies in the following way
at the following rate with input taxing of certain transactions
in these places, these places, these places,
zero rating or exemption in these places, these places, these places, Zero rating or exemption in these places, these places,
these places, right?
Adjustments to excises and blah, blah, blah, blah, blah.
Now tell me what happens to the CPI.
Mm-hmm.
Well, nobody had ever done anything like that before.
And the task was handed to one person because we were a small team, right?
And this guy, he was given the task because he had previously worked
in the Australian Bureau of Statistics at some stage
in the National Accounts area, I think.
He then went on to become quite a good journalist years later.
And he spent weeks nutting his head through this
and he produced a piece of paper that was more than 50 pages in length.
It was probably 55, I think that's from memory anyway.
And I saw this and I thought, oh, my God, you know, this is, well,
firstly, poor bugger, and then secondly, so now we're going to be asked,
well, hang on, what if I tweak this right here and tweak that there
and tweak, then what happens?
So we're going to have to wait another three weeks while this poor bugger
goes through all of this again and produces his workings manually,
you know.
And I thought and I said and I went to this colleague who I knew
had worked in the input-output section in the ABS and I said,
you know what we need here is what in economics is referred
to as a price input output model. I've never seen one except in the textbooks. I don't know if one
even exists anywhere in the world, but that's what we need and that's what we need to construct.
And he just beamed at me, right? And he said, oh, well, you know, I suppose, he said,
I suppose I do know more about the Australia's input-output system
than anybody else.
So maybe we could give this a go.
That was back in 1985.
But see, had he not been there and had I not had that,
I'd call it an insight, but, I mean, it's, you know,
it was, it's not that big an insight, but, and then ask the question
and then get the engagement from him, which was like, you know,
it was enthusiastic, like, let's give this a go, right?
Then I think maybe that poor bugger would have been, you know,
every time he would have said, well, this is going to take weeks
and destroy my life for several weeks.
And actually it wouldn't have worked.
It just wouldn't have worked.
So there is something of chance in these endeavours, I think.
You can't, and you can't plan for it.
No, you can't plan for it because you don't know what bit of kit,
what bit of technology you're going to need to answer
the policy question in a way that will provide the politicians
with what they need to be able to run the argument, construct the narrative,
convince the parliament, you know, all of that kind of stuff.
You just don't know.
It's a fascinating glimpse into how policy gets made.
Yeah.
It's also interesting that there are these decisions
that affect the wealth of nations and they're based on the policy and the advice
that the public service provides.
And ultimately, you can trace that back to one guy kind of hunched
over his desk working 100-hour weeks.
No, it's true.
And it all kind of hinges on the quality of his work.
Yeah.
Or her work.
Or her work.
All right.
But that is true.
Yeah. It her work. All right. But that is true. Yeah, it is true.
I learned a fact about you when I was preparing for this conversation,
and that is that you're colorblind.
And I wondered whether that ever caused any issues
when you were reading charts as Treasury Secretary.
You are too well briefed secretary you are too well briefed
you are too well briefed yeah and i know this became something of a running joke particularly
during the global financial crisis when there's like a red and a green line or something magenta
magenta okay uh magenta was the color that i settled on um to highlight uh i wasn't even
aware that such a color existed because being colourblind, well, why would I?
But in having charts prepared for me to look at and then think
about presenting to Kevin Rudd in particular and Wayne Swan,
you know, that group in the global financial crisis.
People got to learn that there were particular colours
that they had to use.
So there was a colour.
I know they developed a colour palette for me.
Bizarre.
But anyway, but it worked for me.
I could see these colours and the most outstanding
of which was this, it looked iridescent, but magenta colour.
And I know Kevin Rudd, at some point, he said,
why, why, why this colour?
You know, and we had a bit of a joke about it.
So he, yeah, for years afterwards, he'd rib me
about the Magenta line on the chart.
The Magenta line was always the one that I wanted to emphasise.
So it was the one that I wanted anybody in the audience
to take most notice of.
I have no idea whether it stood out for them the same way
it stood out for me.
I haven't know.
Two more questions about public service.
And then I want to ask about recession and financial crises.
Yeah.
So when Terry Moran was appointed Secretary of the Department of Prime Minister and Cabinet in 2008, he said, and I'll quote him here,
I've had a fortunate career, having often been in jobs where
I've been able to make a difference. It's not been about boring administration, but about improving
things. The Benthamite concept that the role of government is to achieve the greatest good for
the greatest number, end quote. And it got me wondering, I'm not sure whether you have thought
about this, but does the Australian public service have
a uniquely utilitarian atmosphere or are all public services
in Anglosphere countries naturally quite utilitarian?
So I think most are, even those that don't think about it.
But no, the public service doesn't have that as a philosophical framework,
even though great chunks of it do.
And look, most people in the Treasury would certainly start
with a utilitarian, indeed even welfarist perspective, you know, just a sum ranking of outcomes to assess the relative merits of different policies or different policy options and also to assess things like the big question, is human progress improving or is it not improving?
Yeah.
And I have a lot of time for utilitarians
and I've got a lot of time for that perspective,
but it's not my perspective.
I think that, for example, I think that there is a case for,
in exceptional circumstances maybe, but these exceptional circumstances
are always present, of improving the circumstances
of the most disadvantaged in society, even if you cannot demonstrate
that that lifts the sum total of utility across society.
I mean, and maybe that's, and there are a lot of utilitarians,
I'm sure, who would be jumping up and down listening to this saying,
well, that's just ridiculous because you can't even conceive
of such an intervention,
namely something that would improve the lot of the most disadvantaged and would not also result in an increase in aggregate utility.
But I'm not sure that that is the case, and I wouldn't want to constrain my thinking to possible policy interventions
that had to satisfy that test.
The reason I ask is some people think that Australia
has a uniquely utilitarian or benthamite political ideology
sort of embedded in our political DNA from the days of Chartism
and the Harvester Judgment.
Yeah, yeah, yeah.
It really is powerful in Australia and maybe more powerful
in Australia than in other places.
And by the way, one of the other, and this is not by the way,
actually one of the really attractive features of that is that people don't get so hung up on uh concepts of procedural
fairness like you know rights and liberties and things like that and and storm the barricades if
um you know if their individual personal liberties have been infringed in some arguable way, that's a real attraction
of the utilitarian discipline is that you're just,
you're focused on the outcomes rather than,
so you're focused on the ends rather than means, if you like,
to go back to something I was talking about earlier,
and you are not going to be distracted by, or you're not going to allow concepts of procedural fairness to interfere.
But then on the other hand, you're on a slippery slope, I think, or at least my view, and I don't want to insist on this, and I don't think I've ever insisted on it, but my own view is that there are some aspects of a rights-based approach that are just, in some circumstances,
so foundational, so fundamental, that if they were not delivered
by a system that was just focused on some ranking
and the aggregate sum of individual utilities,
then the society might well be breeding the
seeds of its own destruction.
And I mean, the most obvious thing to say there is that you've got to be worried about distributional consequences and not just aggregate.
And you can't draw comfort from the fact that, well,
you can draw some comfort from the fact that the aggregate condition is improving and that the majority of people are getting better off.
You can draw some comfort from that.
But you've got to allow yourself to be embarrassed by or bugged
by the fact that some people really are missing out
and may be missing out for generations maybe. maybe, and that it is incumbent upon people with policy responsibilities
to pay particular attention to those cases, right?
I think so.
But, yeah, but there is a strength.
Look, yeah, I don't want to be too critical of those
who are firmly wedded to utilitarianism because I think
it has enormous strengths.
I mean, I think in many ways governments have to be,
people almost expect their government to be utilitarian. I think they do. Yeah, yeah, yeah, I think they do. I think in many ways governments have to be, people almost expect their government to be utilitarian.
I think they do.
Yeah, yeah, yeah.
I think they do.
I think they do.
And that's, look, it's got to be a hell of a good starting point, right?
I mean, it's better than anything else that I can imagine.
Yeah.
It's just that I want them to be particularly focused in particular areas
and not allow themselves to get relaxed by what's happening
to the average or the majority or whatever.
Yep.
So many biographies have been written of political figures
in Australia.
Is there anyone in the public service, living or dead, who would be befitting of
a 700-page recollections of a bleeding heart style
biography? Are there any public servants who we need to know about?
I don't know.
One of the issues here, and it is actually quite problematic,
is that, you know, when I left the Treasury, of course,
well, not of course, but I did have a number of publishers
contact me and say, oh, oh, oh, would you like to write a memoir?
And I know other senior public servants have been asked the same question.
And I assume the same reason.
And I assume that what would sell such a memoir is a lot of stuff that would titillate people and, well,
maybe I'm being unfair, but, you know,
things that are more about the theatre or the contest than the substance.
But also, even when it's dealing with the substance of issues,
what would interest people, and understandably, is, well, what did you advise and how was that advice treated?
What was the response of the responsible minister? And I said to the treasurers that I worked for that understanding the difficult position that this could place them in down the track,
I said to them, I will never write a record of this.
I'll never write a memoir of this exchange.
You know, you don't have to worry about my ghost coming back
to haunt you at any time.
And without, because I felt that there has to be a very high level
of comfort in the confidentiality of the exchange.
Now, I've told you a couple of anecdotes, but not anecdotes, I think,
that would, and I hope, certainly hope, would not embarrass
any particular minister.
And I just wouldn't do that.
I mean, anecdotes come out of those sorts of private exchanges
that are had in absolute confidence, right?
And I feel very strongly about that.
So I think that aspect of the engagement between
or the nature of the engagement between advisors
and those charged with taking decisions, yeah, I think,
I just don't think that that should be exposed in books.
So then the question that's left is, well,
what is there left to write about?
And, of course, there's personal stuff.
But how important is that?
I mean, I think even for politicians,
it's taken on an exaggerated level of importance.
Certainly, the public has a right to know, I think,
something about the personal lives of politicians.
But there's a level beyond which it gets embarrassing
for all concerned, I think, and certainly distracting.
Well, it may be diverting, but it gets distracting.
Yeah.
So speaking of recollections of a bleeding heart,
in that book, there's this passage where Don Watson quotes Don Russell
saying that from the treasurer's office, he had heard the economy snap like a neck in 1990.
The recession we had to have finished before I was born.
What are your personal memories of the beginning of that recession?
Wow.
Yeah.
So. Wow. Yeah. Wow.
There were not many people in Paul's office at the time.
It's not like, you know, those political officers, well, sorry,
political is the wrong description.
That's the wrong adjective to use.
Those Parliament House officers are not staffed,
sorry, were not staffed in the way they are now.
So there weren't many people who have a lived experience of that
and Don is certainly, he was much, much closer to it
than anybody else in the office.
He and Paul were, I mean, the weight was very much on their shoulders
in respect of how to deal with that piece of news.
It had been, even before that particular national accounts figure came out
to confirm the two negative quarters, of course, well, once we got the first negative quarter, there was a higher risk of a successor.
But in the quarters leading up to that first negative quarter, I mean, we knew there was a significant risk that the economy would go into a recession.
The policy action that had been taken was pretty extraordinary, right?
On top of the fiscal tightening, which was being done for structural reasons, not for macroeconomic reasons.
We weren't tightening the budget in order to, well, not principally in order to dampen domestic demand. That wasn't the principal purpose of it, except in a structural sense.
We did want to rebalance private and public net savings balances.
But that was a structural thing.
It goes back to the conversation we were having earlier
about the current account and the contributors
to that current account, and the response to it
featured very heavily the twin deficits proposition
that was part of that debt and deficits narrative.
But the monetary policy response was, you know, just huge.
And it's well documented that Paul played a key role.
I mean, he says it himself, he played a key role in the determination
of the interest rate increases that occurred during that period
in the lead-up to the recession.
And Don was very much a part of those conversations with Paul.
So they knew that this was an increasing risk. I've certainly heard that expression that they heard it snap like a,
did you say a neck?
Yeah.
I thought it was a stick.
But anyway, that doesn't matter.
Maybe it does matter.
There's quite a distinction between those two.
Oh, hell, that's a bit gruesome, really.
Yeah. Oh, hell, that's a bit gruesome, really. Yeah, so sitting where I was in the office with primary responsibility
for micro and structural stuff rather than macroeconomic stuff.
I mean, not that I was excluded from the macroeconomic discussions.
It's just that I was not as intimately involved as Don was, Don Russell.
I didn't have that sense, although I certainly had a sense
that the place was at risk of slowing very, very, very sharply.
And, you know, we did have discussions in the office before the event about the macroeconomic policy structure
and the risks that we were taking.
And those were open enough conversations, several advisors with Paul.
You know, Paul, this is getting close.
Like, I mean, you know, this could happen.
Is it wise to keep tightening?
Should we back off a bit, you know?
And it's a metaphor, of course it's a matter of a judgment,
but also when Paul said in that first press conference
that this is a recession Australia had to have,
of course he was pilloried for it,
and of course people thought he was being completely insensitive.
But if you recall that anecdote that I told you right at the start
when he told one of his cabinet colleagues in 1984
who was sweating on decisions that he'd taken,
mate, maybe this is not the place for you,
maybe it's time for you to go.
There is something in the assessments that Paul makes
and the way he communicates them in the moment that can come across
as quite brutal and uncaring, but in respect of both of those,
I would argue that one should look a lot deeper
into what lies behind those comments.
And in the years following, quite a few people came to the view
that Australia would not have achieved the economic restructuring
that it achieved in the absence of a truly deep recession,
as ugly as it was.
And I'm not saying that excuses it, but it nevertheless may well be an accurate analysis that the high productivity growth that Australia enjoyed through the 1990s and the big change or restructuring of the economy that occurred
as we came out of the recession of the 1990s might not otherwise
have happened.
And so I think actually where most economists would sit is they'd say,
it's probably a bit of a cop-out, right? Which is that, well, hang on a second,
you should find other ways of achieving that massive economic restructuring.
You shouldn't have to rely on a recession.
But I think they would also admit that in the absence of that recession,
at that time, we would not have achieved such a rapid restructuring of the economy hmm I
remember reading that you were haunted by one particular statistic that emerged from that
recession and that was that more than something like 50% of men above the age of 45 who lost their jobs, just never returned to work. Never worked again.
Yeah.
Which is crazy.
I mean, not to put too fine a point on it,
but that book I mentioned to you I'd been reading before we started recording,
Wellbeing, Science and Policy,
that Daniel Kahneman recommended to me
at the end of the podcast I did with him.
In the introduction, they mention the importance of employment
and they note that workers who lose their jobs suffer in life satisfaction
on a scale comparable with the death of a spouse.
Yeah.
Yeah.
It was brutal.
It is brutal.
It is brutal. It is brutal. It is brutal.
And, yeah, that's haunted me for a very long time.
And it was certainly playing on my mind during 2008.
Yeah. You know, actually my father is now deceased, and actually died 18 years ago.
But in that period, in the late 1980s, as we were having these discussions in the office, I did say to him,
look, this economy is just going nuts, you know, and it was.
I mean, we were just having this extraordinary boom
in the late 1980s.
Inflation was one consequence of it, but it was only one consequence of it.
The place was going absolutely nuts. And I said, you know, maybe it is the case that the only thing
that's going to stop this is a recession.
Maybe that's unavoidable.
And he said to me, and it stuck with me, particularly
in the months that followed, he said, nothing excuses a recession.
You can't allow yourself to think like that.
My father was not an educated person, right?
I mean, he left school at 13 and was a timber worker almost all his life.
But he had that sense and had obviously seen it of colleagues
of his who had lost their jobs and, you know,
just destroyed their lives, destroyed it.
That was it.
And they lost the capacity, not just the opportunity
to find another job, but they lost the functional capacity
to go and look for another job, but they lost the functional capacity to go and look for another job.
They'd just been so devastated by the experience.
I mean, I don't know if it's like many of those who went to war and were not functional
when they returned from war, but it's something like that, I think, the trauma that people suffer and the loss of, there are just so many elements of loss, aren't
there?
You know, loss of respect or self-respect and, you know, loss of, yeah, certainly loss
of pride in what they're doing
for their families and so on, you know.
Truly devastating.
And I was, and it's actually why, and it's no wonder that Julia Gillard
made a point of it subsequently, but I do remember on the, when was it? It was the second weekend, second Saturday in October 2008,
when those four ministers met with the first serious discussion
about response to the collapse of Lehman Brothers.
Wayne Swan was in Washington, so he joined by phone,
but the other three, Julia Gillard, Lindsay Turner,
and Kevin Rudd were in the Cabinet Room.
And she went straight to that point.
She said, we cannot allow this to happen.
And for that reason, and, you know, it hit me like a punch in the guts
because it was, it had not been up to that point part of my advice to to kevin rod and the and the other ministers and it just hit
me with i'm a huge force and i just thought of course you know this is the lesson that i learned
all those years ago.
It is exactly this and that's all we need to know.
Of course, there's a lot of other things we can know, but all we need to know is that.
In a senior strategy meeting of the Treasury in 2004, Martin Parkinson,
who was sitting beside you, leant over and remarked to you that you and he were the only two
in the room with lived experience of the 1990-91 recession.
And I think you interrupted the meeting to say that, you know,
we need to run some war games.
Yeah, I did.
I mean, we were having a discussion about, I can't remember,
it was, I don't think it was just a macroeconomic policy discussion
and there were about 20 people, oh, 15 to 20 people in the room,
anyway, the most senior level of the department and we were talking.
We used these discussions to discuss policy issues
that were really so significant that they affected
a large part of the department right um and in part it was to deal with the risk of silos that
you get in any organization but it was more than that it was part of um building and maintaining that, a treasury identity.
And, yeah, and it was in that conversation and had been going on for,
I don't know, I can't remember how long, but anyway,
it had been going on for a long period of time, let's say an hour.
And it was at that point that Martin leaned across to me and made that comment.
And again, that struck me with such force that I,
and it had obviously been something that had been worrying me,
I assume subconsciously, because I just immediately
stopped the meeting.
I said, stop, stop, stop.
Stop.
We're going to have a different sort of discussion about these issues.
And I said, you know, I think we need to war game some scenarios that's what we need to do
we just need to do that and i said you know martin has just mentioned to me just made the observation
um about the depth of um uh experience in the in the department in dealing with recessions.
And let's hope we never have another one,
but we of all people should ensure that where the people
of the government turns to for advice, if and when we find ourselves
in that sort of position.
And the reason I put it that way is that one of the other memories that I carried with
me from the recession of the early 1990s is that when the recession was confirmed,
I mean the fact that we were in one, the advice that came
from Treasury was there's no case for a large fiscal stimulus
and that instead, of course, monetary policy should be eased,
of course, and that should happen immediately.
But as far as the budget is concerned, you should rely upon the operation
of the automatic fiscal stabilisers, right, which just...
Actually, you know, having...
Reflecting on it and having gone through the, about that recession and then the response to the global financial crisis and then having left the department, of course, and observed from some distance the government's response to the pandemic, I actually find that automatic stabiliser narrative quite stupid,
quite stupid for the reason that the way the automatic stabilisers work
and what people mean by that is that when the economy goes
into recession, the economy goes into recession the budget goes
into deficit well like the reason it goes into deficit is because people lose their jobs and
tax revenue plummets and because people lose their jobs there are more people on the unemployment
benefit so spending goes up and revenue plummets that's a consequence of recession.
That doesn't bring the economy out of recession.
It's just a consequence of recession.
So you now got unemployed people.
How does that provide any sort of fiscal stimulus to get people back into work?
So it doesn't.
It's just stupid.
And so the whole proposition, and look, I'm probably doing a deep injustice to the, because I was in Keating's office at the time, right?
I'm probably doing a deep injustice to those who were involved in framing the advice within Treasury at the time on what the government should do to respond to that recession of the early 1990s.
And at the time, I didn't think it was stupid, right?
I just think it's stupid now, having had the opportunity to think more about it.
So anyway, Treasury more or less said sit on your hands,
except in the monetary policy area.
Well, of course, government can't sit on its hands
through a recession, nor should it.
And so what happened was the government, and Keating's now Prime Minister,
of course, rather than Treasurer, the government finds alternative
sources of advice, and those are in other government departments, largely.
And then, and so the Treasury finds itself sidelined in the process that's developing a policy response to a recession.
Well, that's completely absurd, right?
Completely absurd.
It's perverse.
And so I said to the group, you know, we have to make absolutely sure, we have to make sure that if the country ever finds itself in those
circumstances again, that it's the Treasury sitting on the other side of the table from
the Prime Minister, not some other agency that doesn't have our responsibility, doesn't have our
training, doesn't have our understanding, can't possibly have prepared as well as we should have prepared
for this sort of eventuality.
And more to the point, what use are we if we're not at that table?
So that's why we started Wargaming.
What does a Wargame actually look like in the treasury context?
Like what's the output?
Is it a model?
It's model-driven.? It's model-driven.
Yeah.
So it's model-driven.
Yeah, yeah, yeah.
So you run, so you have various macroeconomic models
and you run various scenarios through those macroeconomic models
that allow you to look at, well, firstly,
to develop a benchmark scenario, right?
So just imagine that a component of aggregate demand
were to fall by this much.
How many people would lose their jobs?
Tell us a bit about where those people are.
What sort of people are they?
What would happen? What would the monetary policy response be or likely to be?
So what would happen to interest rates?
What would happen to the exchange rate?
Because that's also a possible stabiliser that can be helpful, right, in immediately
adding the impact of that exogenous loss of aggregate demand in some place.
And then consider various policy responses.
So what sort of fiscal response would be required
to address that sort of demand shock,
to compensate for it, if you like?
And then, and you can do that all model-based.
So that's just model-based, right?
You can run various simulations and scenarios
through that discussion.
And then you get to the really meaty part of it, which is, well,
now let's think about the timeliness of the intervention, right?
So one of the, I mean, even when I was, well, certainly when I was,
by the time I was an undergraduate student of economics,
I learned that one of the problems with using fiscal policy
as a macroeconomic instrument is that there are all sorts
of lags involved in its use.
I mean, there's obviously the recognition lag,
but that bedevils monetary policy as well.
So we didn't know that the economy was in recession
until well after the event, right, because of the lag
in the collection of national accounts and publication
of national accounts.
And you can look at indicators, but you don't really know
until that national accounts figure comes out.
So you've inevitably got the recognition lag,
and then you've got the lag involved in developing a policy response,
and then you've got the lag involved in implementation,
like rolling that response out in some way.
And that led us to having conversations about the fastest track means
of contributing to aggregate demand.
And all of our war games, all of our war gaming told us that you've got
to get cash in the hands of households.
And there are ways that allow you to do that quite quickly.
And we had explored a number of those ways in that war game,
in that war gaming exercise, which is why, you know, which is why when it happened
in 2008, our focus was on very much on getting cash
into the hands of households.
War gaming has to be done in secrecy.
Indeed.
You could say.
Yeah.
I'm taking this to an interesting conclusion.
And indeed, a lot of an economic policy department's thinking
has to be done secretly.
Yeah.
Because obviously you don't want to unnecessarily,
negatively influence the public's perception of the economy.
Does that imply that it is impossible for the public
to ever fully appreciate counterfactuals?
Well, no.
So, well, I think there's a time dimension to that question,
I think, that's, well, maybe you don't want to go there,
but maybe this is me seeking to squeeze out of a tricky spot.
But, you know, once the decision's been taken, of course,
it falls to the political leaders to communicate that to the public
and the reasons for it and to, as part of the narrative, construct the counterfactual.
But even then, I mean, this is really, really,
really tricky stuff, right?
You know, when we decided when, sorry, when on our advice,
the Rudd government decided on that first fiscal stimulus package
in October of 2008, which was delivered before,
well, most of it was delivered before Christmas of 2008.
There were any number of critics who were lining up,
accusing the government of
firstly being spooked and not knowing what they were doing which was just a cheap political shot
secondly of unnecessarily alarming people about the circumstances that we're in after all
the abs had not said, guess what?
We've had a recession, right?
So that action was all about forestalling a recession,
dealing with that risk in advance.
And so there was no counterfactual there that anybody else had constructed.
So the government had to construct it.
And the problem is if it constructs the counterfactual,
it falls into the trap that you've referred to where it can stand accused of having made things worse.
And it was certainly accused of that by the opposition, the political opposition, and by a number of newspapers.
So that is really difficult, right?
But how else does a government explain the seriousness of the issue
and why it has to take such exceptionally,
or such exceptional steps, you know?
There is no way, I just can't see any way of avoiding it.
And so you need a really, really powerful narrative
to be able to carry that one.
It would be the same, though, in a national security context.
It's why, presumably, although, oh, no, I was about to say I wasn't part
of these discussions, but actually I was because I used to sit
on the Secretary's Committee on National Security, among other things.
But, you know, that fridge magnet that said be alert but not alarmed.
Yeah.
Well, that's exactly the point.
It's trying to walk that very fine line that you're getting to, right? That you're getting at. And it's exactly the same in trying to forestall an economic crisis. thinking about non-linearities and exponential growth
as a result of events like the financial crisis and COVID?
I think, okay, so I'm not sure.
I think they have got more understanding of the need
for governments to do exceptional things in exceptional circumstances.
I would say that.
And to act preemptively.
And to act preemptively. And to act preemptively.
Yeah, absolutely.
Yeah.
That much, yes.
But that's when you're talking about a real crisis.
What about if you're talking about a slower moving undermining
of national capacity or national capability, for example?
That is an interesting question.
I just, I don't think so.
It used to be said that, and I think it was probably the OECD
that described Australia in these circumstances way back in the,
it could even have been in the 1970s, maybe it was the 1980s,
that Australia is, and these are not the exact words, of course,
but Australia has demonstrated a great capacity to deal
with crises in the moment and after the moment,
but has not demonstrated the same ability
to deal with things before they become a crisis.
You know, that kind of slow-moving build-up of imbalances
or, you know, whatever the hell, you know.
And so there are quite a number of those that you can see playing
out in Australia or have been playing out in Australia
for some decades.
So, for example, the impact of climate change, the impact.
I mean, at some stage, well, I guess, I mean,
in respect of some of the consequences
of climate change, like the increasing incidence
and severity of bushfires and floods and droughts,
I think people are getting it.
But in the early 1990s, when some politicians were trying to have this or run this narrative and engage the public, they were getting no traction at all.
So that, I think there so far as to say that the real heroic virtues are actually best demonstrated by solving those slow-moving train wrecks.
I agree with that.
Not by working on the kind of sudden crisis.
Yeah.
Yeah. Yeah, and of course, as others in conversation with you,
I'm sure would have noted, you know, this extraordinary ability
of humans to discount probable future events because they're future,
you know, or they're out there.
Hyperbolic discounting.
Hyperbolic discounting, exactly. Right?
Yeah.
It's a nice way of putting it.
That's exactly it.
And that makes the task of such leaders damn near impossible.
Yeah.
Yeah.
I'm struck.
Actually, no. Sorry. I'm struck.
Actually, no.
Sorry, let me ask one question about Kevin Rudd and then I want to move on to this topic of reform and leadership.
So, on the morning of the 29th of February 2008,
must have been a leap year.
Yeah.
You get a call to tell you that the PM is expecting you to be on an aircraft at Gladstone for a chat in the air. Yeah. You get a call to tell you that the PM is expecting you to be on an aircraft
at Gladstone.
Yeah.
For a chat in the air.
Yeah.
And on the flight, Kevin asked you what happens to the Australian
current account.
It's not how he framed the question.
No.
Okay.
It was, no.
No, it took me a while to figure out what the hell he was talking about.
No, the way he framed the question was this.
Look, the plane had just taken off.
Yeah.
We'd levelled out.
In fact, I think we'd been served a cup of tea,
and Wayne Swan was on the plane as well.
And there was one other, I just, it's my fault,
I just can't remember who it was.
It wasn't a minister, it was an advisor.
And I was sitting opposite Kevin.
And so a cup of tea, sir.
And he leans across the table and he literally said,
what is the worst thing that can happen?
Those are his exact words.
What is the worst thing that can happen?
There was no introduction.
There was no context, right?
For a brief moment, I thought, well, I guess we could fall out of the sky,
you know?
I mean, I just had no context at all.
And it wasn't until a long time later that he told me what the context
of it was, which was that he'd not been able to sleep the night previous.
He hadn't got any sleep at all.
And he was, the question he was asking himself was,
with what's going on in the global financial system,
how might this play out in Australia?
And we've been sending him briefing of the sort that you're going to see,
given the earlier past this conversation,
you're going to see how absurd this is.
But we had sent him briefing of the sort that said, well,
Australia's got one of the best regulated financial systems
in the world.
Bank balance sheets are extraordinary, you know.
We just don't see a high risk to the assets sitting
on bank balance sheets.
There are no strong connections between Australian banks
and foreign institutions that might run into trouble.
As far as we can tell, you know, the banks have not been big investors
in these collateralised debt instruments and so on,
which have been a feature of other jurisdictions.
Exposure to the housing market, well, of course it's there,
but we don't think the circumstances exist in Australia to produce a housing price crash.
And, you know, the banks have been stress tested by APRA
on multiple occasions and blah, blah, blah, blah, blah.
And we were not briefing the government on the exposure
that the banks had on the liability side of their balance sheet,
which is what we were talking about earlier,
their dependence upon these international capital markets
for funding.
And so, and I don't know if that was what was in the Prime Minister's mind,
Kevin's mind at the time either, but he was deeply troubled
that there must be some exposure that we have
to the global financial system that we're overlooking.
There must be.
But that's not how he asked the question.
He asked the question, what's the worst thing that could possibly happen?
And what he, so he obviously just assumed that this same question was sitting
in my head and he wanted to know the worst thing and then we were going
to come back from that.
Okay, that's the worst thing that can happen.
How would we respond to that?
Let's backtrack from that to something that's more likely to happen
and how would we respond to that?
And then what should we be putting in place now to help us deal
with that in the event that we find ourselves in that position.
But once I realised that he was talking about Australia's exposure
to the international financial system, I said to him the worst thing
that can happen, well, among the worst things that can happen is that the rest of the world stops funding
our current account.
That's what I said.
And more than that, I mean, the really worst thing that can happen
beyond that is that they stop buying Australian government debt.
That's about as bad as it would get, I think.
And when we went through possible responses to that,
just what you might have to do, and he and I have agreed
that I'll never talk publicly about some of the things
that we discussed on that plane, so I won't do it here. But and then we step back from the absolute worst thing
that could happen.
So that's a place where you do actually have willing purchases
of Australian government securities.
So people out there all over the world who are lining up to buy treasury bonds.
And so then we had a discussion about what the government
might have to do in those circumstances.
And we did discuss things like possibly having
to guarantee bank liabilities.
I don't recall what sort of discussion we had
about a fiscal injection, you know, actually government
spending more money, but that must have been
in the conversation somewhere, given what happened subsequently.
It must have been, yeah.
My question is why was he, I mean,
he didn't really have like a specialised economics background.
No, no, no.
He used to tell me all the time.
He used to say, I don't know anything about economics.
I'm a student of Chinese poetry.
So why was he so far along in his thinking?
Was he just getting like really good briefings from some other agency like DPMC?
No, no, no.
Was it like a temperamental edge that he had?
Temperamental.
Is that the right word?
I think you're on the right word there, but it's just...
He was...
You know, he was out in front of any other leader of any country,
anywhere in the world, in asking that question.
I'm sure he was.
So it was the way that he was interpreting the briefings
that he was getting about what was going on in international meetings
and so on, and, of course, he had attended a couple
where these things, fragilities in the international financial architecture,
were being discussed.
I mean, pretty abstract stuff, really. But his interpretation of it was, oh, hell, you know,
this could get really, really, really ugly.
And it's in the nature of him that he has such a – he is so keen on detail and ensuring
that every base is covered that that's what he wanted to do.
He wanted to get on top of it, on top of every contingency
because it's impossible, but that's what he wanted to do.
And he certainly and understandably wanted some level of confidence
that there were people in the public service who had some understanding
of these contingencies and would be in a position to be able
to provide him with advice on what he should do at the moment
and in the moment.
So, but, you know, so, I mean, an uncharitable way
of describing his personality is that he's a control freak.
But you know what, in a crisis, that's probably exactly what you need,
is a control freak.
Yeah.
And maybe that is exactly the behaviours that he was demonstrating
through 2008, well before the collapse of Lehman Brothers.
Maybe it is.
Well, good on him.
It's a good thing for Australia that he did.
That's my view.
So moving to the bigger picture and reform.
There's a bigger picture.
There's an even bigger picture.
I'm struck by the irony that you seem to have had a better experience
of reform under a conservative government
than a progressive government.
You're struck by that too. So to make this clear, Howard put you in charge
of the GST task force in 1997, spent about a year working on that.
The government goes to an election to get a mandate.
Then there's a couple of years to implement it.
The government even nearly gets rolled at that election in 1998.
Yeah, lost the popular vote.
Lost the popular vote and just got re-elected on the basis
of kind of the distribution of votes in some marginal seats.
Yeah.
And then the negotiation of the bill through the parliament is fraught.
Brian Harradine famously rejects it in the Senate in May 1999
with those words, I cannot.
In good conscience, was it?
Yeah, in good conscience.
In good conscience.
Yeah, support this tax or something like that.
Yeah.
And then Howard negotiates with the Australian Democrats.
He invites Meg Lees into the cabinet room in Melbourne.
And so, this really difficult, complicated, potentially
unpopular tax reform gets up under a conservative government and you're working closely with them helping to design
and implement that.
Yeah.
On the other hand, fast forward to the Henry Tax Review
and you come up with a whole bunch of things that are actually
intuitively popular, like the Resource Superprofits Tax, which, I mean, it's difficult to recall
a poll that was against what was colloquially called the mining tax.
Yeah.
And that just crashed and burned. And on top of that, the vast bulk of the 138 recommendations
weren't adopted by the Rudd government.
So I want to get your reflection looking back on those two experiences.
What has changed in the Australian polity to make reform more difficult?
Or was the example of mismanaged reform under Labor more
just an example of mistakes and bad management?
So it could be those two things and there's a third.
I'll come back to those two things.
The third, though, is that, and it's very important,
is that the GST package was the implementation commencing
on 1 July 2000 of the core recommendation of a tax review
that was published in 1975.
The Asprey Review.
Yeah, and it had been commissioned a few years before.
And there had been a number of attempts to implement
that core recommendation.
So Keating's 1985 tax summit package, that was a notable attempt
to try to implement that core recommendation
of the ASPRI review.
Option C.
Yeah.
And in fact, that was option C. Actually, I think we called it approach C, but never
mind.
It's remembered as option C.
Option C is pretty much ASPRI, ASPRY, ASPRY.
That's pretty much what it is with income tax base broadening, things like fringe benefits
tax, capital gains tax, and so on.
And then personal income tax cuts overall, reform of the indirect tax system, and a broad
base consumption tax, pretty much, you know, which is pretty much what Asprey recommended.
So 10 years later, that failed in spectacular fashion.
Didn't get the support of anybody.
I mean, absolutely anybody apart from Keating and the Treasury.
And then you have John Hewson in 1993 with his fightback package
developed in opposition, which, and by the way,
a very high-quality document, well argued.
It was confronting.
It was challenging.
It was really, really ambitious.
But nevertheless, it was, and particularly for a document created in opposition, an outstanding
piece of work. And of course, on this occasion, I was in the department providing briefing
for actually John Keran was a treasurer at the time
that that was launched, as I recall.
I think I've got that right.
It must have been in 1992 that, yeah, of course,
it was 1992 that it was released.
Was it?
It must have been.
Or maybe it was 91.
No, Keran was treasurer.
It must have been the second half of 91.
It must have been released in 91.
It was.
And so preparing that briefing for Treasurer Keren in a role that put me,
well, people chose to put me or decided that I was then on the other side of the argument, which I certainly wasn't,
but I was nevertheless providing the briefing on the package
as it was presented.
And, you know, that fight back attempt failed
and that was probably a more surprising,
well, that was certainly a more surprising failure
than the one that Keating had suffered in 1995,
you know, very surprising failure.
And you would have thought, and everybody did think,
well, that's it, that's the end of it, never going to happen again.
And that's what Howard said in the 1996 election campaign, right,
there will never, ever be a GST.
So 25 years, I mean mean i think that's something and i don't think
we should and several failed attempts so i don't think we should ignore that having said that
i'm not going to say to you that um so the point there is that well reform's always been difficult
and takes a long time and takes a long time. And takes a long time. Yeah. Yeah.
But having said that, I'm not going to say to you that I'm very confident that in 15 years' time we'll have a resource of super profits
taxed in Australia, right?
It takes more than that.
So there is something about the other, in the other two things
that you mentioned.
And one of them, in fact, maybe both of them go back
to the ability of the proponents to construct a narrative
that is sufficiently compelling to build,
not just to build public support because, as you said,
the polls suggested that the resources super profits tax
had public support, right?
But it is to...
I have thought about this a lot.
It's to give your...
If you're the Treasurer or Prime Minister running the argument,
it's to give your parliamentary colleagues confidence
that you're going to win it, you're going to win the argument.
Also to give them a narrative that they can use
in their own electorates too.
And that is more than being able to point to public opinion polls, which show that overall the public is in favour.
I think the reform ambition of governments, it certainly relies on the leadership and the qualities
of leadership that we've spoken about, but the fuel for it,
on which it absolutely depends, is the more or less
unquestioning support of the parliamentary colleagues
of the leader, you know.
And that's what wasn't there.
It wasn't there in 1985, and that was a Labor government,
and it wasn't there again when the tax review was launched in 2010.
There was was insufficient confidence
in the Parliamentary Labor Party that they were going
to be able to get this done.
Now, people will debate for a long, long time whether
that was a fair assessment being made by those people or not, but I'm sure that's why the jockeying for the moves
against Kevin Rudd as Prime Minister started.
Is the lack of confidence and the inability to craft a narrative
endogenous to the good times?
So I guess here I've kind of got you.
You know those cyclical theories like tough times create hard men and women,
good times create soft men and women.
Is there something like that going on?
Does good policy leadership require like a wolf at the door to motivate it?
Or were we just unlucky with the political leaders we had
during those periods?
I think it would be a bit unfair to say we were unlucky.
I guess with respect to those specific policies.
Yeah, because, oh, with respect to those specific policies.
Okay.
So I used to think about this a hell of a lot, particularly when I was speaking
publicly on economic challenges confronting the nation. When you think about the intergenerational
reports, it's called,
and the first of those was published in 2002.
So these are reports, and Treasury publishes them,
and these are reports that produce 40-year projections
of government spending, right?
And they used to just assume, and certainly in 2002 report,
just assumed that tax revenue would remain constant
as a proportion of those domestic products.
Just a technical assumption.
Let's not worry about the tax side of the budget.
And let's focus on the spending side of the budget.
And I briefed the Howard cabinet on that report well in advance
of being published and drew out what I saw as being
the central components of a policy reform narrative
that could be built on those projections.
And there was a lot of interest around the table, a lot of interest.
And in the subsequent period, Peter Costello, as treasurer, gave a lot of speeches, a lot
that were based on that narrative. And I did too. We both did. And it was kind of a double act,
right? And he would address some audiences and I would address other audiences, right?
And that's exactly what we were trying to do was to build a platform
or more an environment, actually more an environment
in which one could have a serious conversation about emerging reform needs
and then motivate the reforms that would be required.
Because you're not in a crisis period
and the narrative is based on 40-year projections,
you can test things.
And because as a politician your political window is three years at most, right, you don't actually have to expose yourself to the verdict of the electorate.
So with that, you can be a little more comfortable about the ideas that you're expressing. the evidence is though that no matter how daunting those distant challenges are presented as being because of what you referred to earlier as hyperbolic discounting and maybe for other
reasons the narrative has no impact it just doesn't grab people they just um oh well we
don't have to worry about that. We're worried about tomorrow,
thank you very much. And with good reason. Most people are, and with good reason.
Let's not worry about that. And I used to finish, almost every speech I gave on this,
I would finish with the words like, we don't have to, like, we've got to do a lot of things. We
don't have to do them immediately, but we will have to do them.
Well, we still haven't done any of them.
And we're 20 years in, right?
That was 2002.
We're 20 years in.
And by the way, the projections that we published in 2002,
although they were 40-year projections, we had decadal projections.
So we had projections for the first decade, second decade,
third and fourth. If you compare had projections for the first decade, second decade, third and fourth.
If you compare those projections for the first two decades
against lived experience, against what's actually happened,
they're pretty damn good, i.e. the disaster that we had outlined
is occurring.
It's a slow-moving disaster, right?
And surely people have been aware that the disaster is occurring. It's a slow-moving disaster, right? And surely people have been aware that the disaster is emerging.
I mean, surely they're aware of Australia's atrocious performance
in productivity growth, for example, atrocious performance
in growth in gross domestic product per capita,
all of those measures that matter to utilitarians, right?
Surely they're aware of all that stuff and they're just allowing
it to happen.
And moreover, no politician, no political leader has pointed
to those things and said, oh, my God, this stuff that Costello
was talking about 20 years ago, we've actually done nothing
about it and look where we've actually done nothing about it,
and look where we are, it's about time we did something.
That's kind of deeply troubling, right? So I think it is possible to develop the narrative,
but I'm not at all confident that you can get traction,
traction sufficient to motivate action.
And is this like a problem that's unique to this period?
Is this something that... No, I don't think it is, no.
It's not.
Interesting.
No, I don't think it is.
Interesting.
And I think that's exactly the frustration that Keating was venting,
expressing anyway, in his 1986 Banana Republic statement.
It's exactly that.
We've got this slow-moving disaster.
It's not going to hit us tomorrow.
But if we don't do something pretty dramatic,
it is going to hit us in some years hence.
And so he, and I don't think he thought, well,
I have spoken to him about this.
He was just expressing frustration.
But, of course, what he was doing was constructing a burning platform.
Yeah.
That's what he was doing.
He was making the counterfactual.
Yeah, yeah, making it real.
Yeah.
And I really, you know, I've thought a lot about how one might
construct narratives to motivate change.
And when it comes to major policy change, at least economic policy change
and certainly tax policy change, nothing short of a burning platform
will work.
You've really got to convince people that we're all going to hell
or somewhere worse.
Oh, well, let's assume there's nowhere worse.
We're all going to hell unless we do something
and do it pretty damn quickly.
So, Ken, should I think of you as standing in contrast
to thinkers like Mansa Olson,
the public choice economist who wrote that book,
The Rise and Decline of Nations, or more parochially like a Ross Garner
who thinks that there are all these like almost like secular factors
that now make reform more difficult.
Should I think of you in contrast to those kind of theorists? No, I don't think so. I mean, I think those factors have made reform more difficult. Should I think of you in contrast to those kind of theorists?
No, I don't think so.
I mean, I think those factors have made it more difficult.
I'm just saying, I think what I'm saying and where you'd be able
to find accommodation between my views and theirs is
that I don't think it was ever easy.
And I don't think we were ever very good at it, honestly.
I don't think we were ever very good at it, honestly. I don't.
I think there were circumstances that were largely,
I mean the circumstances were bad but it took somebody like Akitin to construct the burning platform
to motivate action, right?
That's with respect to the big things,
some of the big things that were done. With respect to things like on the currency,
which officials and governments have been wrestling
with for a very long time before those decisions
were taken in 1983.
But, of course, the other thing is that other countries
from all around the world, most actually, I think,
I could be wrong on this, but my sense is that most,
certainly leading IMF members would have floated their currencies
before Australia did.
So it was kind of a, why are we not doing this?
It doesn't tell you very much about Australia's preparedness
for economic reform, I don't think.
I don't think I'm doing that an injustice.
It's really in motivating public appetite for the difficult things
like bringing the budget deficit back under control
that you've got to construct that burning platform. like bringing the budget deficit back under control,
that you've got to construct that burning platform.
And that's what Keating did.
And the only other times we've had it is when it couldn't be ignored,
when we were actually in the middle, have been in the middle of a crisis,
whether it's a global financial crisis or the pandemic or whatever if there's a problem with democracy that that implies like a bigger problem for capitalism right yeah because two sides of a coin yeah yeah like milton friedman's argument
that the only social responsibility of a business is to maximize profit for shareholders
was predicated in part on the idea that governments could internalise externalities.
Absolutely.
I mean, more than in part.
More than in part.
I mean, it's very...
Well, I guess the other part I'm contemplating is that individuals
can internalise externalities as well.
Yeah, so, yeah.
Well, let's talk about that.
So, Friedman's perspective, as I read capitalism and freedom,
is that, I mean, it's funny.
So when I read capitalism and freedom, what I get from it
is a perspective that says without functional democracy and governments
playing their role in the public, i.e. the citizens who elect them,
ensuring the governments play the appropriate role with respect to,
and Friedman points to, free and open competition and absence of fraud or deception, right?
In those things in particular, he would say,
and he does say in Capitalism and Freedom that, well,
it's not going to work.
But in saying that, he sets up an adversarial system, right,
where the rest of us, and that's the expression he uses, the rest of us, as citizens in a democracy, we necessarily find ourselves in an adversarial position with respect to business. provided businesses seek to maximise profit and government does its bit to ensure that as consumers
and workers and so on, we're not dudded
by their profit-maximising activities.
What do you know?
That's fine.
Formally, in neoclassical economics,
the expression is that the outcome is Pareto optimal.
Now, there are, in the sense that nobody can be made better off
without somebody else being made worse off, right? And it satisfies all the utilitarians.
But there are other issues, and he canvases these other issues in Capitalism and Freedom, where
he refers to the possibility of neighbourhood effects, which today we call externalities. And I mean, everybody's aware of the really big one,
which is climate change, which is clearly a negative externality of the operation of markets
and businesses seeking to maximise profits and being allowed to do so without taking account of
the damage that they're doing to the climate and to the environment and now to people's lives as a consequence
of those commercial activities.
But there are many other negative externalities
that are a consequence of profit maximisation,
and he admits that, more than admits, he sets out the way
that one should think about the role of government
in dealing with those externalities,
and he refers to essentially a balance sheet approach
or maybe a profit and loss approach.
Anyway, what we these days have termed something
like a cost-benefit analysis of government intervention
because one should recognise that if governments seek
to intervene to address a negative externality
and they're successful, they do some good,
but they could also be doing some harm as well,
associated with the regulatory imposition, blah, blah, blah.
You know, that.
And he also talks about the other case for government,
the other big case for government involvement,
which is in the provision of public goods.
But from memory, and it's a while since I've read it,
but from memory, and it's a while since I've read it, but from memory,
aside from defence, he's pretty reluctant to endorse a case
for governments getting very much involved in the delivery
of public goods.
I remember being absolutely shocked when I read that he could see
no case for governments funding national parks.
And the reason I find that one shocking is that I understand the argument that the beneficiaries,
those who derive benefit from national parks are those who visit them.
So rather than national parks being funded by the general body of taxpayers, they should
be funded by those who get to enjoy the national parks,
i.e. those who visit them.
The problem is that many of those, and even if you are utilitarian on this,
many of those that you would hope get to visit national parks
are not even born yet, far less of a voting age,
and they're not capable
of expressing the value that they attach to a national park
by paying park entrance fees.
And so there's a complete ignorance in his writings
of the important role the government has in preserving things
for the enjoyment of future generations.
And that, I think, is a significant weakness.
But the other thing that's ironic is that it's not until,
I think it's not until,
I think it's in the foreword of the 40th edition because he kept revising that book.
I think I read an interview with him at some stage
where he said it's the most difficult thing he ever wrote,
which I think is why he continued to revise it.
But I think he says in the foreword of the 40th edition
that he, on reflection,
wishes that he had paid more attention to the way
that governments might discharge their responsibilities.
I think he was thinking more of the contest between authoritarianism
and democracy.
But I think, and I don't know if he had this in mind,
but my perspective on it would be that he should have spent more time
thinking about how capitalism operates
when government is incapable, for whatever reason,
of discharging its responsibilities, right?
So what happens when government is dysfunctional, for whatever reason is incapable of ensuring
that business does operate in a way such that profit maximisation
does actually lead to a utilitarian utopia.
Two questions.
If government is dysfunctional for secular reasons,
does that imply that companies and other organisations
are actually the real vehicles for social change?
So all else being equal, today, should ambitious young people think less
about the political arena and the public service and more
about the startup world?
So this is a good question.
All your questions have been good.
So I don't know about the startup world.
Like I wouldn't focus on that particularly,
but I found myself having to, I didn't have to,
but I chose to talk about these issues in an address
I gave recently to a bunch of graduating students at the ANU.
And I made the point that this somewhat dystopian perspective that I have, that government has essentially become dysfunctional, opens up enormous opportunity for people who understand how the system operates and who understand what it might take to achieve better social outcomes,
including environmental outcomes.
And the point I made was that, like at an instrumental level,
the point I made was that there is a role for smart people
in achieving things that governments, for whatever reason,
have demonstrated an incapacity to achieve.
And what's at play here is that even if the vast majority of people don't understand
the reasons for the bad things that they observe going on around them,
they know that there's something wrong, right?
And they are inclined to the view that business is at the heart of it.
And why not?
After all, it's businesses that actually take the decisions
that affect most people's lives, right?
Businesses in one form or another who decide what gets produced,
at what price, who gets a job, where the job is located,
how much they get paid, what inputs are used in the production of whatever it is
that they're producing, whether it's a good or a service,
where those things are sourced from, what environmental damage
is tolerated in the production of those things,
what social harm is done by people consuming the products
that they produce,
all that kind of stuff.
It's actually businesses doing it, right?
And I think people understand that,
and I think they see businesses being, therefore,
the source of the problem.
So as a policy-trained economist, I see government failure there.
I think most people see business failure.
Well, in that, there is enormous opportunity, right?
So there is more interest now in people understanding the consequences
of business activity.
And so there's a lot of support now for enhanced disclosure regimes.
So take, for instance, the Taskforce on Climate-Related Financial Disclosure that is voluntary, and yet,
although it's voluntary, I know the new Environment Minister
has signalled, or maybe it was Chris Bowen, has signalled that one day
these disclosures are going to be mandated
for large public-listed companies, but nevertheless they're voluntary.
But most large public-listed companies are making these disclosures now.
Now, they're only making scope one and possibly scope two disclosures,
not full scope three disclosures of carbon emissions
associated with their activities.
But they're nevertheless moving in that direction, right?
And why?
The reason they're moving in that direction is because they understand
that increasingly the expectation that investors have,
so shareholders have, is that they will take some responsibility
or some accountability is probably a better word,
some accountability for what they're doing
and seek to avoid those negative impacts.
Workers don't want to work for such companies.
So if you're in the market for labour, as you are,
as every business is, and that's an
increasingly difficult market, you're going to find it increasingly difficult to attract people
who want to work for you. You're going to find banks increasingly reluctant to lend to you
because of the reputational risk, but also the credit risk associated with those lending decisions.
And you're going to find customers saying, I don't want to buy your product.
Bugger off.
You know, I'll source product.
I'll satisfy my wants and my needs from other businesses that I just like the look of, right?
I don't like the look of you.
So the way to think about that in economics 101 terms
is that it's actually those economic agents, so investors, credit providers, lenders, workers and consumers who are effectively imposing an externality tax on their business, on business generally.
You can avoid this externality tax by changing your behaviour.
You don't change your behaviour, you're going to have
to pay higher wages to attract people.
You won't be able to charge such high prices
to attract consumers.
You're going to pay higher interest rates and you're going
to have to be capable of paying higher dividends
to attract investor support and that's probably going
to dwindle and dry up anyway. So it's effectively disenchantment on the part of the public
or members of the public generally in attributing the source
of the problems to the activities of business, and understandably so,
that is, I think, leading to an implicit
externality tax being imposed on businesses.
And that is going to change behaviour.
And what I was saying to this group of graduates at the ANU is
there's enormous opportunity there.
You think about everything that's going to be required
to put that system in place, the information requirements,
the data requirements, for a start, people who are capable
of sitting inside businesses and guiding them on how they should respond
to this implicit externality tax in its various forms
and what they need to do, massive change coming, I reckon,
and it's going to go well beyond climate.
It's going to go to the next cab off the rank is the Task Force
on Nature-Related Financial Disclosure.
That too will be voluntary, at least initially,
and maybe for a very long time, but I nevertheless expect
to see Australian businesses responding to that that and responding quickly and maybe even seeking
to be at the forefront globally in responses.
Anyway, I certainly hope that that's the case.
And you've also got other governments in other parts
of the world that are not as timid as ours that are, yeah, not as timid as ours,
I think that's right, that are taking decisions.
Maybe they're protectionist, but of the sort, well,
we're not going to allow our consumers to source product
from countries like Australia that have such a poor record with respect to carbon emissions
or have such a poor record with respect to species extinction
and so on, right?
And that is driving change behaviour as well.
And I think it's going to be an increasingly potent force.
Were you working on anything around the social responsibility of companies before you left NAB?
Yeah.
Yeah, yeah, sure.
I mean, it's kind of we were having a lot of conversations internally
about this topic and, in fact, we had turned out to be quite
an expensive exercise on the whole question of social purpose
and we developed through a long process and involving a lot of people in the organisation,
certainly all of the board and all of the senior management,
but it went well down into the organisation
of developing a purpose statement for NAB.
Yeah, we had a lot of conversations about it, and that included the stance that NAB should take
with respect to its regulatory obligations.
And it's kind of ironic that, you know, we were probably more,
I would say that NAB was more advanced
on these discussions than any of the other banks.
In fact, I'm sure that's true and had made substantial progress.
But, of course, NAB had the wealth business, the MLC business,
which it had acquired in 2000. And it had recently restructured or changed the business model
in advance of everybody else in moving from a trailing commission model
to a fee-for-service model.
And it was still in the process of being bedded down,
and I would have to say,
with huge problems, I mean massive problems.
And we were aware of those problems and were engaging
with the regulators on those problems.
But that was just at the time that, you know,
the legitimate angst in the public was escalating
and we found ourselves in a royal commission.
Interestingly, that royal commission had the opportunity,
because it was certainly within its terms of reference, to consider these issues.
In round seven, I think it was, I was called as a – and it's funny how you get these invitations, because the invitation is to appear before the Royal topics of corporate accountability,
governance and culture.
That's sort of exactly what we've just been talking about in this interview.
So they're big policy questions and I didn't get any questioning
on these topics at all.
And that's because I think it's just the structure,
the way the Royal Commission had been established
and the way it was doing its work, and I'm not being critical
in saying this, but it was operating more as a criminal court, the way a criminal court operates.
And it was good theatre.
And I'm not in any way wanting to diminish the seriousness
of the issues that were under consideration
because they were certainly serious, no question about that.
But what it failed to do is it failed to grapple
with any of the policy issues.
And that's a problem.
And in fact, the big policy issues, the core policy issues that were at issue in respect
of the financial advice part of NAB, the MLC part, which is what I got all the questioning
about, they're still unresolved.
And in fact, the newspapers, even this week,
have been full of commentary about whether the Labor government
will act on a subsequent review of those parts of the law
that the Hayne Royal Commission had failed to address.
It's still ongoing.
Who knows when these issues will ever be resolved, right?
But, yeah, it's a bit of a shame.
But, yeah, we were certainly working on these issues in NAB
in the time that I was there, and I don't know what's happened to that work since.
When you left Treasury in 2011, some coalition MPs had been openly attacking you
since about 2008.
Yeah.
And you'll remember in the 2010 election, as part of the negotiations with the crossbench,
Oakeshott and Windsor extracted the red book and the blue book.
And then the Treasury advice about Abbott's policy program
being quite scathing and that leaked and Abbott was filthy
and was no doubt prepared to be vindictive
as he eventually was when he took government.
Yeah.
That was years later though.
Years later.
Yeah.
I guess I'm curious, like, what part of your motivation
in leaving in 2011 was to protect the broader institution
of the Treasury from political attacks?
Well, it was certainly playing on my mind.
It, but it's, I thought a lot about this.
Well, I thought a lot about it in the moment.
Look, in the 2010 election, this is probably not known.
I'm sure nobody has written this, but I don't think there's any reason
why I shouldn't disclose it.
I don't think I was in any confidential discussion, but in that period following the election
when the discussions were going on with the crossbenchers
and both potential governments were involved in those discussions,
I was sitting in my office, I got an invitation
to go across to Parliament House and meet with the Liberal leader
and the Deputy Liberal leader, which I willingly agreed to do,
of course, even though they'd been bagging me for years,
or at least the party had.
And so I met with Tony Abbott and Julie Bishop.
The only other person in the room was Peter Credlin.
And the purpose of the meeting was simply for them to ask me whether in the event that they were able to get the support of the crossbenchers and form government,
I would give them an undertaking to stay on as Treasury Secretary.
And I said I'd be very pleased to do so, and I would have stayed on.
Matter of fact, Tony Abbott said he would be honoured if I did so.
Anyway, I would have stayed on and I would have expected to have had another term as Treasury Secretary had I done so.
My term was up in April 2011.
I think had I stayed on, I probably would have had another term So my term was up in April 2011.
I think had I stayed on, I probably would have had another term. But the thing is that politics is fickle, right?
And it is not just about, I mean, it's largely about personalities,
of course, because that's the way the game is played.
But politicians on both sides can be absolutely brutal
with people and with institutions when they choose,
when the circumstances suit them.
And I had absolutely no confidence that where I had to stay on
that was going to improve the quality of the relationship
between the Treasury and the coalition government.
And so I didn't think it was in the Treasury's interest
that I stay on.
But mind you, I certainly didn't think it was in my interest
that I stay on either.
I'd had a gutful.
And, yeah, and so, and anyway, I'd been doing the job for 10 years and I thought it was the right time to hand over
and certainly to hand over to Martin it was the right time.
So I've never, a lot of people have asked me whether I ever,
because I was only 53 when I left, and a lot of people have asked me
whether I've ever had any regrets about leaving when I did
and maybe occasionally, but not very often.
Not very often, which isn't to say that I don't miss it.
I miss it enormously. Like I don't miss it. I miss it enormously.
Like every day I miss it.
What I miss, I miss the work.
I miss the colleagues.
I still think about the issues.
Like every day I think about the issues, but not in the way
that I was once able to think about the issues.
I mean, what an extraordinary privilege it is
for a person interested in policy
that if they wake up in the middle of the night
with an idea or a thought or even a burning question,
within a few hours they can have a team of very,
very smart people working that issue to death and then before the day is out be engaging in a robust debate
with those same people about the various issues, right?
I mean, that's extraordinary.
Who gets that opportunity?
And I lived that for years and years and years, right? I mean, that's extraordinary. Who gets that opportunity? And I lived that for years and years and years, right?
And it was just wonderful.
I guess it's just a shame for the country that you were cognizant
of the scapegoating dynamic in leaving Treasury
but not in walking into the Banking Royal Commission.
Yeah, well.
No, that's right.
Possibly I'm drawing a false equivalence.
No, you're not.
No, I don't think it is a false equivalence.
Well, I don't regard, I mean, it's false in the sense
that I don't think it's mean, it's false in the sense that I don't think
it's such a loss for the country that I left NAB when I left NAB.
Because, I mean, honestly, whilst I felt that I was having
an impact on NAB, and I know I was, and by the way,
I think it has, from everything I read,
the institution has continued to improve in the years since I left,
which is not all that long ago.
In those roles, no matter how much you do,
you can't achieve the sort of change that you can achieve
and have the sort of impact that you can have when you're, you know,
you're working in the Treasury.
I mean, you just can't.
And so those roles, those very senior policy advising roles,
they are, they're just in a completely different space from what people have been able to achieve in the corporate world or, you know, in all of those, many of them extraordinarily worthwhile NGOs that we have around, which are vital parts of the civil society that, you know, that underpins Australia. And they're certainly, you know, they're more than much
in a very different space from what academics,
even the world's best academics, are able to achieve with their work.
Of course, they're highly influential on, or should be,
on those senior policy people, but they don't have the same proximity
to the action.
They don't have the ear of the policy decision makers
and cannot in quite the same way.
And, of course, they wouldn't even seek to, right?
Would impact their independence.
Yeah, so there is something very special about it,
and I don't think you can really...
So there is no equivalence in that sense.
Nevertheless, there is something in the, what is it?
I don't even know what it is, but it's kind of, there's nevertheless a sense,
I mean, there's obviously a bit of a sense of personal loss,
although certainly nothing as profound as losing one of those senior policy roles.
I mean, the people who, like Martin years later,
who was unceremoniously sacked by Tony Abbott only to be brought back
by Malcolm Turnbull.
I mean, you just can't get your head around this stuff,
even though I understand how all that happened.
But I think I do.
I mean, that's really bloody devastating, right?
Losing that sort of role for absolutely no reason.
At least when I walked away from NAB, there was a reason for doing it.
It was very much in the interest of the NAV reputations that I considered
that somebody in my job, i.e. the chairman of the company,
stand up and say, well, you know what?
And it took me a while to get to this point, and I know that's my own failing,
but you know what?
As chairman of this outfit, I just have to take accountability for this. And by the way, there used to be a parallel in public service.
It was called ministerial accountability.
And it was much the same thing, which is that,
motivated by much the same idea, that, of course,
if you are the minister with responsibility for an agency and the agency misbehaves in some way, right, in some big way, even if you couldn't possibly personally have had anything to do with that, you are nevertheless accountable and you must resign.
And that's the doctrine of ministerial responsibility, right,
which we don't have any longer in Australia.
We had it up until some way through the Howard government.
I don't know, you may recall that in the, I think,
the first 12 months of the Howard government,
I think there were six ministers who lost their jobs.
Not all of them on the doctrine of ministerial responsibility,
but some, yes.
And it's a peculiar feature of the Westminster system
and it's a really odd, somebody has to be seen publicly
to take accountability for failings.
And where is the buck going to stop if not on the desk of the minister
or on the desk of the chairman of the company?
You know?
So I think it's actually, it should be seen as a strength
of our system, not a weakness of our system.
To finish the conversation, I thought it would be fun.
Fun.
Fun to ask you a few questions about specific policies.
Oh, yeah.
And these will be high variance questions.
Uh-huh.
So either-
And I'm not going to say, well, that's hypothetical.
Yeah, you can't say that.
No.
But either the questions will be kind of daft
or they could actually provoke really interesting responses.
So let's- we'll see how we go.
What would it take for Australia to build a major new city
and where would you put it?
Yeah.
Okay.
So that is a question I've thought about.
Yeah.
Oh, wow.
Great.
I know.
Did Treasury ever look into this?
Yeah, yeah, yeah.
So I, oh, yeah, yeah, yeah, yeah. Oh, interesting. Oh, wow. Great. I know. Did Treasury ever look into this? Yeah, yeah, yeah. So I, oh, yeah, yeah, yeah.
Oh, interesting.
Oh, yeah.
So when was this?
Oh, goodness me.
It was, it must have, well, yeah, I was Treasury Secretary,
certainly at the time.
And I remember having a conversation.
Pull your mic up.
You can lean back, just pull it.
I remember having a conversation with Kevin Rudd only a few days
after the November 2007 election.
In fact, it was the first conversation I had with him
after he became Prime Minister.
And we were just talking about a whole range of issues.
And he said, I think he said something like,
oh, and by the way, what do you think the maximum
sustainable population for Australia is?
And I said, probably 15 million thereabouts.
And he thought I said 50.
And he went forward and he said, 50 million.
Ah, right, good.
I said, no, no, no, I said 15.
Having you say that, population's already much more than 15.
And I said, I don't think you can argue that human activity
on this continent is sustainable, not in any way I think about it.
And so I think we'd have to cut our population quite a bit
if that's all we were going to do in order to achieve
a sustainable population.
And he was obviously shocked and obviously disappointed.
He may even have been appalled.
I don't know.
And then I said to him, but although that's my view,
it's also my view that it would be possible to construct a set
of policies that would sustain a population of 50 million, 5-0.
That's possible.
But it would mean that we'd have to do a lot of things
very differently.
And in that conversation, I said, for example,
we might have to build a whole brand-new city for 10 million people,
one that doesn't presently exist.
So then we subsequently, in the department,
and it wasn't just in the department,
there were other people involved in this as well,
started exploring where you might build not a whole brand new city
of 10 million, but say a number of cities of 1 million
where you'd put them throughout Australia, right?
And there, and so I'm not trying to avoid the question,
but here's the thing.
The reason we don't have a very fast train in Australia
from Melbourne to Brisbane is obvious, right?
And everybody knows it.
It's because we don't have the population that would support it.
That doesn't mean we don't have sufficient population in total.
It's the distribution of the population that makes it ridiculous, right?
But if the population were distributed differently, like along a corridor
that a train line might run through with maybe five stops,
something like that, maybe a few more,
because not every train has to be an express,
then it is possible to think about those things, right?
And so in specific answer to your question,
I think there's a lot of spots along a potential rail corridor
where you could build such cities.
Of course, there are environmental issues associated
with every one of those spots.
So those are issues that factors that have to be taken into account.
But we don't avoid those issues by allowing the continuing suburban sprawl
in Melbourne and Sydney and, oh, Perth, for heaven's sake, and Brisbane too.
All those cities that are going to become, probably going to become megacities.
Maybe Brisbane won't ever be called a megacity,
but it's going to be a big one and Perth's going to be a big one.
And Sydney and Melbourne will be called megacities globally, right,
if we don't do something smarter. So transport infrastructure, I think, is quite a big part of it.
And, of course, there are other things that would have to be attended to,
but I would start looking at that corridor.
That's so interesting.
Have you heard of the Bradfield scheme?
Oh, yeah.
So, as you know, it was this-
To turn the rivers back.
Yeah, this really ambitious project back in 1938,
I think it was first suggested,
basically to create an inland sea in Australia
by filling up like air and then diverting rivers to it.
And the idea was that this would basically drought-proof much of Queensland and South Australia.
Except that it would be saltwater, right?
Presumably, yeah.
Well, it would.
Yeah.
Yeah, I'm not actually familiar with the details of how they were going to get around that particular problem.
Well, I don't think they were.
I don't think they thought about it.
Right.
Well, that probably explains why it doesn't exist. No, no, I don't think that's about it. Right. Well, that probably explains why it doesn't exist.
No, no, I don't think that's why it doesn't exist.
There might be other reasons as well.
Yeah, I think there might be other reasons.
Yeah, okay.
Fair enough.
But regardless of the merits of that particular scheme,
I guess just thinking on that level of kind of like crazy ambitious
nation-building projects, what incredibly ambitious project are we not building currently that we should be?
Yeah. Outside of kind of new cities.
Yeah, outside of new cities. See, I would start, I actually would start with new cities.
That's why I was so well prepared for that. I'm glad I
asked. For that question. Yeah, I would start with new
cities. But others, oh, look, the renewable energy space offers huge challenge
and huge opportunity, right?
And we're kind of, look, this is a gross generalisation.
So it's not, it's nowhere near close
to being accurate, but we are applying much, to date anyway,
to date we've applied much the same thinking and policy analysis
to the accommodation of renewable energy projects
as we have anything else.
Even though we know we've got a pretty good sense of the size
of the transformation that's going to be required.
And, of course, whenever anybody talks about it, I say,
oh, my God, we've got to do, you know, what we've already done.
We've got to do it 10 times over and we've got to do it within 10 years
or something, you know, things to that effect.
And I know some people are thinking about an entirely new approach to this like just turn
the way we think about these issues on their heads and let's just say okay let's aim to achieve that
outcome right what are we going to have to do in order to achieve that outcome it does bring you
back to locational issues like where you're going to locate the cities um it it forces you to think about transmission infrastructure, of course,
in a way that we haven't to date thought about it.
It forces you to think about things like local electricity networks
using battery storage or a whole variety of different possible
pumped hydro storage or a whole variety of different possible pumped hydro storage or whatever,
every one of those projects would be multi-billion dollar projects.
They're huge.
And as a country, aside from Snowy Hydro, and not even Snowy Hydro 2.0,
it's not of the scale that's going to be required
of some of these other projects.
It's not even big enough.
I mean, some of these projects that we are going to have to invest in
will be much bigger than Snowy 2.0, right?
What sort of policy thinking do you have to bring
to projects of that order of magnitude?
And it's kind of pressing, right, because it's not as if we can
avoid these challenges.
So that's another one.
Here's another one.
When I was working for the Gillard government leading the development
of the white paper in Australia in the Asian century,
this idea popped into my head.
I was in Darwin and I thought,
why doesn't Darwin look like Singapore?
So that's a good one to think about.
What would it take? I like that.
Yeah, what would it take?
What could you do?
And I know what's happened since to the port of Darwin
makes some of these questions problematic.
But if there's enough money and enough will,
you could build a second port of Darwin.
Would it be possible to do a deal with the Singapore Port Authority
or whatever it's called with respect to entrepot activity.
You think of all those ships that sit for weeks and weeks and weeks
off Singapore merely to drop their cargo,
for that cargo to be sorted and then picked up by another ship.
It's going to take it somewhere else.
It's not like it was never heading for Singapore
other than to allow for transference from one vessel to another vessel.
Darwin's a few hours south of Singapore, of course,
and as the ship would sail, I'm not sure how much additional time
it would take, but, I mean, if you're going to be sitting
for a couple of weeks off Singapore, why not divert to Darwin
and it'll cut your time massively and get the activity undertaken there.
Why not see the port of Darwin as an export port for some of the natural resources that are going out through the port
of Gladstone?
A lot of them are located in Western Queensland.
What would it take?
You're getting the vibe here.
I can see by the expression on your face. What would it take
to have that cargo sent west and then north out through the Port of Darwin? And then what are the
other opportunities that would be available in essentially a tropical city
in the north of Australia, very close to all of Southeast Asia.
I mean, I think I did see it.
When I was consulting on this project, I visited the then Chief Minister of the Northern Territory
and stood in his office and he's got this.
I'll bet it's still there.
I'll bet every Chief Minister of the Northern Territory
hangs onto this.
It's a wall map.
And, of course, Darwin is at the centre of it, right?
So that's how the world is drawn.
That's how the world map's drawn.
It's wonderful.
And then there are these concentric circles identified by flight time
or maybe it's kilometres.
Anyway, it doesn't really matter.
It's an easy translation, right?
And it just shows how many Asian cities are closer to Darwin
than is Melbourne or Perth or Sydney.
And it allows you to think about Darwin playing a completely different role as a significant Southeast Asian city
with obvious connections to several very big cities in Australia.
Right?
Mm-hmm.
Yep.
There's another idea for you.
This is great.
My high variance questions are going well so far.
Oh.
Okay.
Here's another one.
So we have a decentralized privatized super system.
Yep.
Two trillion of disengaged money.
Mm-hmm.
And that's a honeypot for fraud and misbehavior.
Mm-hmm.
ASIC has to be the arbiter of that fraud.
Has ASIC been set up for failure?
Does it have enough resources to oversee a honeypot that large?
Okay.
So, no, it doesn't.
I mean, clearly it doesn't.
It has to rely on reporting and information systems,
data collection systems that are, well, they're getting better.
But, I mean, it's, I don't want to sound alarmist.
And I'm not really alarmist about it because, actually,
things have gone pretty damn well.
You'd have to say things have gone pretty damn well to date.
But it's going to become increasingly challenging obviously for ASIC to stay on top of that
and in part that's because
I mean it's not just fraud
but there's also the risk of
internet-based activity, the so-called cybercrime,
for which I don't think any regulatory agency in the world
would regard themselves as exceptionally well-placed to deal with.
It's just an increasingly difficult set of issues for we humans having invented the capability to now deal with.
I mean, I say I am.
So that's under KYC provisions, know your customer provisions.
Very sensible.
Understand it.
Understand it completely.
But I'm old enough to remember a time when you'd never have to do that.
And of course you didn't have to do it because the risks
to which you're exposed or were exposed back then
are several orders of magnitude less than what they are now.
The risk of identity fraud or identity theft
and then fraud that can be perpetrated once the identity theft has occurred.
I mean, all the spam emails and so on that you get.
And I was in this extraordinary conversation
with a very helpful person in the bank and I said,
look, I've received this email from you.
Well, it looks like it comes from you, but I can't be sure.
And the reason I'm worried about it is because I've heard your CEO say,
be wary of spam emails.
We'll never send you an email that asks you to click on a link to anything.
I said, have a look at this email.
It's got 12 links in it.
Turned out it was a genuine email from that thing.
Like holy hell.
Now, is that just a case of the left hand not knowing
what the right hand's doing?
I don't know.
But it's hugely complex and the exposures that we all have
are of a diabolical order of magnitude, right?
And so, yeah, the simple answer to your question is that, no,
I don't think ASIC could possibly have the resources that would be required to prevent fraud in all cases,
and that's probably not its objective.
I mean, it's probably looking to a more realistic objective, which is to provide a level
of deterrence that minimises some level of comfort,
the amount of fraud that's going to be undertaken.
And that's not a comfortable place, but it's a realistic place.
And by the way, that issue raises its head because of the interconnection, because of the way in which our financial system is wired, including the superannuation system.
That issue is there no matter whether the superannuation funds are privately owned as they are or, you know, if we had one mega superannuation fund
in public ownership, you'd still have the issue.
I mean, if the Commonwealth Bank was still in public ownership,
it would still have the same issues that all the other banks have got.
True.
So on my most recent podcast episode, I interviewed Palmer Luckey,
who's a US tech entrepreneur.
He's founded a couple of unicorn companies.
The second is Endural, which sells weapons tech to the US government,
the Australian government, other Western governments.
Oh, wow.
And I think he's designed a lot of the tech himself.
But he was telling me about how the defense industry in the US
is grossly inefficient.
Contracts are awarded on a cost plus basis.
And the incentives are structured such that sometimes there's almost
a competition to see who can put in the most expensive bid,
not the cheapest bid.
Is this problem similar in Australia as well?
And I guess like as a corollary of that,
could we view the nuclear subs decision through that lens?
I don't think that's not the lens that I would use in looking
at the nuclear subs issue.
The issue that has bedevilled defence procurement in Australia is, yeah,
it's in part to do with, let's call them inefficiencies or cost padding
or cost overruns on the part of vendors or contractors,
that's part of it.
But there's a part of me, because I'm an economist,
I kind of accept that it's a fact of life
that people will seek to get away with whatever they can get away with.
Sorry, that they will get away with whatever they can get away with.
And I know that's harsh.
And I know actually I hope it's the case that most of the people I know
are not actually like that.
But look, it's not a bad working assumption if you're a policy economist, right?
And so I think more about then what you can do
in respect of institutional arrangements and policy guidelines
and whatever to protect yourself or to protect the system from that, right? So, all right, you know, we can lament that people are greedy
and we can lament that greed encourages people
to behave dishonestly.
But isn't there something that we can do to protect government,
protect taxpayers, protect citizens
against that?
Now, the big issue in defence procurement, for as long as I had any visibility on it, our determination, infatuation actually, with bespoke assets,
the development of bespoke assets.
It cannot possibly be the case that a piece of military hardware
used anywhere else in the world is suitable for Australian conditions,
even if we have no intention of ever using it in Australia
but could only ever deploy it to a foreign battlefield.
What were the origins of that infatuation?
Isn't that a great question?
And I don't know the answer to that question
even though I saw it play out time and time and time again.
It is possible that those running that line.
So that's all about it would be a mistake, Prime Minister,
to build an off-the-shelf product.
We have to build it here.
Now, because there is no off-the-shelf product that suits us. Was that a bullshit argument that was really motivated
by a desire to protect local industry jobs?
Yeah, probably.
I'm not sure, but quite probably.
And when you look at the connections between the military
and domestic suppliers,
that's plausible, right?
And you look at, as in the US, that military people
on leaving military positions tend to pop up in jobs,
in supply firms.
Yeah, well, you know, it's plausible.
It's plausible that what's at play there is the protection
of domestic industry jobs.
But I remember having this conversation with somebody
who used to run defence procurement, and his take on it was that, yes, well, that may be true,
but then on the other hand, doesn't it make sense for Australia
to sustain a capability in the construction of military assets?
Because you never know, right? And the answer to that question has to be, well because you never know, right?
And the answer to that question has to be, well, yes, okay, right?
Of course it does, right?
So the policy challenge here is actually quite tricky.
In many cases, the policy conclusion would be buy off the shelf.
But then on the other hand, there is a policy argument for sustaining a local build capability, not of everything,
but, you know, who knows of what?
We just don't know, right?
So that's how I think the policy issue should be should be dealt with and there shouldn't
be um and it should be dealt with in an open in an open way right we are we are we really are
trying to sustain this domestic industry capability yes we are and we're not going
we're not making any secret of that we're not trying to hide that um but that's why we're doing it we're not doing it because australia is unique
uh and needs heavily modified things knowing that there's a very high probability that the
modifications are going to lead to extraordinary cost overruns and time overruns and in some cases
and there are some cases i'm aware of where it's rendered the asset completely inoperable
and it's had to be scrapped.
And I'm talking about projects worth more than a billion dollars,
but I'm not going to name them.
The economist Vernon Smith had on my podcast a couple of years ago.
As a factoid, he actually shared the Nobel Prize with Danny Kahneman.
They got it the same year.
Yep.
So he wrote a book on the US housing bubble a few years after the Great Recession.
And he argued that the Bipartisan Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997,
Clinton's Act, which exempted home resales from capital gains taxes, is like the prime suspect
for the trigger that caused the US housing bubble
because suddenly you have this kind of exogenous shift
where people start to view homes as a speculative asset.
You mean they've become more Australian?
Is that what this question's about?
I think you can see where I'm going.
I guess, like, let me phrase it this way.
To the extent that, well, at least in the 2000s,
Australian house prices were overvalued
or certain housing markets in Australia were frothy.
Could we tell a similar story?
Could we say that the Howard government's decision
to halve the rate of the capital gains tax in 1999
was the trigger for some, I'll call it whatever you want,
bubble or valuation, et cetera?
I think we'd have to say it had a significant impact.
Yeah.
Would that be the prime suspect?
Prime suspect.
I don't know.
There's a few things at play here, right?
So in my view, definitely one of them, right?
So prior to that, we had capital gains tax indexation.
So the cost base of the acquired asset was indexed along the CPI,
and you paid capital gains tax on the difference between the sale price
and the index cost base, right?
So you pay capital gains tax on the – but full, at full marginal rates,
on the real gain, the bid over inflation.
Now, in high inflationary times, that is where the CPI is rocketing
and house prices are just kind of chugging along,
that means you get a lot of protection from having
to pay capital gains tax. But, of course, if monetary policy is effective
and the Reserve Bank is successful in keeping inflation
within the range of 2% to 3% on average over the site,
well, even let's leave it there.
If keeping it within that range of 2% to 3%,
then there are going to be many times,
at least Australian history suggests,
there are going to be many times at least australian history suggests are going to be many times in which um it would be rational even to expect that house price growth
is going to result in uh very substantial real gains and of course the howard government change
did mean that those real gains would be taxed at a much lower rate, right? Basically, half the rate, right?
Most of the gain would be taxed at half the rate it would have been taxed at previously.
That's with respect to rental property.
And of course, owner-occupier property has always been exempt, right?
Back from 19 September 1985, has always been exempt. And so you've got, you had particularly through those, I don't know, through the years 2001, 2002, 2003, I mean, we were dealing with accelerating house prices through those years. to say that the capital gains tax decision played a significant role in what was happening
in the housing market, because what we saw was a lot of people jumping into investor
housing.
I mean, there was more debt being taken on by households around occupier housing as well,
but there was strong investor interest.
And we've seen that strong investor interest in every house price run
up in the subsequent period, every one of them.
Whenever the house prices take off, investors pile in.
And those investors have got a blend of debt finance and increasingly, increasingly pretty close to 100% equity acquisition
because they're baby boomers who have retired
and are wondering where they're going to put all of that cash
that they didn't manage to get into a tax-preferred
superannuation vehicle, right?
Where are they going to put it?
Put it in investor housing.
You won't have the interest deduction that you would have had
had your debt financed.
You know what?
You're going to make a capital gain and you're going to walk away laughing
because only half the capital gain will be included
in your taxable income.
Yeah, I think it's a significant part of the story.
And also, and it was in the way that you phrased the question,
I mean this idea that what's motivating it
is speculation is, I think, true.
It's true.
I think what happens when these house prices accelerate
is the people who jump into the market are jumping
in for speculative reasons.
It's not too much of an oversimplification to say that everyone
who's negatively gearing is by definition speculating.
No.
No, probably not.
Probably not.
Because after all, it's an investor asset if it's negatively geared, right?
So we're not talking about anarcho-pars.
But you're also losing money on the carry,
so presumably you think you'll make it back in price appreciation.
You got it, right?
I mean, otherwise it's nuts.
Yeah.
And I don't believe that people who are doing this are mad, right?
Quite the converse.
And I remember having discussions about this
around the Reserve Bank board table from time to time and just saying, well, what, if anything,
can the Reserve Bank do about this?
After all, it's not its mandate to control house price inflation.
Its mandate is to look at consumer price inflation and keep consumer
price inflation between that target band of 2% to 3%.
Okay, on average over the cycle.
But with respect to speculative assets, including property,
it has no particular mandate other than to wring its hands
and be worried that if bubbles burst,
they could cause some instability in the financial system, which is a concern,
and they could lead to broader macroeconomic impact,
so affect the economy more generally,
which would be a concern of the Reserve Bank.
But the Reserve Bank does does not to date anyway have instruments at its disposal that would allow
to address asset price inflation as opposed to consumer price inflation now we have in recent
years under the present governor seen some use of so-called macro prudential instruments.
These are instruments that APRA holds, not the Reserve Bank.
If it is the case that the Reserve Bank, and we don't know because we've never been told,
but if it is the case that the Reserve Bank has been leaning on or instructing or in some way influencing APRA to make use of those macroprudential instruments,
then that's a curious thing, right?
Because that's, and I presume that is what's happening
and I'm not being critical of it either,
but it doesn't sit well with the idea that the board
of the Reserve Bank determines monetary policy in Australia
and exercises monetary policy
independently. Yeah. I mean, I guess
I kind of empathise with the difficulty of the Reserve Bank
situation in the sense that if on the one hand you say to them that it's
not their mandate to lean against the wind, then
if they find themselves in a situation where they're very concerned
about a build-up of household debt, presumably there's got
to be some other way of addressing that.
Oh, no, no, no.
Don't get me wrong.
I'm not being critical of them.
I'm not being critical of them.
I'm not saying you are.
No, no, no.
I think the position is, well, it's not, I guess it's not diabolical,
but it's a very difficult position that they're in.
And I can understand why they would be from time to time
very concerned about asset price inflation,
particularly speculative-driven asset price inflation.
And of course, it makes perfectly good sense
that they'd be concerned about that.
But if their only instrument is the overnight cash rate,
the target cash rate of interest,
then they are simply not capable of dealing with that issue.
I mean, if house prices have been running,
have been increasing at 15% per annum for, let's say,
three years.
And there are several periods in Australia's recent history where you can see that.
It's highly likely that people who are purchasing property as a speculative asset have got in
mind that for some time, house prices are going to continue to increase in double digits,
right?
So at what rate, to what level are you going to have to lift?
Suppose they do have a mortgage.
To what rate are you going to have to lift the overnight cash rate
of interest to convince them that that's a dumb thing to do?
And the answer, I think, on every occasion I've looked at it,
is that you'd have to lift the cash rate of interest
to a level that would generate a recession
because it would just kill the rest of the economy.
So that's the problem.
You need additional instruments.
And it makes sense.
You've got now more than one target you got a
target for consumer price inflation you got a target now for speculative assets
a speculative asset price inflation you're probably going to need more than
one instrument yeah mm-hmm Tinbergen real Tinbergen yeah yeah one goal one
instrument mm-hmm um not to to spend too much time on this, but I mean,
I think it's now quite clear that the Reserve Bank
did consciously lean against the wind in the early 2000s.
Was that the right decision in those circumstances?
Yes.
Whatever you think of like-
No, no, no, I do.
No, no, no.
Well, I was on the board at the time.
How could I say otherwise? But no, I do. No, no, no. Well, I was on the board at the time. How could I say otherwise?
But no, I do think it was the right thing to do.
They actually did more than that, right?
There was an exercise of what's collectively referred
to as jawboning.
You know, so Governor McFarlane was out there publicly
talking about the risks, all right?
One should not, I forget the precise words,
it doesn't really matter, but it was to the effect
that you should not, nobody should assume
that house prices are going to increase at these rates forever.
And those who are operating with that premise in mind
are taking on an increasing risk, right?
And during that period, of course, I know even people you'd talk
to socially would say to you, but house prices never fall.
That's how poorly informed markets can be, right?
So house prices never fall.
It's a one-way bet, right?
Hmm.
I mean, in more recent times, I think there's a broader appreciation of the fact that there is a significant risk that house prices could fall and could fall by quite a lot, right?
And you may find yourself in negative equity territory, having to sell a house and recover less than what you owe the bank.
And I think that's, you think that people find that really confronting.
I mean, that's not part of the Australian mindset.
But then neither is it part of the Australian mindset
that you should expect to lose money when you find yourself
in front of a poker machine.
But anyway.
Okay.
Last question.
I think for me, this is one of the more interesting questions.
But let's see what you think.
Why hasn't Australia taken a populist turn to the same extent as the US or UK?
I think the jury's still out.
Do you have any explanations as to why it hasn't happened so far?
I think there have been periods at which we have been
at considerable risk of doing so.
Yeah, so, gee, how do I answer this question
without getting really, really personal about particular, you know.
Look, the risk is obviously on the right, let's call it the right side of politics.
Pretty much, I think, because the issues that left-wing populists have been able to exploit in other countries are not as obvious here.
So we do have income inequality, of course we do.
And we do have wealth inequality, of course we do.
And the wealth inequality is probably increasing, yeah.
But we have also, we avoided much of the global financial crisis, right?
Whereas in North America and Europe, that really brought these issues to everybody's consciousness, right?
And that's when you had the Occupy Wall Street movement and so on, right?
As a consequence of that. And it really gave voice to, I know they're not all left wing
and actually some of them are right wing, but anyway,
it gave voice to disaffected elements that are a bit more extreme
than what you see in Australia.
So I think that's part of the story. And the challenge that I think the left side of politics
finds itself dealing with in Australia is really a challenge from,
it's more from the environmental movement, right?
And that's not an extreme or populist challenge at all.
It's actually a deeply conservative challenge,
if you think about it, because it's motivated by conservation.
It's motivated by a desire to protect what we have,
what we have left.
And it's a movement that would like to see government do more,
not less. So I think it's more on the, I think the risk for Australia is more on the right side of
the political spectrum than it is on the left.
And there was a time in the 1990s when I think the major political parties
on the right side of politics were deeply concerned
about what was happening there and how to deal
with what was happening there.
And what do you do?
I mean, you either ignore it, and there's a good reason
for ignoring it,
which in economics, I don't know what they call it
in political science, I don't know, but in economics
it's referred to as Hotelling's Rule on spatial location, really.
Are you familiar with Hotelling's Rule?
So the simple idea is you've got your town is just
a ribbon development, right?
So you've just got one road running through the town
and you've got two stores and they sell the same.
Well, they don't necessarily sell the same product,
but actually part of our tellings rule is that they will sell
the same product.
But anyway, two general stores, right?
And where do they locate?
And let's start with the proposition that one locates at the western end of the town
and the other one locates at the eastern end of the town. That being the case, either one of them
would have an incentive to move closer to the centre because if they move closer to the centre,
so let's suppose the one at the western end of the town moves closer to the centre, they will
retain all of the customers to their west and they'll get half of the customers to their east, right?
And so they end up side by side.
Converging.
Right in the middle.
And they end up selling exactly the same products
and being located in exactly the same place.
It's a place and this is why duopolies end up with identical behaviour,
blah, blah, blah, right?
So that's hoteling's rule.
And in political science, I don't think they call it that,
but they've got the same proposition, that it makes sense for the,
if you've got two major political parties, it makes sense for them
to sit in the centre, right, with virtually indistinguishable policies.
And for many, many policies in Australia, for many years now,
that's what you've seen.
It's exactly what you've seen.
So if you were in charge of running, had responsibility
for the right wing of that political system,
and you saw an extreme right movement out there,
a valid response is to ignore it. political system and you saw an extreme right movement out there,
a valid response is to ignore it because, after all,
it's not as if those people are going to jump all the way and direct their preferences to the left side of politics.
That ain't going to happen.
So provided they remain a fringe group or a small group,
you're going to end up with their preference flow anyway.
You don't get that in the United States.
There's no such thing as a preference flow, right?
In any way, voting is optional, right?
But with exhaustive preferential voting and compulsory voting,
such as we have in Australia, it's a legitimate thing,
a valid thing to do, maybe a smart thing to do,
to just ignore what's happening out there and just rely
on getting their preferences eventually at the end of the day.
Trouble is, that relies on a lot of people being able
to hold their nerve, right, and there's something else.
And, look, I'm no expert on the Liberal Party,
but remember the Liberal Party is a...
Well, if you go right back to the formation of the Liberal Party,
I mean, for goodness sake, you had the free traders
and the protectionists get together.
I mean, and they got together in order to produce a party
that was in opposition to the Labor Party.
That was the only reason they got together.
And you've got free traders and protectionists in the same party.
It's not going to be happy on policy.
We'll never be happy on policy, right?
And so that was in the party that predated the Liberal Party,
but it still is in the Liberal Party.
You've got both free traders and you've got protectionists and you've got so-called moderates and you've got right-wingers
and you've got, you know, I mean, you've got everything there, right, everything that's non-Labour,
which I think basically means don't like trade unions.
I think that's what it means, which seemed to be a disappearing issue.
And so the question for the moment is really about the identity
of the Liberal Party.
I think it is.
And if you'd like to see the Liberal Party remain attractive
to those who tend to be a bit right-wing
in their thinking, you're going to want to keep the stake
in the ground right there, right?
Because if you follow the alternative that I was describing earlier,
that the hotelings rule would drive you to,
when you see the emergence of a political party in the extreme right,
that would push you further to the centre, further to the left, right?
That would be the smart thing to do, according to our tellings rule.
But if you're ideologically really uncomfortable with that
and you can only ever imagine yourself occupying the right,
then you're going to seek to do battle with the extremists on the right.
And I think that's the real risk.
The real risk in Australia, I think, is that in these terms,
and I don't want to overstate it, but I think it is nevertheless a risk,
is that a principal, a major political party,
decides that it wants to occupy an extreme position over there
on the right, and that's what's happened to the Republican Party
in the United States.
I don't think we should rule it out as a risk,
even though I think it's a low probability outcome.
But then what is a higher probability outcome?
A higher probability outcome is probably that the Liberal Party
becomes a different party.
Maybe it formally dissolves the coalition arrangement
with the National Party.
Doesn't mean it would not, obviously doesn't mean it wouldn't seek
to rely upon the support of the National Party for supply, informing government
following an election.
I mean, that's how coalitions operate around the world
in many, many countries, right?
But they're not, they don't see themselves as being part
of the same party and they just come together in a marriage
of convenience.
Coalitions are very unstable.
Very unstable.
And that's a possible future for Australia.
Yeah.
Can I, so yeah, that's all super interesting and makes complete sense.
I also just want to offer one speculative explanation for why we've avoided the same levels of populism
as the US and the UK have experienced and get your reaction
to it. Because I think it's an underrated explanation
and maybe someone listening can do this as an honest thesis
or something, but we're a highly urbanized country.
This is an exaggeration, but you could almost say that Australia's population is distributed
like bimodally.
You have a lot of people in rural centers and then most people in the massive conurbations.
Yeah.
And we don't have that middle category of like the medium-sized cities that you have
in the US and the UK.
Oh, wow.
You think they're all redneck cities, do you?
No, no, no, no.
But what I do think is when globalization and automation kind
of hollowed out the manufacturing centers, so say in the UK,
that's like Sheffield in the US, Dayton, St. Louis, Milwaukee,
you have large swathes of the population disaffected, angry,
suffering the indignity of unemployment.
Yeah, this is really interesting.
And that's dry tinder waiting for a demagogue.
Yeah, yeah, yeah.
We don't have that.
And to complicate this picture further, the Australian cities,
which would have a legitimate claim to kind of bang our versions
of Detroit and Sheffield, have actually maintained
their progressive identities.
That's true.
Newcastle, Wollongong, Geelong, Adelaide.
Yeah.
So it's a puzzle, but I think it's worth thinking about.
I don't know if you have any reactions.
I do, I do, I do. No, I like it's worth thinking about. I don't know if you have any reactions. I do, I do, I do.
No, I like it.
I like it.
I do like it.
And it's certainly true.
You travel through, yeah, you're absolutely right.
You travel through North America.
You travel through the United Kingdom.
I mean, you see those rust belts exactly.
Yeah.
And these are the cities that kind of turned against the European Union
and the UK and voted for Brexit en masse.
I see the same thing playing out in Scotland too.
It's the other way around.
But, you know, people I think still blame Maggie Thatcher
for the closure of the shipyards up there or something.
Somebody was trying to explain this to me.
They said they'll always vote Labour.
They'll always vote Labour.
Yeah, right.
I don't know whether that's true or not, but they intended to.
Yeah.
So, no, that makes perfectly good sense.
And it comes back to something that we were discussing earlier, right,
which is about the dangers, the risks associated
with people losing their jobs, losing their self-esteem,
losing their capabilities to, well, actually to function properly in society.
And, yeah, I mean, that's fertile ground for the demagogues, as you say.
Absolutely.
Sure.
So, no, I find that quite an attractive,
if also unattractive, explanation.
Yep.
Good.
Ken, this has officially been my longest podcast ever.
Oh, my goodness.
But I have enjoyed every minute.
Thank you so much.
No, it's been a pleasure.
I don't often get to talk to anybody about these issues and certainly not in this depth and length. And I never get questions of this quality. So there you go. Thank you.
It's my honor. Thank you. things before you go. First, for links, show notes, and the episode transcript, go to my website,
thejspod.com. That's thejspod.com. And finally, if you think the conversations I'm having are
worth sharing, I'd be deeply grateful if you sent this episode or the show to a friend.
Message it to them, email them, drop a link in a WhatsApp group. The primary way these conversations
reach more people is through my
listeners sharing them. Thanks again. Until next time. Ciao.