The Joe Walker Podcast - Ken Henry — An Economic Odyssey

Episode Date: May 9, 2023

Dr Ken Henry is an Australian economist who served as Secretary of Australia's Treasury from 2001 to 2011. He was instrumental in helping Australia avoid recession during the 2008 Global Financial Cri...sis — Australia was the only major advanced economy to do so. Full transcript available at: thejspod.comSee omnystudio.com/listener for privacy information.

Transcript
Discussion (0)
Starting point is 00:00:00 Ladies and gentlemen, boys and girls, swagmen and swagettes, welcome back to the show. Before we start, a quick housekeeping item to say I love getting correspondence from you, so I want to take a moment to encourage it further. I'm continually shocked and humbled by how impressive this audience is. Some truly brilliant people listen to the show and that makes engaging with you all particularly fruitful. So if you have suggestions, things you think I should read, ideas you want to share, please get in touch. You can reach me by email joe at the jspod.com or on Twitter. My handle there is at Joseph N Walker. Okay, to this episode, our guest is Ken Henry. Ken Henry is an Australian economist who has held roles in academia, the public service, as a political advisor,
Starting point is 00:01:14 and in the public sector as chairman of National Australia Bank, one of Australia's big four banks. But his most prominent role was as Secretary of Australia's Treasury Department from 2001 to 2011, which effectively made him the most powerful bureaucrat in the country for a decade. That decade included, of course, what we Australians call the GFC, or Global Financial Crisis of 2008. Australians don't speak of the Great Recession since Australia was the world's only major advanced economy to avoid recession during that period. That success was in no small part thanks to Ken and his treasury team who engineered Australia's fiscal response to the crisis. Ken's immortal advice to then Prime Minister Kevin Rudd
Starting point is 00:02:05 was, go early, go hard, and go households. So it was a real honour to chat with Ken about his career, about economic policymaking, and economic theory. Now, for non-Australian listeners, such as my British and American swagmen and swagettes, this episode partly focuses on topics within an Australian context, which might seem parochial. However, if you enjoy learning about other cultures and about economic policymaking in specific contexts, you will find this episode extremely enriching. At four and a half hours, this is my longest podcast ever, and it remains fascinating right up to the very end. So a word of advice, if you come across a topic during the conversation that doesn't interest you personally, keep listening because many other subjects are covered throughout the discussion that you will probably find interesting. Like all my episodes, this episode comes with an
Starting point is 00:03:10 amazing resource that is a transcript complete with helpful hyperlinks to things mentioned during the conversation. Except this episode's transcript is the length of a small novel. And you can find it on my website, thejspod.com. That is thejspod.com. Finally, please excuse any dogs barking or other background noises you might hear during the conversation as we recorded this at Ken's farm. The recording took place on Thursday, the 4th of May, 2023. Enjoy. Ken Henry, welcome to the podcast. Good to be with you. So Ken, I have questions about treasury as an institution and the process of making policy.
Starting point is 00:04:01 I've got philosophical questions and I have questions about specific policies, but first I want to start with some history. Okay. You joined Treasury's Tax Policy Division in 1984 and then you moved across to Paul Kidding's office in 1986 while he was Treasurer to be one of his senior economic advisors and you were there until 1991. What was it like to be in the engine room of Australia's golden era of economic reform? Well, it was an absolute blast. You know, for some years before that, I had been a junior academic
Starting point is 00:04:37 having just completed a PhD, and I went into the Treasury in I think it was August of 1984, and I was naive but curious. I went in because of what I could see happening within government, that there was a hell of a lot going on. The whole Keating reform era that had commenced, I guess, really, well, pretty much after they were elected in March 1983. I mean, they got straight into it, but by early 1984, it was clear that this was going to be a reformist government. I thought, well, I wouldn't mind finding out what this is like, stepping out of academia. But I thought, I can't step out of academia for very long. And all my colleagues said to me, you're nuts.
Starting point is 00:05:25 If you step out of academia, you'll never get back in or you get back in but you take one year out. It's like going to sleep for five years as far as your academic career is concerned. And I thought, oh, well, okay, I'll put a limit of two years on it. I reckon after six months of being in the Treasury in that reform period, I knew that I was never going back to academia and that policy was going to, and policy work, was going to dominate my life. I knew that after six months. and of course I was working as part of the team through the first half of 1985 that put together
Starting point is 00:06:10 that draft white paper on tax reform that Keating, without cabinet authority by the way, that he took to the National Tax Summit in June of 1985 without any support from within, from amongst his colleagues, on the basis of work that had been produced by a very small team of Treasury people. Maybe you'd need two hands to count the number, maybe, who had produced a reform package that had the support of nobody outside of the Treasury.
Starting point is 00:06:53 Nobody. Like not in academia, not amongst other government departments, and certainly not in the media. And yet Keating had the courage to take that all the way to the National Tax Summit, knowing beforehand that he was almost certain that he was going to lose the argument. And I just thought, God, it can't get any better than this, right? And so when in the middle of 1986 he asked me to join his office as a senior advisor and get even closer to the action,
Starting point is 00:07:35 which actually I think from my perspective it really meant get closer to him, well, it was irresistible. It was an irresistible invitation. And as you say, I stayed there for five years. But I would say that whole five years was just a blast, just one continuous amazing experience. I don't think the adrenaline ever stopped flowing, not for a second. Do you have any Keating anecdotes that you can share?
Starting point is 00:08:05 No. I've got Keating anecdotes. I'm not sure that I've got ones that I would share. I think, I mean, maybe one, which is maybe give you a bit of a flavour for the sort of person he is. And I won't mention... No, I'll give you two. I won't mention names, but I don't think these stories
Starting point is 00:08:39 have ever been told publicly, and there's no reason why they should be. And I was the only witness to these two. But on one occasion, it was shortly after I joined Keating's office, so we were still in the old Parliament House, one of his senior colleagues, very senior minister, came in to see Paul. And I happened to be sitting in Paul's office across the desk from him.
Starting point is 00:09:11 I'd been briefing him on some policy issue. And the senior minister came in and he said, look, Paul, I really need to talk to you before question time. And I got up to leave and the fellow said, no, no, no, look, honestly, it's all right. You stay. It doesn't matter. And Paul said, what is it, mate? And he said, well, you know, I'm taking all these decisions. And I find myself waking up at 2 o'clock or 3 o'clock in the morning just worrying about whether I was taking,
Starting point is 00:09:50 whether I'd been taking the right decisions or not and, you know, questioning my own judgment on the decisions that I'd taken the previous day and days before. And he said, I'm just in turmoil over it. And I think these are the precise words Paul said. He said, well, mate, it's time to go. Wow. Yeah, like, wow.
Starting point is 00:10:22 And I thought, God, I don't know anybody else, and I'm sure I've never met anybody else in my life who would have responded in that way. And I mean, it wasn't as if Paul was unfeeling at all. It was just, in fact, probably quite the opposite. Because they then went on to discuss why Paul had said what Paul had said. And shortly after the minister did, he stepped down. So there's a, I mean, it can come across as almost brutal, but it's, there's a method, sorry, there is, there was more to it than that.
Starting point is 00:11:11 I mean, Paul wasn't being unkind at all. He understood the situation absolutely perfectly, but his assessment was the right one, and I'm sure that minister came to the, well, he obviously came to the same view, that yes, yes, this is the right assessment. You're absolutely right. So the implication being that the reality of power is that you have to be able to sit with these decisions and make them confidently. Yeah, exactly.
Starting point is 00:11:41 Yeah, yeah. And if you find just, exactly. And if you find yourself questioning your own judgment then this is not the place that you should be you should not be you should not be putting yourself in this position find a a more peaceful existence doing something else, helping out in some other way. And this particular minister had had a long career as an advisor and official in various capacities and, you know, a highly successful career and was much loved by all of his colleagues, including Keating, right?
Starting point is 00:12:22 So this was not a person without talent, far from it, far from it. But he'd found himself in a position in which he was uncomfortable and a position of power, and the power was, or the exercise of the power was, I guess, killing him, slightly, but killing him, right? Anyway, the second anecdote I'll tell, this is now in the new Parliament House, but two very senior business people came in to talk Keating as Treasurer,
Starting point is 00:13:04 and he was probably also Deputy Prime Minister by this time. I'm not sure, but anyway, certainly Treasurer, and he was probably also Deputy Prime Minister by this time, I'm not sure, but anyway, certainly Treasurer, obviously, to inform him of a decision that they had reached to merge their two national institutions, both large corporate entities. And this was the first Paul had heard of it. But he was a bit curious as to why the two had sought a meeting with him and a meeting under, you know, it was a time constraint and we have to see you today. And they didn't say why, at least in the meeting and, you know, it was a time constraint and we have to see you today.
Starting point is 00:13:46 And they didn't say why, at least in the meeting request, but we have to see you today. It's very, very important, critical. And so when they arrived, he asked me to step in to really just to be a witness to the meeting. And I was blown away. The two, you know, since I've been in very senior positions in the corporate world myself, but as a young policy advisor, what I saw was these two people who were absolutely certain that what they were doing was in the national interest. It couldn't be questioned.
Starting point is 00:14:31 It must have been. And they were merely, as a matter of courtesy, informing the Treasurer that they were going to do this. I don't know if they knew that the Treasurer, under various bits of legislation, one in particular, had the power to prevent them from doing what they'd already decided they were going to do. I don't know if they knew that. But when he said to them, you're going to do what? I saw them sit back, colour drained from their faces, and they went on, explained it again.
Starting point is 00:15:03 And he said, you think you're going to do that? Well, yes. And he said, like hell you are. You're not going to do that. No way are you going to do that. They were absolutely shocked. And Paul had had no briefing on this issue. He didn't know what was coming.
Starting point is 00:15:26 But he had this, look, it's more than instinct. By then, he had such a robust policy framework in his head that he himself was capable of bringing some pretty sophisticated analysis to the issue that had been presented to him. And knowing, perhaps it was instinctive, I don't know, but knowing anyway that this can't possibly be in the national interest for this to happen. And he blocked it. And that was that. And they were both furious and devastated, these two, the two CEOs, when they left the room. And I thought, well, I thought a lot of things.
Starting point is 00:16:20 I learned a lot from that. But it was another, it's another anecdote in the exercise of power that I'm sure has never been recorded anyway. Well, not publicly. It tells you a bit about the sort of person that Keating was. when he took a decision, he would be absolutely comfortable with the decision that he took. And he had that ability. He didn't always get it right. But I would say over the years that I spent with him
Starting point is 00:17:00 and working closely with him, and of course, even after I left his office, because he six months later became Prime Minister, I continued to work with him in a different capacity, obviously. But I rarely saw him take a poor decision. Now, he did take some, but it was rare. People tend to focus on those that were poor, and that's understandable. But amongst the plethora of huge decisions that he found himself having to take
Starting point is 00:17:39 on the basis of necessarily limited or incomplete advice. He was, in my view, he stands well above any other treasurer that I've ever come into contact with. Wow. Raises a couple of questions. One is, so he obviously left high school at the age of 14. Yeah. And that was sort of the end of his formal education.
Starting point is 00:18:10 Yeah. Didn't have any economics education. No. Learned it all on the job. Yes. And obviously, as you've described, had an incredible intuitive grasp of the economy. How far can intuition take you in economic policymaking?
Starting point is 00:18:28 Is it necessary and sufficient? Oh, it's certainly not sufficient. Is it necessary? Is it even necessary? Helpful. Certainly helpful. Good intuitive instinct is certainly helpful good intuitive instinct is uh is certainly helpful but then relying upon it to the exclusion of analysis and the exclusion of engagement with uh with advisors uh would be uh
Starting point is 00:19:00 very very dangerous i mean there's a lot of things that make good intuitive sense that I've seen in my career that are just nuts, you know, just nuts. And so you wouldn't want to rely on it. So is kidding the exception to that rule? Uh, in my, uh, I've seen others who have pretty strong intuitive grasp. So I wouldn't say that he was the exception, but I would say an absolute standout. Yeah, an absolute standout.
Starting point is 00:19:37 You know, but people's minds work differently, right? Some are extraordinary intuitive thinkers i had a um and i won't mention a name either but i had in the department uh as an advisor uh somebody who um these days is a very very wealthy highly successful person in the private sector, and has quite a profile. And he was working in the Treasury, and he was deeply, most days he was upset. I mean, deeply upset, like often in tears. And I spent quite a bit of time with him because he was clearly brilliant
Starting point is 00:20:27 and discovered eventually that the reason for him being upset was a frustration in... He saw it as a frustration in the capacity of people he was talking to to understand why he was right. Fair enough. And I saw it, I think the true, I think it would have been more honest of him to admit that his source of frustration was that he couldn't explain to others why
Starting point is 00:21:05 he was right. And we're talking about really complex stuff, right, without going into the subject matter. It was really complex stuff. And he could see the answer just like, no, bang, that's it. That's what you got to do. But he couldn't explain why. And so he was forever finding himself in heated arguments with other people who, you know, also had first-class honours degrees in several disciplines, if not PhDs, who, you know, had always been top of their class right through school and university and blah, blah, and who couldn't see what he could see and who would not accept that he had it right, and particularly because he couldn't explain why he had it right.
Starting point is 00:21:58 And it got to the point, you know, where I had a hunch that his, I don't know whether it's inductive reasoning powers. I'm not sure that that's what I was seeing. But anyway, I had a hunch that he was kind of, he was unbalanced in the sense that his intuition was really, really strong, but I had a suspicion that the linear analytical abilities were not so strong. Because after all, if they were, how come he wasn't able to explain it to other people whose minds work in that linear sequential sort of fashion, you know. And so I took one of the debates that he was engaged in and I produced the algebra and the calculus that, to me, constructed the formal argument that analyzed the thing. And I came to the conclusion that he was 95% right, which blew me away, actually, because I thought that's highly improbable. Like, I thought he might be 50% right, but he was 95% right.
Starting point is 00:23:24 And I gave it to him, and I said, look, could you just check this? And weeks went by and eventually he came back to me and again, he was in tears. And I said, I just don't understand what's wrong. And he said, I can't understand your mathematics. And I said, well, I don't understand. I just do not understand. How the hell on earth could you be capable of analysing this complex problem without being able to understand this, which to me was a relatively routine bit of analysis, you know?
Starting point is 00:24:13 And he said, well, I just can't, right? So, can you rely on intuition? He can. He's a fabulously wealthy person, done incredibly well. He can rely on intuition. Yeah. Would I want him to rely on intuition and run the country? I'd be a bit worried.
Starting point is 00:24:38 Okay. By the way, I think I know who this person is. We can talk about it afterwards. Okay. Right. Okay, right. Okay. Another reaction to your second anecdote about Keating. Your description almost reminds me of someone like an expert cellist
Starting point is 00:25:00 or pains or a basketball player in flow state. Yeah, like someone in flow state yeah yeah completely confident has almost a grace in what they're doing grace is a really good word yeah there was but it was almost like he'd made an art out of the use of power oh that is so insightful and I reckon that's dead right. And it did look graceful to me, even the brutality, there was grace in it. Even, yeah, and the way that he would wield that sword and the damage that he would do with it. There was artistry in it, theatre.
Starting point is 00:25:51 Yeah, and grace. And it's, you know, that comes through most of the things that he got involved in, because he wasn't involved exclusively in economic policy, right? I mean, a great appreciator of art and architecture, of history. His command of those disciplines too was, well, anyway, relied to a very large extent upon instinct and intuition. And if he were here, he would say it's all the same, mate. He would.
Starting point is 00:26:40 It's, you know, being able to see the big picture. He would say it's all the same. He would find that the sort of, the way that academics approach issues, where they find themselves getting narrower and narrower and narrower, and they say, well, of course, we need to in order to be able to dig sufficiently deep to make real progress. I doubt that he'd find that. I doubt that he'd even understand what they were talking about.
Starting point is 00:27:21 Yeah. For him, it's all about finding the the patterns and the truth is in the patterns did interacting with australian political leaders in canberra make you more or less inclined to believe in the great man or woman view of history uh but i guess you've got this dialectic between it's yeah people who influence history or it's like forces that shape history. So both. And we've had leading politicians who have said things like, the times suit me. And I think that's quite revealing.
Starting point is 00:27:59 And generally, I think when they have said it, it's been true um like they haven't said it just to inflate their own egos i think it's probably been true generally that the times have suited them but but of course the other way of putting that is that other times probably wouldn't have suited them there might have been absolute disasters at other times. And yet there are also leaders that we've had who were able to change the times to suit them, right? And I think Keating was in both camps. I think he was capable of taking, really maximising, maybe not maximising, maybe that's too strong,
Starting point is 00:28:48 but exploiting as much as anyone could possibly imagine, exploiting the opportunity presented by the times as they were. But then he was also capable of shifting the narrative, changing the narrative, you know, from like he created the debt and deficits narrative, right? He created that. That wasn't there. He created those times. And then he used what he had created to enormous effect,
Starting point is 00:29:25 to build support for extraordinary economic transformation or a set of policies that were going to produce and did produce an extraordinary economic transformation, right? Now, of course, it is likely that had he not cast the challenge in the terms he did, you know, the Banana Republic and so on, had he not done that, at some stage we would have found, Australia would have found itself in a crisis and having to make those big changes anyway. And so, you know, maybe you could argue that, well, he was only 10 years ahead of his time. Well, God, if only we had leaders who were 10 years ahead of their time, right? Now, the debt and deficits narrative was a sub-narrative of a broader narrative, which you termed the Australian mercantilism narrative.
Starting point is 00:30:18 Yeah. And Keating kind of unleashed both of them. Yes. They were effective in his time, but they've obviously plagued the Australian political discourse in decades since. Yeah, yeah, yeah. Can you just talk about the origins of those narratives, why he constructed them? Yeah. Yeah.
Starting point is 00:30:35 Okay. one um his his concern was that um having um taken big steps to open the economy up and and really the steps that that had been taken at that stage were to float the currency um and to abolish capital controls so to allow capital to flow into the economy and then, of course, to flow out of the economy. And he was – and so we had a bumpy ride, right? I mean, the economic outcomes, the macroeconomic outcomes were quite volatile in those years following those two things, floating the currency and abolishing, removing capital controls. And there was no, at least by 1986, which is when he made the Banana Republic statement, there wasn't a lot
Starting point is 00:31:43 to show for it right in terms of improved economic performance sure we'd come out of the recession but we're going to come out of the recession the drought had ended in early night in the early 1980s right um but things had not improved so much that the budget was showing any signs of getting back or getting anywhere toward balance. So we still had a big budget deficit. The currency was under continual downward pressure. We had what appeared to be a widening current account deficit. Should that have worried him? Look, I don't know, but it did.
Starting point is 00:32:23 I mean, he did worry about these things right um it didn't it wasn't part of a narrative that he could wasn't part of a nice positive narrative that he could construct right it was a was uh something that that really worried him and there was this uh concern I don't think he would I don't think he was the person who first articulated the concern about Australia's increasing reliance upon short-term capital inflows from offshore, particularly debt flows. But he was deeply uncomfortable with it, that Australia had, because it was continually running current account deficits, it was therefore relying upon the rest of the world to finance those current account deficits.
Starting point is 00:33:10 And a lot of the funding was coming in in the form of short-term debt financing. And if it wasn't coming in in the form of short-term debt financing, it was foreigners wanting to buy up property and, oh God another that's also not very comfortable and and um and he got it the way that he chose to frame it or frame the narrative was that at some point if we didn't get on top of this at some point australia would lose flexibility and maybe even sovereignty in respect of its economic policy settings. And so that it was better that we take matters into our own hands, take the decisions ourselves about how we were going to respond Being a small, open economy in a world of very large flows
Starting point is 00:34:09 of global capital and how we could insulate ourselves against the risks associated with that. And his answer, and look, he wasn't the only person who came up with this answer, and there were a lot of academics too who said you know uh or what you're talking about is a and this is true it's just a tautology you're talking about um a gap between national saving and national investment that's right so it's just a simple piece of arithmetic that the current account deficit is simply equal to the excess of national investment
Starting point is 00:34:46 over national saving. So maybe Australia's got a chronic saving problem, right? And that's in two parts. There's a public saving problem. Well, that was clear from the budget papers, right? Succession of budget deficits getting worse and worse and worse and worse. And we've also got a private saving problem. And it was true that household saving on international standards were pretty low. Of course, the irony is that in addressing his efforts to lifting public saving, i.e. reducing the budget deficit, and also to some extent lifting private saving,
Starting point is 00:35:31 although that really came later with superannuation, private superannuation. But certainly that first bit in fixing the, or appearing to fix the structural budget position, what do you know? Capital flows into Australia increased. And the capital flows were financing a spectacular investment boom because the rest of the world said, all of a sudden,
Starting point is 00:35:56 Australia's a great place to put your money, to invest in an enhancement of productive capacity, right? And so there were all these new investment opportunities that opened up in Australia. And that's his true legacy, in my view, on the economic front, is that we had this enormous investment inflow. And then even though there was a recession in the early 1990s, as we came out of the recession, it just kept powering on, right? And it powered on because
Starting point is 00:36:26 of the way in which he had educated the world or re-educated the world about the sort of place that Australia is and how they should think about Australia. Australia is actually a great place to invest. And the current account, deficit just widened and widened and widened, right, even though the budget deficit had closed. So deeply, deeply ironic, but nevertheless, and the narrative in and of itself is flawed, right? I mean, the debt and deficits thing. Well, it's incomplete, but it's seriously incomplete.
Starting point is 00:37:09 I mean, it's so incomplete that in the wrong hands it's deeply flawed. Let me put it that way. But nevertheless, and it did lie behind the extreme measures that were taken in the late 1980s or early 1990s that actually did tip the economy into recession. And, you know, there's no resiling from that. I don't think there's any resiling from that. Yet it is also true that it supported an extraordinary investment boom
Starting point is 00:37:38 that actually rebuilt the economy, restructured the economy, and allowed the economy to produce rates of productivity growth that hardly, through the 1990s, that hardly any other economy in the world had ever produced at any time, including us. Is the debt and deficits narrative not long for this world, given that as of 2019 we've been in a current account surplus? Well, no. So why are we in a current account surplus?
Starting point is 00:38:16 And the reason we're in a current account surplus is because investment has collapsed. That's the reason, yeah. And that's the problem. I mean, the problem, we shouldn't see this as a good thing. And would Keating see it as a good thing? Would he say, ah, you know, this is a triumphal moment for me. We've actually converted a current account deficit
Starting point is 00:38:39 into a current account surplus. I think if he were to, and I haven't had this conversation with him, but I'm pretty sure if he were to look at Australia's rate of business investment, he would be absolutely appalled. And he would understand that with the sort of business investment rates that we've got in Australia now, the sort of investment rates that, I mean, investment as a proportion of gross domestic product, so low. The only other times in our history that we've seen rates of investment this low is in the depths of recessions. And yet we've been here for years now with these investment rates. He would be appalled and he would understand that that's the principal reason for declining productivity growth in Australia, the undermining of living standards, the lack of growth of real wages.
Starting point is 00:39:25 He would get all that and he would be appalled by that. So he wouldn't regard it as a success story at all. He would want to see that investment rate lifted. Now, by the early 2000s, I think I had at the time, and I think all of my colleagues in official circles would have had a similar view, was that, look, provided you've got high-quality domestic policy, we took it for granted, right?
Starting point is 00:40:20 I mean, this is ridiculous, but we did. We did. Until the beginning of this century, we just took it for granted that we were always going to have high quality domestic policy settings, right? And an absolute commitment to first rate transparency with respect to policy setting and so on. We've got an independent central bank and all this kind of stuff. Provided you've got that, you don't need to worry about the rest of the world financing your current account deficit, even if it is going to increase to significant proportions of GDP from time to time.
Starting point is 00:40:58 Who cares? They will do it because you're such a good target, such a good place to invest, right, because you've got those wonderful policy settings. And that's what I thought. And I thought that I was thinking that right through to 2006, 2006 as part of a program of work that really began after the Asian financial crisis in 1997-98,
Starting point is 00:41:28 which really didn't affect Australia at all. And that kind of confirmed the view that, you know, well, our policy settings are so good, look, we didn't even suffer contagion in the Asian financial crisis. And actually, our economic performance during that period was so good that North American commentators, including very senior ones, started dubbing Australia the miracle economy. program run by the International Monetary Fund that came out of the interminable meetings that followed the Asian financial crisis, we in Australia received a visit from a very smart team of IMF officials. I remember I was a member of the Council of Financial Regulators at the time because I was Treasury Secretary.
Starting point is 00:42:27 It's a four-person council that's chaired by the Reserve Bank Governor. The Treasury Secretary sits on it. The Chairman of APRA and the Chairman of ASIC sit on this four-person council. And we had a preliminary meeting. It was like day one of this group being in Australia. And the mission leader said, look, and we'd supplied them with boxes and boxes of documents before they arrived in Australia.
Starting point is 00:42:53 So they were incredibly well briefed, you know. And he said, thank you for all the material you've provided. And I'm pretty sure, like I can't prejudge this, but I'm pretty sure that in six months' time when we come back and talk to you, we're going to say the Australian financial system is very robust, you know. You're doing everything right. But there's one thing that worries me.
Starting point is 00:43:22 Oh, what's that? He said, the one thing that worries me is your reliance upon short-term debt flows to finance what's going on in this place and it's all intermediated or largely intermediated by your domestic banking system and he said i don't actually quite know what to make of it, but it has me a bit worried. And I'm thinking, oh, he's a debt and deficits guy, right? That's what he is. Anyway, we politely wished him well and off he went. And six months later, he came back with his team and he said, well,
Starting point is 00:44:04 you know, this has turned out very much as I thought it would. Australian financial system is in really good health. You've got very well regulated institutions. Your regulators are world-class. You've adopted all these relevant international standards, blah, blah, blah. But there's one thing that worries me. And he said, after six months, it worries me even more. And that's your reliance upon short-term debt flows. So then we had a conversation about it. And I remember saying to him, let's think that through. So in what circumstances, so this is 2006, in what circumstances should we be really worried about that? We've done everything we possibly can in terms of policy settings
Starting point is 00:44:50 and institutional settings and so on. So in what circumstances would we have to worry about the fact that we are reliant upon this flow of capital from offshore, short-term debt, even if it is short-term debt. You know, why should we be worried about it? And we had a bit of a discussion about it, and I remember saying to him, I think what you're saying is that this is something we really should worry about if the global financial system collapses. And he just smiled, right?
Starting point is 00:45:27 And we just smiled at one another and had a bit of a chuckle, and that was that. But anyway, they printed the report in 2006, and it does, you can go back, you can dig it out, and it has that concern in it. It is in it. It's sitting in there saying that I'm a bit worried about it. That's 2006. And two years later, Lehman's collapses and bang.
Starting point is 00:45:55 And what do you know? That was our Achilles heel. That was the thing that was problem number one for us. And a huge problem was this reliance upon short-term capital inflows. It was the debt and deficits issue, recast, but nevertheless, there it was, was our Achilles heel. I have three specific questions about that FSAP report. Yep.
Starting point is 00:46:19 And then I'll come back to the narratives question. So the first question is, does it really matter if the debt isn't denominated in a foreign currency? Ah, you've got, okay. So we did see this as a big advantage for us that we were able to sell debt in Australian dollar, in Australian dollar debt, right? The issue, though, is that if the debt is denominated
Starting point is 00:46:55 in your currency, then at some point the interest rates you pay are going to reflect expectations of bilateral currency movements, right? So if the people lending you the money think, oh, there is a risk, a substantial risk that the Australian dollar is going to depreciate, right, then they will demand a higher interest rate, right, to cover the currency loss in the value of the asset that they hold, you know, debt for us asset for them.
Starting point is 00:47:23 So it can be reflected in interest rates. Of course, and the reason for your question is that there's no question about your ability to repay the debt in Australian dollar terms because you can always print money, right? Yeah, exactly. The Reserve Bank can be a lender of last resort. Correct, correct. But it can only – oh, well, look, if you were borrowing in US dollars,
Starting point is 00:47:47 to some extent the reserve bank could also be a lender of last resort, right, provided it's got sufficient reserves. But pretty soon it's going to run out of those reserves, right, of US dollars. So, and you want to avoid that. So it makes sense, obviously, to be able to issue debt in your own currency. So you are then in control of
Starting point is 00:48:06 the question of whether you can ever repay that and um creditors those lending you money they they can drive some comfort from the fact that they will uh get their money back but they're going to get it back in australian dollars and what are those australian dollars going to be worth and they may be worthless and And so, I mean, relative to the dollars that matter to them, which is generally US dollars. And so those, and so they, in order to protect their own interest rate, are going to be demanding higher and higher interest rates. And so that's how the cost is reflected. So
Starting point is 00:48:43 yeah, it matters. Yeah. My second question about the FSA report is to what extent is offshore wholesale borrowing still the key vulnerability of our financial system? Yeah. Yeah. And that's why I said in response to your earlier question that even though we're in a current account surplus position, I don't think we should be sanguine about the debt and deficits narrative. I mean, we've got to be careful about the way
Starting point is 00:49:16 in which we interpret it. The – one day, hopefully, our investment rate will bounce back. And when our investment rate bounces back, our reliance upon offshore capital, including short-term debt, is going to increase. Now, look, that doesn't necessarily imply that we're going to have the sort of extreme volatility ever again that we had in the global financial crisis. And it may very well be that, and I know, I mean, there were people, including in the Reserve Bank and very senior people in the Reserve Bank, who even in the middle of the global financial crisis said,
Starting point is 00:50:13 well, you know, it makes sense for the government to guarantee these debt lines as a form of insurance, but really are the capital markets going to remain closed for an extended period or is this just going to be a short-term thing until people sort out, you know, who they can trust and who they can't trust, you know? And as soon as they get around to figuring out who they can trust, they're going to look at Australia
Starting point is 00:50:38 and say, well, we can certainly trust them, right? Because they never miss a payment and, you know, look at their track record. But the general view taken at the time was that it was worth taking out quite a lot of insurance, even if the insurance was going to be expensive. Turns out it wasn't expensive for the budget at all. We actually made money out of it. But, I mean, would I be courageous enough to say
Starting point is 00:51:13 that we should never expect to see a repeat of anything like the global financial crisis, which at its core, it was all about counterparty risk or really about people's views on whether they could, the extent to which they could rely upon undertakings that were being given by their counterparties in the financial system. And they just lost confidence lost trust lost trust and it's trust that you know holds the whole thing together really i mean contracts of course but really in the in the moment it's trust when you're picking up the phone and doing a deal can you trust the person on the other end of the line um and that's what that's what fell apart really in the global financial crisis. Turns out the activities of governments were sufficiently swift and large as to be able to rebuild a sufficient level of trust in quite a short period of time,
Starting point is 00:52:25 will that always be the case? I don't know. And I just think that, well, I don't think we should assume that that will always be the case. And there is therefore, I think, a risk that's inherent in, well, you know, what I was going to say is that there's a risk that's inherent in a world of mobile capital flows. But even if you cut yourself off from the rest of the world, this risk of one part of the system losing confidence in another player in maybe the same part of the system or even a different part
Starting point is 00:53:13 of the system upon which they rely, that's still a fundamental question, right? So it's really at base how confident can you be that the claims being made by your counterparties and the undertakings that they're giving you that they can be relied upon? For the most part, it's been good, I mean, more than good, right? I think actually the ability of the global financial system and national financial systems to be able to, you know,
Starting point is 00:53:54 mediate flows of capital that go into building productive capacity and allowing people to buy houses and, you know, everything really, is an extraordinary success story for economics, really. But there is that fragility or is it a fragility? Anyway, look, there's a risk that's inherent in it and you can do a lot, of course, to manage that risk, but there will always be residual risk, always, sitting out there in the tail somewhere, right, that most times you can ignore.
Starting point is 00:54:35 It turns out you can safely ignore what's sitting out in that tail, but every now and again that tail is going to whip you. My third F'sSAP question is, by the time the financial crisis struck, only three of the 183 IMF member states hadn't completed their F-SAP. Yeah. And one of them was the United States. Yeah. How much would it have helped the US if they had that F-SAP report
Starting point is 00:55:05 or was the pain already baked in? They wouldn't have taken any notice of it because of the politics. Well, I don't know if it's – it's certainly not big P politics. There's, right, it is that the IMF, I think generally the IMF is incapable of criticising the United States in any meaningful fashion. Right. Well, at least it was. I don't know if that is still the case. So that's the first point.
Starting point is 00:55:41 Second point is, were the IMF to do so, I don't think the United States would have taken any notice. And why? Well, I just, look, I just think the domestic scene, and you can call it politics, the domestic political scene then in the United States is impervious to international criticism. And that's what this would have been seen, would have been seen as an international organisation taking a potshot at us. And I think that's generally true of international organisations, just the general.
Starting point is 00:56:14 I'm no expert on the psyche of the United States as an entity, if it's legitimate to talk about such a thing, but I think they're pretty impervious to international criticism, right? Maybe this is part of the, when people talk about US exceptionalism, maybe it's part of what they're talking about, is that the United States sees itself as standing apart. And there's, I mean, I delivered a speech at the ANU in 2004, which was a Bretton Woods sort of function.
Starting point is 00:56:54 And I reflected in this speech that on the history of the Bretton Woods institutions and what I saw as their declining effectiveness, in part it was a consequence of their own success, which is that, remember, when they were established, they were established in a world of fixed exchange rates. And the IMF and its principal lending programs were actually designed to forestall or deal with a balance payments crisis in a country
Starting point is 00:57:40 that's got fixed exchange rates, right? Where, as we were talking about before, it experiences capital outflow, and a central bank for some time can actually meet the outflow from its reserves, but then the reserves are drained very quickly. This is what we saw in the Asian financial crisis. You know, Bank of Thailand, I don't know how many days of reserves they had, but it disappeared pretty quickly, right?
Starting point is 00:58:02 And then the Thai bar just tanked. And when you move to a world of flexible exchange rates, it's just much less likely that anybody's going to need to rely on the International Monetary Fund for support, for financial support, because how do you have a balance of payments crisis in a world of flexible exchange rates? I guess it's possible, but it's just very unlikely. It's probably not the problem you're going to be dealing with.
Starting point is 00:58:33 And so did countries really, in this world of flexible exchange rates, did they really have to pay that much attention to what the IMF was saying? One of the good things about Australia was that in that period, certainly up to the global financial crisis, we were as a community, broadly defined, highly sensitive to international criticism, whether it was the OECD, the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank to some extent.
Starting point is 00:59:03 Not the United Nations somewhat deplorably, but anyway, I mean, that's, like, it criticises all they like about the treatment of asylum seekers and so on, and nobody seems to give a stuff. But if you're talking about financial matters, then Australia has historically been quite sensitive to that sort of criticism. You don't see it in a lot of other countries, but you most certainly don't see it in the United States.
Starting point is 00:59:27 So, yeah, you're right, the United States was one of only three. Anyway, in that 2004 speech, I said that, you know, I pointed out that there's no reason for the United States to take any notice of the IMF, and yet I said that, and this was true at the time, that the United States was, had become, the biggest debtor nation in the world, right? And it was borrowing from the rest of the world to fund its current account deficit.
Starting point is 01:00:05 And, of course, it was actually borrowing certainly more than half. And in some months, all of its borrowings were being funded by the People's Bank of China, right? So it was selling US treasuries to the People's Bank of China that was just rapidly building up huge stores of US treasuries. And I just said, and I thought it was kind of obvious, that the biggest risk to the global financial system right now
Starting point is 01:00:37 has to be the United States and the quality of its domestic financial system. That was in 2004. And the IMF had drawn attention to this earlier in 2004. This was not a novel proposition. It's just nobody took any bloody notice of it. And certainly in the United States, they didn't. But when I said it in Australia, a lot of commentators got stuck into me.
Starting point is 01:01:05 They said, what the hell are you talking about? Blah, blah, blah. It's unnecessarily alarmist. Anyway, it's not true. Blah, blah, blah. The United States should have been acting on its financial system fragilities through those early years of the 21st century. When I, after the collapse of Bear Stearns,
Starting point is 01:01:34 found myself accompanying Treasurer Swan on meetings in Washington and New York, so this was early 2008. It was before Lehman's collapsed. And I had, we had, we had, it was actually the Treasurer, of course, who was the principal interlocutor in the meetings, obviously, and I was there supporting, but I was absolutely amazed at the things I learned about the poor quality of US financial system regulation. I mean, absolutely gobsmacked.
Starting point is 01:02:04 And I did say to, and I remember we were walking down the steps of the Federal Reserve and I said to Wayne Swan, because we were reflecting on the rescue that the Federal Reserve had been instrumental in or had organised the rescue for Bear Stearns. And I said to Treasurer Swan, I said, God, heaven help the next US investment bank that gets into trouble. And he turned to me and he said, why do you say that? And I said, they're going to let it go.
Starting point is 01:02:41 They're going to let it go. And so when Lehman's got into trouble and they let it go, I was not at all surprised. You knew that because they'd been so defensive in the meeting? Hugely defensive. I couldn't believe how defensive. And, you know, I'm not going to name names of who we were talking to, but I could not believe how defensive they were.
Starting point is 01:03:06 And it was, anyway, I formed the view that they had been so beaten up over what they'd done by, I don't know, by whom, I have no idea. But anyway, so they were so shell-shocked they wouldn't do it again. Today, of course, they would do it again, right? I mean, I think they're different now. It's a different institution. But in those days, and you remember in the UK as well, I mean, it was Northern Rock that was earlier,
Starting point is 01:03:41 if my memory serves me correct. And before Northern Rock collapsed, you had Mervyn King as Governor of the Bank of England talking about the evils of moral hazard, right? And he was trying to get out. I think he was actually trying to get out ahead of all this. He saw that there was a possibility of financial institutions collapsing and he wanted to lecture the policymakers in the United
Starting point is 01:04:06 Kingdom. And I understand they took umbrage at this, small wonder, but he wanted to give them a lecture about the evils of moral hazard. And there were people in the United States who had a very similar perspective, were also convinced that moral hazard was such an evil that you had to be prepared to allow even systemically significant institutions to fall over, even if people's lives were ruined as a consequence. People had to learn, even if learning the hard way, about the risks that are involved in the economic system that we have
Starting point is 01:04:47 is gobsmacking. Before we move on, what if I grab your dog's blanket over there and hang it on the window so the sun's not shining in your eyes? It's kind of irritating, really. Do you want me to try something? Yeah, and while you do that, take a look at Ned. There he is. Oh, my God.
Starting point is 01:05:10 That's wonderful. Actually, it will probably move around that way because the sun will go in that sort of arc, won't it? No, no, no. I can move a little if that's okay. If I move this around. Oh, that's great. Yeah. I reckon that'll be fine for a while.
Starting point is 01:05:29 Yep. Oh, that's much better. Move as much as you like. You can take the mic with you. Oh, okay. To go back to the mid-'80s when Keating was constructing the Australian mercantilism narrative and the debt and deficits narrative.
Starting point is 01:05:45 Yeah. At the time, did you have any sense that these narratives would eventually metastasise? No. No, I didn't. No, no, no. Oh, God, now you make me feel really uncomfortable. So because I'm now asking myself the question, suppose I did,
Starting point is 01:06:08 what would I have done about it? And I was so impressed by what Keating was doing. I think if I'm to be honest with myself, I don't think I would have dissuaded him or sought, not that it would have been effective, but I don't think I would have sought to dissuade him from using it. Even though, even had I seen how it was going to be brutalized really by the Australian political system subsequently. I mean, that's, I've never reflected on that question before, so thank you for asking it. And I feel a bit uncomfortable answering it, but I think that is the truth.
Starting point is 01:06:50 I think, I mean, I don't, I'm not generally in the ends justify the means camp, not generally, because I think that so many of the things we regard as means are significantly important ends in their own right. Yeah, but I think I would have forgiven him this one. And I forgive him in retrospect. I mean, I don't think one should blame him for having constructed that narrative just because others have used it for base political purposes. What gives a politician a talent for crafting compelling narratives?
Starting point is 01:07:41 Because presumably it's not like smarts or intelligence isn't sufficient. So then plenty of very smart politicians who've failed miserably at this. What gives one the ability to be good at crafting political narratives? Again, I feel like I almost have to answer this question the way I imagine Paul Keating answering it. And I think he would say you've got to be a storyteller and you've got to be comfortable with telling stories. I mean, more than comfortable, you have to like telling stories. And it's more than being a raconteur.
Starting point is 01:08:38 It has to be stories that expose people's minds to things that, either things they would never have thought about or to thinking about things in a completely different way, in a way that they'd never thought about or to thinking about things in a completely different way, in a way that they'd never thought about them before. And he had the capacity to do that, right? To just completely wrong foot you, then to get you to think about an issue in a completely different way, and then to make you feel comfortable and safe again. And that's a really, I think it's quite an extraordinary ability, but if you're not drawn to the storytelling business,
Starting point is 01:09:20 then it's probably not a game for you. Actually, my younger brother said to me somewhat unkindly the other day, and he's a mathematician, a theoretical physicist, and he said to me somewhat unkindly, he said, and yet it's true, he said, is economics really anything more than storytelling? Well, it's probably not. Not really. Storytelling through models.
Starting point is 01:09:52 Yeah. Yeah, yeah. Storytelling through models, yeah. Yeah. Well, it's the models that give you some confidence that there's an inherent logic in the argument. Okay. Even though you have to accept that the model itself is going to be flawed.
Starting point is 01:10:05 I mean, it's going to be flawed necessarily in respect of scope because a model can't possibly incorporate everything that you see out there, and it would be of no use if you tried to construct such a model. But it's also going to be flawed in respect of the assumptions upon which it has to rely, right? And so it's necessarily going to be fought in those respects but even even accepting all of that it's the model that's going to give you some confidence
Starting point is 01:10:30 in the intellectual rigor of the argument but then you have to convert that formalized model into something which is uh a really compelling story, a story that grabs people's attention. And more than that, and it's not just a story. There's something quite unusual about these stories that we've been talking about, which is that you want the listener to become a part of the story as it unfolds. You're not telling an historical story.
Starting point is 01:11:08 You're not telling a story in history. You're actually talking about a story of, yes, the present, and to some extent the past, yes, but more importantly about the future. And you want these listeners to be a part of that story, players in that story, participants in that story, and feeling good about the development of that story as they go along. It's quite an unusual story telling quality, really, that is needed of our leaders. But it's always been true. I mean, I think it's always been true. I mean, I think it's always been true. And you go and read Shakespeare's words on the great leaders,
Starting point is 01:11:54 you know, on which he spent a lot of time, all flawed characters, of course. But nevertheless, their stories were largely about encouraging others to be part of a different future from the one that was actually confronting them, whether in the near term or the distant term. Yeah. That's really interesting. I mean, you're right.
Starting point is 01:12:20 That's what separates political narratives from history. Political narratives connect past, present, and future. That's right. Yeah, yeah. I want to ask you some questions about Treasury and the public service, but let me segue to that from narratives by asking this question. So traditionally there's been this distinction between the sort of work that a government agency like Treasury would do which is almost like the object
Starting point is 01:12:46 level policy analysis and then the storytelling aspect or the crafting of the narratives is left to the politicians to the government in recent years economists like bob schiller have started talking about the importance of narratives in economics as like something that should actually belong in the object level economic analysis. Yeah. Bob has a book called Narrative Economics. Yeah. Should Treasury actually be prepared to provide advice
Starting point is 01:13:17 to the government on economic narratives and which economic narratives will work? Yes. And my answer to that's unequivocal. Did that happen when you were in Treasury? Yes, it did. Yeah, it did. It did.
Starting point is 01:13:32 I mean, that's actually what motivated a lot of the work that we did on wellbeing, right? That was about us. I mean, we weren't asked to do that. Nobody said to us, oh, we'd like you to think about a wellbeing framework to guide the way that we, the government, think about economic, social and environmental policy. No, we constructed this wellbeing framework ourselves to be able to recast narratives that we presented to government in the expectation that the government would then change its own narrative or broaden its own narrative to deal with some really, really difficult issues. Think of entrenched Indigenous disadvantage, for example,
Starting point is 01:14:28 where, and that's not a success story, right, but the narrative did change. The narrative did change. I think it, I think, look, it did, I think without the change in the narrative, it would have been really highly improbable that the Closing the Gap narrative would have been constructed. I just don't think it would have. And the notion of, which has not been well respected,
Starting point is 01:15:02 but nevertheless is understood within government and has been for a long time, the notion of involving Indigenous people at the grassroots level in discussion of, sorry, policy design, the design of policies that will improve their circumstances. That notion, I think the wellbeing framework did make a contribution to that as well. Not that it's a novel notion. I mean, it certainly wasn't a novel notion at the time.
Starting point is 01:15:38 Many Indigenous leaders had been banging on about it for decades, right? It was just that there was a tin ear in Canberra, really, I think, until we started having those discussions about a broader framework for thinking about progress, economic, social and environmental progress, but particularly economic and social. And so, yes, I do think that should be a core competency of an economic policy agency. And that was my view at the time. I remember, here's an interesting thing I had shortly become what's called a band two SES officer
Starting point is 01:16:31 In most government departments in Canberra these days That position is referred to as a first assistant secretary In the military it's a two-star general, right? So that's the level we're talking about I mean in the army it's a two-star general Major general right so that's the level we're talking about i mean in the army it's two-star general um major general and um i attended a residential uh leadership course uh in i think was in bower if my memory serves me correctly it was five days and um one afternoon we had a fellow come in full
Starting point is 01:17:02 of uh enthusiasm with uh literature that had been that had come out of the Harvard Business School and it was all about strategic alignment. And he had this, and I don't know whether this, I don't know whether he was relying on any literature or whether this was just his own bright idea, but the proposition that he was putting to these relatively senior public servants was that we should think about strategic alignment in the same way that businesses think about strategic alignment. And of course, what he was talking about was businesses identifying their customer base
Starting point is 01:17:37 and then understanding everything about their customers. You know, what does it make some tick? If you want to be successful as a business, you've really got to understand your customers, right? These days it's called customer centricity. I mean, who would have thought, right? As if this is a really amazing idea. But then he was saying, and what that means is that in the private sector, that means you should think
Starting point is 01:18:04 about even your organisational structure in terms of how you can best match the personality. You can see where this is going, I suspect. But anyway, match the personality of your customers, right? And then he said, and that's how you should be thinking about your own departments. And he went into it, you know, you've really got to understand what makes the minister tick, everything about the minister.
Starting point is 01:18:41 And I was getting increasingly uncomfortable, right? There were 22 or 23 of us sitting around the table. At some point I put up my hand and I said, excuse me, what if your minister is an idiot? And, you know, he was uncomfortable. I think everybody in the room was uncomfortable, right? But seriously, what if your minister is an idiot? And then, look, actually he dealt with the question.
Starting point is 01:19:16 I thought I was surprised at how well he dealt with the question. But then I said, so are you saying, I said, sorry, let's take this up one other level, another level, right? So what then about the minister? How should the minister be constructing his or her own persona? I mean, who is their customer, right? Or is it even valid to think about a minister as having a customer or a set of customers for whom they are seeking to deliver high-quality product? And maybe it's the case that ministers are just responding in the main,
Starting point is 01:20:08 just responding to events. And this was, I know, quite a radical thing to say, but I said, is it never appropriate for a public servant, even a senior public servant, to go out into the public arena and construct such an event? The narrative for such an event anyway, right? Because maybe that is, in certain circumstances, the way to have maximum impact. In certain circumstances, maybe you should be seeking
Starting point is 01:20:42 to influence the truly external environment, the one in which both you and the minister are operating, right, and not just rely on a conversation between you and the minister as to what should be happening. And I think, I mean, I've got some support for that view subsequently, not in that room, not at that time. I think everybody said, not everybody. There was a rear admiral who thought it was quite
Starting point is 01:21:13 a reasonable proposition, although he didn't disclose that at the time. He disclosed it to me the following morning at breakfast when he said, I didn't realise how similar Treasury and Defence are until you made that comment. And I said to him, well, you shouldn't assume that this is Treasury speaking, this was just me. But it is a really... But subsequently, I think there was, at least for a period,
Starting point is 01:21:38 there was an acceptance of senior public servants having voice in the public square, provided they're not embarrassing the government, nor embarrassing the opposition, you know, not embarrassing the political players, but nevertheless, talking about the challenges confronting the country, and in general terms, about the sort of policy directions that would probably have to be followed if we were to avoid the risks the traps associated with with those challenges or make the most of the opportunities that those developments present for the nation there was there was some uh level of comfort with that i would say that during the 10 years of the former government,
Starting point is 01:22:25 there was no comfort with that, excluding in the national security and defence space, which is quite extraordinary. But I do think that's the case. And I think we lost a hell of a lot because of that. You see, one of the things, one of the deep flaws, is it a flaw? Let me talk it through, see if it's a flaw.
Starting point is 01:22:47 I think one of the deep flaws in our system of government is that we rely upon adversarial instruments for almost everything, right? So, oh, well, our political system is adversarial. Our legal system is adversarial. Our legal system is adversarial. Actually, the capitalist model is adversarial in its construction, right? That you've got businesses out there doing nothing other than seeking to maximize profit. It's up to the rest of us. Actually, that was the phrase that Milton Friedman used, right? The rest of us to use our agency as citizens in a democracy. He didn't quite use that phraseology, but that's what he was talking about,
Starting point is 01:23:28 to force these, oh, to elect politicians who would frame rules and regulations and would resource regulatory agencies and the judicial system such that it would force profit maximising businesses to operate in a competitive manner without fraud or deception being inflicted upon the public. that in its construction is adversarial. It sets the corporation up against the rest of us, right, and the rest of us having to get in there and muscle it. So much of it is adversarial. And one of the consequences of that is that the sort of institutions of civil society
Starting point is 01:24:27 that you necessarily have to rely upon to keep the political actors honest, or at least to call out the bullshit, is that they get seduced into reporting the contest rather than what is at contest, right? So they become no more than enthusiastic commentators of a gladiatorial spectacle, right? You even think about, as I have done and had to, the way that the Financial Services or Banking and Financial Services Royal Commission was constructed.
Starting point is 01:25:17 It became, and I think quite deliberately, a reality TV show. And what was reported overwhelmingly wasn't the substance of what was being discussed, but rather the arguments that were being put on either side and who performed better. So who won the gladiatorial contest? contest uh and you can understand why but you need to have uh a voice of the experts that's external from all of that and which precedes all of that that is calling out the bullshit when the bullshit is being espoused by the politicians or whoever they are, really, the redneck commentators or whoever, right?
Starting point is 01:26:12 And I think we've lost a lot of that. And maybe there's a lot of people who point to social media here and say, well, it's the fault of social media. It's just kind of oxygenated the place so much that considered analysis from respectable commentators and even considered reporting of what's going on by responsible journalists. It's just all too hard, you know. And, you know, that's probably true, but only to some extent. I remember even before I entered the public service when I was still a junior academic, I was a junior academic in New Zealand in the last years of the Muldoon government, right?
Starting point is 01:27:03 There was no social media. There was media. There were two publicly owned television stations, TV1 and TV2, right? And when Parliament was sitting, every afternoon when Parliament was sitting, Sir Robert Muldoon would call a press conference. There were two TV cameras in the room
Starting point is 01:27:19 and TV camera operators and maybe one or two or three journalists. And he would say something outrageous. And it would lead the evening news, both channels. So when New Zealanders were sitting down, tucking into their dinner, watching the evening news, they saw Sir Robert Muldoon saying something really outrageous but quite entertaining, usually highly divisive, you know, disparaging his opponents
Starting point is 01:27:48 and quite often disparaging Australians, by the way, because it worked really well in New Zealand. Punching up. Yeah, punching up. Exactly. And at the time I thought, you know, at the time I thought, this is just populist crap. How can these journalists allow, why do they even show it?
Starting point is 01:28:08 Right now, I know you showed it because he healed the purse strings, right? But actually, I think there's always been a temptation on the part of even good journalists to report on the punches being thrown more than the reason for the punches being thrown, right? So it's a real trap. And I think that in Australia over many years now, we've lost something that I think we once had. Maybe I'm just looking back with rose-tinted glasses, probably am, I think there was a time when we had media that were less inclined to be seduced by that kind of stuff and more interested in the substance of the issues. But we also had academics who were in the public place,
Starting point is 01:29:02 experts, I mean genuine experts, right, who were in the public place, experts, I mean, genuine experts, right, who were in the public space seeking to educate the public about these things. Now, we haven't lost that entirely. And publications like The Conversation have gone a long way. And I think, I mean, what you do, right, what you do in getting to the heart of the issues and not just the personalities, right? That kind of stuff, I think, is really, really important. And we need more of it, right, to hold this show together because there are dangers inherent in the adversarial contest
Starting point is 01:29:42 that really could blow the whole place up. This is what Trump was doing in the United States. Sure, he was being advantaged by social media. I would wake up, as you would, every morning in Australia, but in the probably 12 months or 18 months in the run-up up to the last presidential election, you would have woken up every morning to the lead story on the news being something amazingly ridiculous that Donald Trump had tweeted overnight, right?
Starting point is 01:30:18 The whole world was. I miss those days. Yeah, right. See, I think a lot of people do, right? They do miss it because of the entertainment in it. But here's the thing. So Robert Muldoon thing tells me that even without social media, you would have been waking up to that stuff.
Starting point is 01:30:36 He would have found a way of getting it on the TV cameras and we would have got it. If it's sufficiently outrageous, we would have got it, right, because people are just so drawn to the drama and the theatre and the, you know, as much as they say, oh, I hate politicians, they love the entertainment content in the political argument. And then the last thing I'll say on this point, well, I should never say it's the last thing I'll say, but you know what? I have had very senior ministers open up to me and tell me things as troubling as, you know what?
Starting point is 01:31:16 I've never had any interest in policy. The only reason I came into parliament was because I was a good barrister and I enjoy the argument. Because if you're going to have that sort of adversarial system where what's valued is the perceived quality of those engaged in the combat, those are the people who are going to be drawn to it, right? Think also of the dumbing down of debate that you get when interviewers, unlike what you do, because you've let me rabbit on and on and on and on, but when interviewers say, look, we're about to go to a break, by which they mean we're about to earn
Starting point is 01:32:08 some money from advertisers, we've only got a few seconds. I'm going to ask you a really complicated question, and I want you to give me a three-word answer. And what are you going to get? Well, you're going to get a three-word slogan and small wonder that eventually australia ends up with a politician like tony abbott right what do you expect um so there are real risks in this and we've got to be alive to those risks and we've got to make sure that the other institutions of society are capable of and really do contribute to a better informed public. And I do think that leaders of public institutions,
Starting point is 01:32:59 including institutions like the Treasury, do have a role to play here. That comment that Minister made to you is disturbing. For me, it's also indicative of this kind of culture of individualism that emerged in the West beginning around the 1970s where now you have this whole class of politicians for whom a seat in parliament is a prize rather than a responsibility. Sure. That's the goal.
Starting point is 01:33:28 Yeah. Yeah, yeah. And hanging on to it at all costs is the goal. Yeah. No matter how many deals you have to do with the devil. Yeah. And regardless of what policy you actually get done. Yeah, yeah.
Starting point is 01:33:41 A few more questions about the public service. Yeah. A few more questions about the public service. So when I was preparing for this conversation, I read a Canberra Times article about you from 2006 that mentions you putting in 100-hour weeks at the Treasury in the 80s and the 90s. Yeah. And it also mentioned this anecdote about how in the mid-80s you would slip a tax draft under your division head,
Starting point is 01:34:02 David Morgan's door at like 3am. Yeah. By 8am, he's up and he's read it and responded to it. Yeah. $100 a week is a lot. Yeah. Was that A, something unique to treasury because it's got things like budget week it has to deal with, B, something unique to the reform era and the sort of esprit de corps of the
Starting point is 01:34:23 80s and 90s, C, something unique to senior officials or D, something unique to the reform era and the sort of esprit de corps of the 80s and 90s, C, something unique to senior officials, or D, something unique to Ken Henry? B and A, and probably in that order. Wow. Because I was not unique. It certainly was not unique. There were a team of us who were working those sorts of hours.
Starting point is 01:34:46 And look, not all the time, obviously. I mean, you can't work those sorts of hours all the time and survive for very much time. But there were several times in my treasury career going for several months at a time when, yes, I did work those sorts of ridiculous hours. And the only reason I know it's 100 hours is that during the 1985 process when, you know, I referred to this earlier where there was just maybe a bit more than one handful of policy officers
Starting point is 01:35:20 who were working on the content of what became called the Draft White Paper on Tax Reform. officers who were working on the content of what became called the draft white paper on tax reform. And at some point, Paul Keating, observing the sort of hours that we were working, said to somebody more senior than me in the department, are these people getting paid any overtime? And actually, I don't know if you know this, but at a certain, once you reach a certain level in the public service, you don't qualify for overtime. Anyway, we were all at that level.
Starting point is 01:35:48 No, there was one person in our group who was below that level, but all the others were at that level or above. So we didn't qualify for any overtime at all. And so the answer was, oh, well, actually, no, I don't think any of them are being paid overtime. And he wasn't aware of how many hours we were working, but he knew that it was ridiculous. And so somebody senior in the department said, well, I think you'd better keep timesheets for the next three months. Keep timesheets, right?
Starting point is 01:36:18 And we'll see if we can do something. We're not compelled to do anything. You don't deserve overtime. But we'll see if there's something that we can do. And that was when I, and so I did. And then I trotted it all up and over the three month period, it averaged a hundred hours a week. And that was, ironically, and I should have been smarter. I should have figured this one out. But, of course, when you calculate how much overtime I would have been entitled to for that three-month period,
Starting point is 01:36:50 it was larger than my annual salary, right? So it was so big that I didn't get a cent. I should have been smarter, right? I should have said I was 70 hours, you know, or 60 hours. Even 45 hours, I would have got something. Yeah. But at 100 hours, I got nothing, right? But during budget week, or more than budget week,
Starting point is 01:37:13 during the run-up to the preparation of the annual budget, there are people who do work those hours in Treasury. Yes, there are. And then at particular times like that 1985 tax summit, yeah, it does happen. And it's, of course, it's not appropriate, right? And yet there is something in it that speaks volumes about the sort of organisation that that place is, at least was, and I'm sure still is.
Starting point is 01:37:50 And there isn't a spread of core in it. And look, some politicians are working those sorts of hours too, right? I mean, most people have no idea of the hours that politicians work. And maybe it's not all work either. I mean, maybe it's not all what you and I would regard as being worthwhile work, but it is part of their job.
Starting point is 01:38:11 Or they won't survive in their job if they don't do it. And so that kind of stuff does happen. But, I mean, it's also true, the D is also true because I could have opted out, you know, obviously. And I could have said this game's not for me. And, of course, there were times when I had that feeling, of course, but you go on and it's for the reason that I mentioned in answer to your very first question, you know, it's just those periods
Starting point is 01:38:40 are just a blast, an absolute blast. And you are full of adrenaline and you just go on and on and on. And, you know, it's probably both a good thing and a bad thing that humans are capable of, that sort of thing. You see it all over the place, not just in policy development, right? And sometimes it's for the good and sometimes it's actually for the bad. So, Ken, you can correct this if it's wrong, but I heard a story that you famously wrote Prismod in 1991
Starting point is 01:39:17 on about 20-odd sheets of paper one night. And those sheets of paper may have even been a translation from like the back of a coaster or a napkin um you know hastily hastily written on uh late one night in a canberra restaurant is that is that anecdote correct and how much of policy happens like that um you know like a brilliant public servant just kind of whipping something up versus like a slower, more formal process? I don't know the answer to that question.
Starting point is 01:39:48 Oh, sorry. The first part of the question, that's broadly correct. It's the architecture of Prismod. Of course, Prismod is a huge model. It ended up being the, I think the OECD certainly described it as the most detailed economic model that had ever been constructed. It probably was.
Starting point is 01:40:10 But there's a reason for that, which we can go into if you want to, but it doesn't really matter for this question. But so it's broadly correct, the architecture. How much of what happens in policy circles happens like that? Yeah, I really don't know. But I do, I mean, I've seen enough instances of people having brainwaves and those brainwaves subsequently translating into big things that, you know, I can say it happens a bit. It probably doesn't happen enough. into big things that, you know, I can say it happens a bit,
Starting point is 01:41:09 probably doesn't happen enough. I mean, it's easy to say that the public service is structured in such a way that it has insufficient flexibility and gives people insufficient authority to be able to behave in that manner. That's probably true, but it certainly wasn't true of the Treasury, not from the day I first joined it. One of the strengths of that institution was that you could be a, well, you could be a graduate recruit and you could have an idea that challenged orthodoxy
Starting point is 01:41:47 and you could expect people to take notice of it i mean they might tell you it's complete crap you know and go away and grow up and that's also part of what well was was a strength of the department was that um whether you're going to be listened to or not whether notice is going to be taken of your idea or not dependent upon rank not at all i mean just not at all so um i mean i hope that's still true but but it was true. And, yeah, I saw enough of those people having a brainwave and things happening as a consequence to know that it is quite a feature of or was, has been quite a feature of public policy. So Prismod took you and about five other people about five months to build.
Starting point is 01:42:48 How long would such a project take nowadays? And what was the main constraint back in 1991? Was it software, hardware? Oh, actually, I think it would take longer now. Really? Yeah. Because I don't think people would work those hours. But also that, I mean, even when that project was launched, those launching it knew and everybody involved in it knew,
Starting point is 01:43:15 all five of us knew that this was just quite unreasonable, right? I mean, you couldn't, you wouldn't have been able to. John Caron gave you about four months. Yeah. Yeah, and that was in a, you know, a written document. I mean, it was a letter to the secretary to say this is what I want and I wanted to have this capability, blah, blah, blah, blah, blah. Now, look, in truth, we could have done a slimmed-down version
Starting point is 01:43:49 and we could have achieved, well, I guess, an acceptable outcome in a less stressful way, but, uh, several of us, several of us, the total was five, um, a couple of us had been involved in, um, uh, a similar sort of exercise back in 1985. And we were aware, we carried scars from the, I've used this word a lot today, but brutality of the battles that were fought around the modelling that we had done back in 1985. And having survived that experience, we were determined that what we produced in 1991 would be technically unassailable, that nobody would be able to say, this is shonky, you've cut corners, you've ignored blah, blah, blah.
Starting point is 01:45:10 And so, you know, the data demands were absolutely immense. A lot of data, what you would call data, had to be constructed from scratch. So, I mean, think about this, right? Maybe this is one way of describing the challenge. So, imagine a matrix that's got 109 different industries identified. So, that's your columns, 109. Yeah. And then it's got 1,400 rows.
Starting point is 01:45:48 And those rows identify commodities that are purchased by those 109 industries. So 1,400 commodities purchased by 109 industries, right? That's got some scale. That's big. And then you just say to somebody, and this is in the days before the GST, so we had, I think at the time it was the world's most complex indirect tax system, multiple rate wholesale sales tax, excises,
Starting point is 01:46:21 and these things were not just levied at final point of sale, right? I mean, wholesale sales tax is obviously not. excises and these things were not just levied at final point of sale right i mean hostess hostex obviously not um so they applied to industry purchases of commodities of products and uh we had to know with some level of precision how the wholesale sales tax revenue was distributed across all those cells, right? Well, nobody would have done that before, and why the hell would they, right? It took months for a couple of people.
Starting point is 01:47:00 It was only a couple of people because we couldn't afford any more in terms of resources. It took them months to get their head around that question. And it's just a, I mean, you could say, well, it's just a statistical exercise. But they had to do it with a high level of precision. It had to be unassailable. And, of course, what they discovered, I mean, they discovered all sorts of things like we should be collecting more household sales tax revenue. If the base is really that big, then how come we're not collecting enough household sales tax revenue? And then in other cases, we're getting more household sales tax revenue than that um that suggests that the
Starting point is 01:47:46 the abs's input output data are wrong uh and so we had this toing and frying with the abs and they did amend the input output data on several occasions because of this exchange it just doesn't make sense we can't make sense of this. So we ended up creating data sets that had never previously existed, and we ended up helping the ABS revise. I'm not saying a complete transformation, don't get me wrong, but nevertheless revise, in important ways, data sets that had been around for quite a while. Now, it probably helped us that one of the members of the team, and indeed a fellow who,
Starting point is 01:48:32 a very close colleague of mine, unfortunately now deceased, but who went through the 1985 exercise. We sat shoulder to shoulder working those 100-hour weeks through the 1985 exercise, and he was also a member, key team member of this exercise. And at an earlier time in his career, he had spent 10 years as head of the input-output section in the Australian Bureau of Statistics, and he actually compiled Australia's first ever input-output tables. And that is, I mean, it's just chance, right?
Starting point is 01:49:10 Just extraordinary. Actually, to clock back a bit, because this is, I think this is actually part of the answer to your question or maybe your earlier question, but in the 1985 exercise, we needed to answer questions like this. Well, suppose you replace the household sales tax with a broad-based consumption tax that applies in the following way at the following rate with input taxing of certain transactions
Starting point is 01:49:40 in these places, these places, these places, zero rating or exemption in these places, these places, these places, Zero rating or exemption in these places, these places, these places, right? Adjustments to excises and blah, blah, blah, blah, blah. Now tell me what happens to the CPI. Mm-hmm. Well, nobody had ever done anything like that before. And the task was handed to one person because we were a small team, right?
Starting point is 01:50:00 And this guy, he was given the task because he had previously worked in the Australian Bureau of Statistics at some stage in the National Accounts area, I think. He then went on to become quite a good journalist years later. And he spent weeks nutting his head through this and he produced a piece of paper that was more than 50 pages in length. It was probably 55, I think that's from memory anyway. And I saw this and I thought, oh, my God, you know, this is, well,
Starting point is 01:50:29 firstly, poor bugger, and then secondly, so now we're going to be asked, well, hang on, what if I tweak this right here and tweak that there and tweak, then what happens? So we're going to have to wait another three weeks while this poor bugger goes through all of this again and produces his workings manually, you know. And I thought and I said and I went to this colleague who I knew had worked in the input-output section in the ABS and I said,
Starting point is 01:51:02 you know what we need here is what in economics is referred to as a price input output model. I've never seen one except in the textbooks. I don't know if one even exists anywhere in the world, but that's what we need and that's what we need to construct. And he just beamed at me, right? And he said, oh, well, you know, I suppose, he said, I suppose I do know more about the Australia's input-output system than anybody else. So maybe we could give this a go. That was back in 1985.
Starting point is 01:51:38 But see, had he not been there and had I not had that, I'd call it an insight, but, I mean, it's, you know, it was, it's not that big an insight, but, and then ask the question and then get the engagement from him, which was like, you know, it was enthusiastic, like, let's give this a go, right? Then I think maybe that poor bugger would have been, you know, every time he would have said, well, this is going to take weeks and destroy my life for several weeks.
Starting point is 01:52:11 And actually it wouldn't have worked. It just wouldn't have worked. So there is something of chance in these endeavours, I think. You can't, and you can't plan for it. No, you can't plan for it because you don't know what bit of kit, what bit of technology you're going to need to answer the policy question in a way that will provide the politicians with what they need to be able to run the argument, construct the narrative,
Starting point is 01:52:48 convince the parliament, you know, all of that kind of stuff. You just don't know. It's a fascinating glimpse into how policy gets made. Yeah. It's also interesting that there are these decisions that affect the wealth of nations and they're based on the policy and the advice that the public service provides. And ultimately, you can trace that back to one guy kind of hunched
Starting point is 01:53:13 over his desk working 100-hour weeks. No, it's true. And it all kind of hinges on the quality of his work. Yeah. Or her work. Or her work. All right. But that is true.
Starting point is 01:53:26 Yeah. It her work. All right. But that is true. Yeah, it is true. I learned a fact about you when I was preparing for this conversation, and that is that you're colorblind. And I wondered whether that ever caused any issues when you were reading charts as Treasury Secretary. You are too well briefed secretary you are too well briefed you are too well briefed yeah and i know this became something of a running joke particularly during the global financial crisis when there's like a red and a green line or something magenta
Starting point is 01:53:55 magenta okay uh magenta was the color that i settled on um to highlight uh i wasn't even aware that such a color existed because being colourblind, well, why would I? But in having charts prepared for me to look at and then think about presenting to Kevin Rudd in particular and Wayne Swan, you know, that group in the global financial crisis. People got to learn that there were particular colours that they had to use. So there was a colour.
Starting point is 01:54:34 I know they developed a colour palette for me. Bizarre. But anyway, but it worked for me. I could see these colours and the most outstanding of which was this, it looked iridescent, but magenta colour. And I know Kevin Rudd, at some point, he said, why, why, why this colour? You know, and we had a bit of a joke about it.
Starting point is 01:55:03 So he, yeah, for years afterwards, he'd rib me about the Magenta line on the chart. The Magenta line was always the one that I wanted to emphasise. So it was the one that I wanted anybody in the audience to take most notice of. I have no idea whether it stood out for them the same way it stood out for me. I haven't know.
Starting point is 01:55:26 Two more questions about public service. And then I want to ask about recession and financial crises. Yeah. So when Terry Moran was appointed Secretary of the Department of Prime Minister and Cabinet in 2008, he said, and I'll quote him here, I've had a fortunate career, having often been in jobs where I've been able to make a difference. It's not been about boring administration, but about improving things. The Benthamite concept that the role of government is to achieve the greatest good for the greatest number, end quote. And it got me wondering, I'm not sure whether you have thought
Starting point is 01:56:06 about this, but does the Australian public service have a uniquely utilitarian atmosphere or are all public services in Anglosphere countries naturally quite utilitarian? So I think most are, even those that don't think about it. But no, the public service doesn't have that as a philosophical framework, even though great chunks of it do. And look, most people in the Treasury would certainly start with a utilitarian, indeed even welfarist perspective, you know, just a sum ranking of outcomes to assess the relative merits of different policies or different policy options and also to assess things like the big question, is human progress improving or is it not improving?
Starting point is 01:57:06 Yeah. And I have a lot of time for utilitarians and I've got a lot of time for that perspective, but it's not my perspective. I think that, for example, I think that there is a case for, in exceptional circumstances maybe, but these exceptional circumstances are always present, of improving the circumstances of the most disadvantaged in society, even if you cannot demonstrate
Starting point is 01:57:40 that that lifts the sum total of utility across society. I mean, and maybe that's, and there are a lot of utilitarians, I'm sure, who would be jumping up and down listening to this saying, well, that's just ridiculous because you can't even conceive of such an intervention, namely something that would improve the lot of the most disadvantaged and would not also result in an increase in aggregate utility. But I'm not sure that that is the case, and I wouldn't want to constrain my thinking to possible policy interventions that had to satisfy that test.
Starting point is 01:58:36 The reason I ask is some people think that Australia has a uniquely utilitarian or benthamite political ideology sort of embedded in our political DNA from the days of Chartism and the Harvester Judgment. Yeah, yeah, yeah. It really is powerful in Australia and maybe more powerful in Australia than in other places. And by the way, one of the other, and this is not by the way,
Starting point is 01:59:03 actually one of the really attractive features of that is that people don't get so hung up on uh concepts of procedural fairness like you know rights and liberties and things like that and and storm the barricades if um you know if their individual personal liberties have been infringed in some arguable way, that's a real attraction of the utilitarian discipline is that you're just, you're focused on the outcomes rather than, so you're focused on the ends rather than means, if you like, to go back to something I was talking about earlier, and you are not going to be distracted by, or you're not going to allow concepts of procedural fairness to interfere.
Starting point is 01:59:58 But then on the other hand, you're on a slippery slope, I think, or at least my view, and I don't want to insist on this, and I don't think I've ever insisted on it, but my own view is that there are some aspects of a rights-based approach that are just, in some circumstances, so foundational, so fundamental, that if they were not delivered by a system that was just focused on some ranking and the aggregate sum of individual utilities, then the society might well be breeding the seeds of its own destruction. And I mean, the most obvious thing to say there is that you've got to be worried about distributional consequences and not just aggregate. And you can't draw comfort from the fact that, well,
Starting point is 02:01:19 you can draw some comfort from the fact that the aggregate condition is improving and that the majority of people are getting better off. You can draw some comfort from that. But you've got to allow yourself to be embarrassed by or bugged by the fact that some people really are missing out and may be missing out for generations maybe. maybe, and that it is incumbent upon people with policy responsibilities to pay particular attention to those cases, right? I think so. But, yeah, but there is a strength.
Starting point is 02:02:06 Look, yeah, I don't want to be too critical of those who are firmly wedded to utilitarianism because I think it has enormous strengths. I mean, I think in many ways governments have to be, people almost expect their government to be utilitarian. I think they do. Yeah, yeah, yeah, I think they do. I think in many ways governments have to be, people almost expect their government to be utilitarian. I think they do. Yeah, yeah, yeah. I think they do.
Starting point is 02:02:28 I think they do. And that's, look, it's got to be a hell of a good starting point, right? I mean, it's better than anything else that I can imagine. Yeah. It's just that I want them to be particularly focused in particular areas and not allow themselves to get relaxed by what's happening to the average or the majority or whatever. Yep.
Starting point is 02:02:56 So many biographies have been written of political figures in Australia. Is there anyone in the public service, living or dead, who would be befitting of a 700-page recollections of a bleeding heart style biography? Are there any public servants who we need to know about? I don't know. One of the issues here, and it is actually quite problematic, is that, you know, when I left the Treasury, of course,
Starting point is 02:03:38 well, not of course, but I did have a number of publishers contact me and say, oh, oh, oh, would you like to write a memoir? And I know other senior public servants have been asked the same question. And I assume the same reason. And I assume that what would sell such a memoir is a lot of stuff that would titillate people and, well, maybe I'm being unfair, but, you know, things that are more about the theatre or the contest than the substance. But also, even when it's dealing with the substance of issues,
Starting point is 02:04:38 what would interest people, and understandably, is, well, what did you advise and how was that advice treated? What was the response of the responsible minister? And I said to the treasurers that I worked for that understanding the difficult position that this could place them in down the track, I said to them, I will never write a record of this. I'll never write a memoir of this exchange. You know, you don't have to worry about my ghost coming back to haunt you at any time. And without, because I felt that there has to be a very high level of comfort in the confidentiality of the exchange.
Starting point is 02:05:22 Now, I've told you a couple of anecdotes, but not anecdotes, I think, that would, and I hope, certainly hope, would not embarrass any particular minister. And I just wouldn't do that. I mean, anecdotes come out of those sorts of private exchanges that are had in absolute confidence, right? And I feel very strongly about that. So I think that aspect of the engagement between
Starting point is 02:05:54 or the nature of the engagement between advisors and those charged with taking decisions, yeah, I think, I just don't think that that should be exposed in books. So then the question that's left is, well, what is there left to write about? And, of course, there's personal stuff. But how important is that? I mean, I think even for politicians,
Starting point is 02:06:33 it's taken on an exaggerated level of importance. Certainly, the public has a right to know, I think, something about the personal lives of politicians. But there's a level beyond which it gets embarrassing for all concerned, I think, and certainly distracting. Well, it may be diverting, but it gets distracting. Yeah. So speaking of recollections of a bleeding heart,
Starting point is 02:07:15 in that book, there's this passage where Don Watson quotes Don Russell saying that from the treasurer's office, he had heard the economy snap like a neck in 1990. The recession we had to have finished before I was born. What are your personal memories of the beginning of that recession? Wow. Yeah. So. Wow. Yeah. Wow. There were not many people in Paul's office at the time.
Starting point is 02:07:51 It's not like, you know, those political officers, well, sorry, political is the wrong description. That's the wrong adjective to use. Those Parliament House officers are not staffed, sorry, were not staffed in the way they are now. So there weren't many people who have a lived experience of that and Don is certainly, he was much, much closer to it than anybody else in the office.
Starting point is 02:08:22 He and Paul were, I mean, the weight was very much on their shoulders in respect of how to deal with that piece of news. It had been, even before that particular national accounts figure came out to confirm the two negative quarters, of course, well, once we got the first negative quarter, there was a higher risk of a successor. But in the quarters leading up to that first negative quarter, I mean, we knew there was a significant risk that the economy would go into a recession. The policy action that had been taken was pretty extraordinary, right? On top of the fiscal tightening, which was being done for structural reasons, not for macroeconomic reasons. We weren't tightening the budget in order to, well, not principally in order to dampen domestic demand. That wasn't the principal purpose of it, except in a structural sense.
Starting point is 02:09:37 We did want to rebalance private and public net savings balances. But that was a structural thing. It goes back to the conversation we were having earlier about the current account and the contributors to that current account, and the response to it featured very heavily the twin deficits proposition that was part of that debt and deficits narrative. But the monetary policy response was, you know, just huge.
Starting point is 02:10:10 And it's well documented that Paul played a key role. I mean, he says it himself, he played a key role in the determination of the interest rate increases that occurred during that period in the lead-up to the recession. And Don was very much a part of those conversations with Paul. So they knew that this was an increasing risk. I've certainly heard that expression that they heard it snap like a, did you say a neck? Yeah.
Starting point is 02:10:53 I thought it was a stick. But anyway, that doesn't matter. Maybe it does matter. There's quite a distinction between those two. Oh, hell, that's a bit gruesome, really. Yeah. Oh, hell, that's a bit gruesome, really. Yeah, so sitting where I was in the office with primary responsibility for micro and structural stuff rather than macroeconomic stuff. I mean, not that I was excluded from the macroeconomic discussions.
Starting point is 02:11:21 It's just that I was not as intimately involved as Don was, Don Russell. I didn't have that sense, although I certainly had a sense that the place was at risk of slowing very, very, very sharply. And, you know, we did have discussions in the office before the event about the macroeconomic policy structure and the risks that we were taking. And those were open enough conversations, several advisors with Paul. You know, Paul, this is getting close. Like, I mean, you know, this could happen.
Starting point is 02:12:09 Is it wise to keep tightening? Should we back off a bit, you know? And it's a metaphor, of course it's a matter of a judgment, but also when Paul said in that first press conference that this is a recession Australia had to have, of course he was pilloried for it, and of course people thought he was being completely insensitive. But if you recall that anecdote that I told you right at the start
Starting point is 02:12:51 when he told one of his cabinet colleagues in 1984 who was sweating on decisions that he'd taken, mate, maybe this is not the place for you, maybe it's time for you to go. There is something in the assessments that Paul makes and the way he communicates them in the moment that can come across as quite brutal and uncaring, but in respect of both of those, I would argue that one should look a lot deeper
Starting point is 02:13:21 into what lies behind those comments. And in the years following, quite a few people came to the view that Australia would not have achieved the economic restructuring that it achieved in the absence of a truly deep recession, as ugly as it was. And I'm not saying that excuses it, but it nevertheless may well be an accurate analysis that the high productivity growth that Australia enjoyed through the 1990s and the big change or restructuring of the economy that occurred as we came out of the recession of the 1990s might not otherwise have happened.
Starting point is 02:14:13 And so I think actually where most economists would sit is they'd say, it's probably a bit of a cop-out, right? Which is that, well, hang on a second, you should find other ways of achieving that massive economic restructuring. You shouldn't have to rely on a recession. But I think they would also admit that in the absence of that recession, at that time, we would not have achieved such a rapid restructuring of the economy hmm I remember reading that you were haunted by one particular statistic that emerged from that recession and that was that more than something like 50% of men above the age of 45 who lost their jobs, just never returned to work. Never worked again.
Starting point is 02:15:05 Yeah. Which is crazy. I mean, not to put too fine a point on it, but that book I mentioned to you I'd been reading before we started recording, Wellbeing, Science and Policy, that Daniel Kahneman recommended to me at the end of the podcast I did with him. In the introduction, they mention the importance of employment
Starting point is 02:15:28 and they note that workers who lose their jobs suffer in life satisfaction on a scale comparable with the death of a spouse. Yeah. Yeah. It was brutal. It is brutal. It is brutal. It is brutal. It is brutal. And, yeah, that's haunted me for a very long time.
Starting point is 02:15:57 And it was certainly playing on my mind during 2008. Yeah. You know, actually my father is now deceased, and actually died 18 years ago. But in that period, in the late 1980s, as we were having these discussions in the office, I did say to him, look, this economy is just going nuts, you know, and it was. I mean, we were just having this extraordinary boom in the late 1980s. Inflation was one consequence of it, but it was only one consequence of it. The place was going absolutely nuts. And I said, you know, maybe it is the case that the only thing
Starting point is 02:16:51 that's going to stop this is a recession. Maybe that's unavoidable. And he said to me, and it stuck with me, particularly in the months that followed, he said, nothing excuses a recession. You can't allow yourself to think like that. My father was not an educated person, right? I mean, he left school at 13 and was a timber worker almost all his life. But he had that sense and had obviously seen it of colleagues
Starting point is 02:17:25 of his who had lost their jobs and, you know, just destroyed their lives, destroyed it. That was it. And they lost the capacity, not just the opportunity to find another job, but they lost the functional capacity to go and look for another job, but they lost the functional capacity to go and look for another job. They'd just been so devastated by the experience. I mean, I don't know if it's like many of those who went to war and were not functional
Starting point is 02:17:55 when they returned from war, but it's something like that, I think, the trauma that people suffer and the loss of, there are just so many elements of loss, aren't there? You know, loss of respect or self-respect and, you know, loss of, yeah, certainly loss of pride in what they're doing for their families and so on, you know. Truly devastating. And I was, and it's actually why, and it's no wonder that Julia Gillard made a point of it subsequently, but I do remember on the, when was it? It was the second weekend, second Saturday in October 2008,
Starting point is 02:18:51 when those four ministers met with the first serious discussion about response to the collapse of Lehman Brothers. Wayne Swan was in Washington, so he joined by phone, but the other three, Julia Gillard, Lindsay Turner, and Kevin Rudd were in the Cabinet Room. And she went straight to that point. She said, we cannot allow this to happen. And for that reason, and, you know, it hit me like a punch in the guts
Starting point is 02:19:27 because it was, it had not been up to that point part of my advice to to kevin rod and the and the other ministers and it just hit me with i'm a huge force and i just thought of course you know this is the lesson that i learned all those years ago. It is exactly this and that's all we need to know. Of course, there's a lot of other things we can know, but all we need to know is that. In a senior strategy meeting of the Treasury in 2004, Martin Parkinson, who was sitting beside you, leant over and remarked to you that you and he were the only two in the room with lived experience of the 1990-91 recession.
Starting point is 02:20:12 And I think you interrupted the meeting to say that, you know, we need to run some war games. Yeah, I did. I mean, we were having a discussion about, I can't remember, it was, I don't think it was just a macroeconomic policy discussion and there were about 20 people, oh, 15 to 20 people in the room, anyway, the most senior level of the department and we were talking. We used these discussions to discuss policy issues
Starting point is 02:20:44 that were really so significant that they affected a large part of the department right um and in part it was to deal with the risk of silos that you get in any organization but it was more than that it was part of um building and maintaining that, a treasury identity. And, yeah, and it was in that conversation and had been going on for, I don't know, I can't remember how long, but anyway, it had been going on for a long period of time, let's say an hour. And it was at that point that Martin leaned across to me and made that comment. And again, that struck me with such force that I,
Starting point is 02:21:35 and it had obviously been something that had been worrying me, I assume subconsciously, because I just immediately stopped the meeting. I said, stop, stop, stop. Stop. We're going to have a different sort of discussion about these issues. And I said, you know, I think we need to war game some scenarios that's what we need to do we just need to do that and i said you know martin has just mentioned to me just made the observation
Starting point is 02:22:14 um about the depth of um uh experience in the in the department in dealing with recessions. And let's hope we never have another one, but we of all people should ensure that where the people of the government turns to for advice, if and when we find ourselves in that sort of position. And the reason I put it that way is that one of the other memories that I carried with me from the recession of the early 1990s is that when the recession was confirmed, I mean the fact that we were in one, the advice that came
Starting point is 02:23:11 from Treasury was there's no case for a large fiscal stimulus and that instead, of course, monetary policy should be eased, of course, and that should happen immediately. But as far as the budget is concerned, you should rely upon the operation of the automatic fiscal stabilisers, right, which just... Actually, you know, having... Reflecting on it and having gone through the, about that recession and then the response to the global financial crisis and then having left the department, of course, and observed from some distance the government's response to the pandemic, I actually find that automatic stabiliser narrative quite stupid, quite stupid for the reason that the way the automatic stabilisers work
Starting point is 02:24:20 and what people mean by that is that when the economy goes into recession, the economy goes into recession the budget goes into deficit well like the reason it goes into deficit is because people lose their jobs and tax revenue plummets and because people lose their jobs there are more people on the unemployment benefit so spending goes up and revenue plummets that's a consequence of recession. That doesn't bring the economy out of recession. It's just a consequence of recession. So you now got unemployed people.
Starting point is 02:24:56 How does that provide any sort of fiscal stimulus to get people back into work? So it doesn't. It's just stupid. And so the whole proposition, and look, I'm probably doing a deep injustice to the, because I was in Keating's office at the time, right? I'm probably doing a deep injustice to those who were involved in framing the advice within Treasury at the time on what the government should do to respond to that recession of the early 1990s. And at the time, I didn't think it was stupid, right? I just think it's stupid now, having had the opportunity to think more about it. So anyway, Treasury more or less said sit on your hands,
Starting point is 02:25:36 except in the monetary policy area. Well, of course, government can't sit on its hands through a recession, nor should it. And so what happened was the government, and Keating's now Prime Minister, of course, rather than Treasurer, the government finds alternative sources of advice, and those are in other government departments, largely. And then, and so the Treasury finds itself sidelined in the process that's developing a policy response to a recession. Well, that's completely absurd, right?
Starting point is 02:26:12 Completely absurd. It's perverse. And so I said to the group, you know, we have to make absolutely sure, we have to make sure that if the country ever finds itself in those circumstances again, that it's the Treasury sitting on the other side of the table from the Prime Minister, not some other agency that doesn't have our responsibility, doesn't have our training, doesn't have our understanding, can't possibly have prepared as well as we should have prepared for this sort of eventuality. And more to the point, what use are we if we're not at that table?
Starting point is 02:26:56 So that's why we started Wargaming. What does a Wargame actually look like in the treasury context? Like what's the output? Is it a model? It's model-driven.? It's model-driven. Yeah. So it's model-driven. Yeah, yeah, yeah.
Starting point is 02:27:08 So you run, so you have various macroeconomic models and you run various scenarios through those macroeconomic models that allow you to look at, well, firstly, to develop a benchmark scenario, right? So just imagine that a component of aggregate demand were to fall by this much. How many people would lose their jobs? Tell us a bit about where those people are.
Starting point is 02:27:39 What sort of people are they? What would happen? What would the monetary policy response be or likely to be? So what would happen to interest rates? What would happen to the exchange rate? Because that's also a possible stabiliser that can be helpful, right, in immediately adding the impact of that exogenous loss of aggregate demand in some place. And then consider various policy responses. So what sort of fiscal response would be required
Starting point is 02:28:18 to address that sort of demand shock, to compensate for it, if you like? And then, and you can do that all model-based. So that's just model-based, right? You can run various simulations and scenarios through that discussion. And then you get to the really meaty part of it, which is, well, now let's think about the timeliness of the intervention, right?
Starting point is 02:28:42 So one of the, I mean, even when I was, well, certainly when I was, by the time I was an undergraduate student of economics, I learned that one of the problems with using fiscal policy as a macroeconomic instrument is that there are all sorts of lags involved in its use. I mean, there's obviously the recognition lag, but that bedevils monetary policy as well. So we didn't know that the economy was in recession
Starting point is 02:29:16 until well after the event, right, because of the lag in the collection of national accounts and publication of national accounts. And you can look at indicators, but you don't really know until that national accounts figure comes out. So you've inevitably got the recognition lag, and then you've got the lag involved in developing a policy response, and then you've got the lag involved in implementation,
Starting point is 02:29:42 like rolling that response out in some way. And that led us to having conversations about the fastest track means of contributing to aggregate demand. And all of our war games, all of our war gaming told us that you've got to get cash in the hands of households. And there are ways that allow you to do that quite quickly. And we had explored a number of those ways in that war game, in that war gaming exercise, which is why, you know, which is why when it happened
Starting point is 02:30:26 in 2008, our focus was on very much on getting cash into the hands of households. War gaming has to be done in secrecy. Indeed. You could say. Yeah. I'm taking this to an interesting conclusion. And indeed, a lot of an economic policy department's thinking
Starting point is 02:30:52 has to be done secretly. Yeah. Because obviously you don't want to unnecessarily, negatively influence the public's perception of the economy. Does that imply that it is impossible for the public to ever fully appreciate counterfactuals? Well, no. So, well, I think there's a time dimension to that question,
Starting point is 02:31:20 I think, that's, well, maybe you don't want to go there, but maybe this is me seeking to squeeze out of a tricky spot. But, you know, once the decision's been taken, of course, it falls to the political leaders to communicate that to the public and the reasons for it and to, as part of the narrative, construct the counterfactual. But even then, I mean, this is really, really, really tricky stuff, right? You know, when we decided when, sorry, when on our advice,
Starting point is 02:32:09 the Rudd government decided on that first fiscal stimulus package in October of 2008, which was delivered before, well, most of it was delivered before Christmas of 2008. There were any number of critics who were lining up, accusing the government of firstly being spooked and not knowing what they were doing which was just a cheap political shot secondly of unnecessarily alarming people about the circumstances that we're in after all the abs had not said, guess what?
Starting point is 02:32:45 We've had a recession, right? So that action was all about forestalling a recession, dealing with that risk in advance. And so there was no counterfactual there that anybody else had constructed. So the government had to construct it. And the problem is if it constructs the counterfactual, it falls into the trap that you've referred to where it can stand accused of having made things worse. And it was certainly accused of that by the opposition, the political opposition, and by a number of newspapers.
Starting point is 02:33:22 So that is really difficult, right? But how else does a government explain the seriousness of the issue and why it has to take such exceptionally, or such exceptional steps, you know? There is no way, I just can't see any way of avoiding it. And so you need a really, really powerful narrative to be able to carry that one. It would be the same, though, in a national security context.
Starting point is 02:34:02 It's why, presumably, although, oh, no, I was about to say I wasn't part of these discussions, but actually I was because I used to sit on the Secretary's Committee on National Security, among other things. But, you know, that fridge magnet that said be alert but not alarmed. Yeah. Well, that's exactly the point. It's trying to walk that very fine line that you're getting to, right? That you're getting at. And it's exactly the same in trying to forestall an economic crisis. thinking about non-linearities and exponential growth as a result of events like the financial crisis and COVID?
Starting point is 02:34:52 I think, okay, so I'm not sure. I think they have got more understanding of the need for governments to do exceptional things in exceptional circumstances. I would say that. And to act preemptively. And to act preemptively. And to act preemptively. Yeah, absolutely. Yeah.
Starting point is 02:35:07 That much, yes. But that's when you're talking about a real crisis. What about if you're talking about a slower moving undermining of national capacity or national capability, for example? That is an interesting question. I just, I don't think so. It used to be said that, and I think it was probably the OECD that described Australia in these circumstances way back in the,
Starting point is 02:35:42 it could even have been in the 1970s, maybe it was the 1980s, that Australia is, and these are not the exact words, of course, but Australia has demonstrated a great capacity to deal with crises in the moment and after the moment, but has not demonstrated the same ability to deal with things before they become a crisis. You know, that kind of slow-moving build-up of imbalances or, you know, whatever the hell, you know.
Starting point is 02:36:20 And so there are quite a number of those that you can see playing out in Australia or have been playing out in Australia for some decades. So, for example, the impact of climate change, the impact. I mean, at some stage, well, I guess, I mean, in respect of some of the consequences of climate change, like the increasing incidence and severity of bushfires and floods and droughts,
Starting point is 02:36:54 I think people are getting it. But in the early 1990s, when some politicians were trying to have this or run this narrative and engage the public, they were getting no traction at all. So that, I think there so far as to say that the real heroic virtues are actually best demonstrated by solving those slow-moving train wrecks. I agree with that. Not by working on the kind of sudden crisis. Yeah. Yeah. Yeah, and of course, as others in conversation with you, I'm sure would have noted, you know, this extraordinary ability
Starting point is 02:37:52 of humans to discount probable future events because they're future, you know, or they're out there. Hyperbolic discounting. Hyperbolic discounting, exactly. Right? Yeah. It's a nice way of putting it. That's exactly it. And that makes the task of such leaders damn near impossible.
Starting point is 02:38:20 Yeah. Yeah. I'm struck. Actually, no. Sorry. I'm struck. Actually, no. Sorry, let me ask one question about Kevin Rudd and then I want to move on to this topic of reform and leadership. So, on the morning of the 29th of February 2008, must have been a leap year.
Starting point is 02:38:41 Yeah. You get a call to tell you that the PM is expecting you to be on an aircraft at Gladstone for a chat in the air. Yeah. You get a call to tell you that the PM is expecting you to be on an aircraft at Gladstone. Yeah. For a chat in the air. Yeah. And on the flight, Kevin asked you what happens to the Australian current account.
Starting point is 02:38:55 It's not how he framed the question. No. Okay. It was, no. No, it took me a while to figure out what the hell he was talking about. No, the way he framed the question was this. Look, the plane had just taken off. Yeah.
Starting point is 02:39:10 We'd levelled out. In fact, I think we'd been served a cup of tea, and Wayne Swan was on the plane as well. And there was one other, I just, it's my fault, I just can't remember who it was. It wasn't a minister, it was an advisor. And I was sitting opposite Kevin. And so a cup of tea, sir.
Starting point is 02:39:30 And he leans across the table and he literally said, what is the worst thing that can happen? Those are his exact words. What is the worst thing that can happen? There was no introduction. There was no context, right? For a brief moment, I thought, well, I guess we could fall out of the sky, you know?
Starting point is 02:39:51 I mean, I just had no context at all. And it wasn't until a long time later that he told me what the context of it was, which was that he'd not been able to sleep the night previous. He hadn't got any sleep at all. And he was, the question he was asking himself was, with what's going on in the global financial system, how might this play out in Australia? And we've been sending him briefing of the sort that you're going to see,
Starting point is 02:40:29 given the earlier past this conversation, you're going to see how absurd this is. But we had sent him briefing of the sort that said, well, Australia's got one of the best regulated financial systems in the world. Bank balance sheets are extraordinary, you know. We just don't see a high risk to the assets sitting on bank balance sheets.
Starting point is 02:40:54 There are no strong connections between Australian banks and foreign institutions that might run into trouble. As far as we can tell, you know, the banks have not been big investors in these collateralised debt instruments and so on, which have been a feature of other jurisdictions. Exposure to the housing market, well, of course it's there, but we don't think the circumstances exist in Australia to produce a housing price crash. And, you know, the banks have been stress tested by APRA
Starting point is 02:41:33 on multiple occasions and blah, blah, blah, blah, blah. And we were not briefing the government on the exposure that the banks had on the liability side of their balance sheet, which is what we were talking about earlier, their dependence upon these international capital markets for funding. And so, and I don't know if that was what was in the Prime Minister's mind, Kevin's mind at the time either, but he was deeply troubled
Starting point is 02:42:09 that there must be some exposure that we have to the global financial system that we're overlooking. There must be. But that's not how he asked the question. He asked the question, what's the worst thing that could possibly happen? And what he, so he obviously just assumed that this same question was sitting in my head and he wanted to know the worst thing and then we were going to come back from that.
Starting point is 02:42:32 Okay, that's the worst thing that can happen. How would we respond to that? Let's backtrack from that to something that's more likely to happen and how would we respond to that? And then what should we be putting in place now to help us deal with that in the event that we find ourselves in that position. But once I realised that he was talking about Australia's exposure to the international financial system, I said to him the worst thing
Starting point is 02:43:00 that can happen, well, among the worst things that can happen is that the rest of the world stops funding our current account. That's what I said. And more than that, I mean, the really worst thing that can happen beyond that is that they stop buying Australian government debt. That's about as bad as it would get, I think. And when we went through possible responses to that, just what you might have to do, and he and I have agreed
Starting point is 02:43:36 that I'll never talk publicly about some of the things that we discussed on that plane, so I won't do it here. But and then we step back from the absolute worst thing that could happen. So that's a place where you do actually have willing purchases of Australian government securities. So people out there all over the world who are lining up to buy treasury bonds. And so then we had a discussion about what the government might have to do in those circumstances.
Starting point is 02:44:19 And we did discuss things like possibly having to guarantee bank liabilities. I don't recall what sort of discussion we had about a fiscal injection, you know, actually government spending more money, but that must have been in the conversation somewhere, given what happened subsequently. It must have been, yeah. My question is why was he, I mean,
Starting point is 02:44:51 he didn't really have like a specialised economics background. No, no, no. He used to tell me all the time. He used to say, I don't know anything about economics. I'm a student of Chinese poetry. So why was he so far along in his thinking? Was he just getting like really good briefings from some other agency like DPMC? No, no, no.
Starting point is 02:45:16 Was it like a temperamental edge that he had? Temperamental. Is that the right word? I think you're on the right word there, but it's just... He was... You know, he was out in front of any other leader of any country, anywhere in the world, in asking that question. I'm sure he was.
Starting point is 02:45:47 So it was the way that he was interpreting the briefings that he was getting about what was going on in international meetings and so on, and, of course, he had attended a couple where these things, fragilities in the international financial architecture, were being discussed. I mean, pretty abstract stuff, really. But his interpretation of it was, oh, hell, you know, this could get really, really, really ugly. And it's in the nature of him that he has such a – he is so keen on detail and ensuring
Starting point is 02:46:29 that every base is covered that that's what he wanted to do. He wanted to get on top of it, on top of every contingency because it's impossible, but that's what he wanted to do. And he certainly and understandably wanted some level of confidence that there were people in the public service who had some understanding of these contingencies and would be in a position to be able to provide him with advice on what he should do at the moment and in the moment.
Starting point is 02:47:06 So, but, you know, so, I mean, an uncharitable way of describing his personality is that he's a control freak. But you know what, in a crisis, that's probably exactly what you need, is a control freak. Yeah. And maybe that is exactly the behaviours that he was demonstrating through 2008, well before the collapse of Lehman Brothers. Maybe it is.
Starting point is 02:47:34 Well, good on him. It's a good thing for Australia that he did. That's my view. So moving to the bigger picture and reform. There's a bigger picture. There's an even bigger picture. I'm struck by the irony that you seem to have had a better experience of reform under a conservative government
Starting point is 02:47:59 than a progressive government. You're struck by that too. So to make this clear, Howard put you in charge of the GST task force in 1997, spent about a year working on that. The government goes to an election to get a mandate. Then there's a couple of years to implement it. The government even nearly gets rolled at that election in 1998. Yeah, lost the popular vote. Lost the popular vote and just got re-elected on the basis
Starting point is 02:48:33 of kind of the distribution of votes in some marginal seats. Yeah. And then the negotiation of the bill through the parliament is fraught. Brian Harradine famously rejects it in the Senate in May 1999 with those words, I cannot. In good conscience, was it? Yeah, in good conscience. In good conscience.
Starting point is 02:48:55 Yeah, support this tax or something like that. Yeah. And then Howard negotiates with the Australian Democrats. He invites Meg Lees into the cabinet room in Melbourne. And so, this really difficult, complicated, potentially unpopular tax reform gets up under a conservative government and you're working closely with them helping to design and implement that. Yeah.
Starting point is 02:49:17 On the other hand, fast forward to the Henry Tax Review and you come up with a whole bunch of things that are actually intuitively popular, like the Resource Superprofits Tax, which, I mean, it's difficult to recall a poll that was against what was colloquially called the mining tax. Yeah. And that just crashed and burned. And on top of that, the vast bulk of the 138 recommendations weren't adopted by the Rudd government. So I want to get your reflection looking back on those two experiences.
Starting point is 02:49:57 What has changed in the Australian polity to make reform more difficult? Or was the example of mismanaged reform under Labor more just an example of mistakes and bad management? So it could be those two things and there's a third. I'll come back to those two things. The third, though, is that, and it's very important, is that the GST package was the implementation commencing on 1 July 2000 of the core recommendation of a tax review
Starting point is 02:50:43 that was published in 1975. The Asprey Review. Yeah, and it had been commissioned a few years before. And there had been a number of attempts to implement that core recommendation. So Keating's 1985 tax summit package, that was a notable attempt to try to implement that core recommendation of the ASPRI review.
Starting point is 02:51:07 Option C. Yeah. And in fact, that was option C. Actually, I think we called it approach C, but never mind. It's remembered as option C. Option C is pretty much ASPRI, ASPRY, ASPRY. That's pretty much what it is with income tax base broadening, things like fringe benefits tax, capital gains tax, and so on.
Starting point is 02:51:35 And then personal income tax cuts overall, reform of the indirect tax system, and a broad base consumption tax, pretty much, you know, which is pretty much what Asprey recommended. So 10 years later, that failed in spectacular fashion. Didn't get the support of anybody. I mean, absolutely anybody apart from Keating and the Treasury. And then you have John Hewson in 1993 with his fightback package developed in opposition, which, and by the way, a very high-quality document, well argued.
Starting point is 02:52:22 It was confronting. It was challenging. It was really, really ambitious. But nevertheless, it was, and particularly for a document created in opposition, an outstanding piece of work. And of course, on this occasion, I was in the department providing briefing for actually John Keran was a treasurer at the time that that was launched, as I recall. I think I've got that right.
Starting point is 02:52:53 It must have been in 1992 that, yeah, of course, it was 1992 that it was released. Was it? It must have been. Or maybe it was 91. No, Keran was treasurer. It must have been the second half of 91. It must have been released in 91.
Starting point is 02:53:06 It was. And so preparing that briefing for Treasurer Keren in a role that put me, well, people chose to put me or decided that I was then on the other side of the argument, which I certainly wasn't, but I was nevertheless providing the briefing on the package as it was presented. And, you know, that fight back attempt failed and that was probably a more surprising, well, that was certainly a more surprising failure
Starting point is 02:53:46 than the one that Keating had suffered in 1995, you know, very surprising failure. And you would have thought, and everybody did think, well, that's it, that's the end of it, never going to happen again. And that's what Howard said in the 1996 election campaign, right, there will never, ever be a GST. So 25 years, I mean mean i think that's something and i don't think we should and several failed attempts so i don't think we should ignore that having said that
Starting point is 02:54:14 i'm not going to say to you that um so the point there is that well reform's always been difficult and takes a long time and takes a long time. And takes a long time. Yeah. Yeah. But having said that, I'm not going to say to you that I'm very confident that in 15 years' time we'll have a resource of super profits taxed in Australia, right? It takes more than that. So there is something about the other, in the other two things that you mentioned. And one of them, in fact, maybe both of them go back
Starting point is 02:54:45 to the ability of the proponents to construct a narrative that is sufficiently compelling to build, not just to build public support because, as you said, the polls suggested that the resources super profits tax had public support, right? But it is to... I have thought about this a lot. It's to give your...
Starting point is 02:55:18 If you're the Treasurer or Prime Minister running the argument, it's to give your parliamentary colleagues confidence that you're going to win it, you're going to win the argument. Also to give them a narrative that they can use in their own electorates too. And that is more than being able to point to public opinion polls, which show that overall the public is in favour. I think the reform ambition of governments, it certainly relies on the leadership and the qualities of leadership that we've spoken about, but the fuel for it,
Starting point is 02:56:10 on which it absolutely depends, is the more or less unquestioning support of the parliamentary colleagues of the leader, you know. And that's what wasn't there. It wasn't there in 1985, and that was a Labor government, and it wasn't there again when the tax review was launched in 2010. There was was insufficient confidence in the Parliamentary Labor Party that they were going
Starting point is 02:56:53 to be able to get this done. Now, people will debate for a long, long time whether that was a fair assessment being made by those people or not, but I'm sure that's why the jockeying for the moves against Kevin Rudd as Prime Minister started. Is the lack of confidence and the inability to craft a narrative endogenous to the good times? So I guess here I've kind of got you. You know those cyclical theories like tough times create hard men and women,
Starting point is 02:57:34 good times create soft men and women. Is there something like that going on? Does good policy leadership require like a wolf at the door to motivate it? Or were we just unlucky with the political leaders we had during those periods? I think it would be a bit unfair to say we were unlucky. I guess with respect to those specific policies. Yeah, because, oh, with respect to those specific policies.
Starting point is 02:58:02 Okay. So I used to think about this a hell of a lot, particularly when I was speaking publicly on economic challenges confronting the nation. When you think about the intergenerational reports, it's called, and the first of those was published in 2002. So these are reports, and Treasury publishes them, and these are reports that produce 40-year projections of government spending, right?
Starting point is 02:58:38 And they used to just assume, and certainly in 2002 report, just assumed that tax revenue would remain constant as a proportion of those domestic products. Just a technical assumption. Let's not worry about the tax side of the budget. And let's focus on the spending side of the budget. And I briefed the Howard cabinet on that report well in advance of being published and drew out what I saw as being
Starting point is 02:59:11 the central components of a policy reform narrative that could be built on those projections. And there was a lot of interest around the table, a lot of interest. And in the subsequent period, Peter Costello, as treasurer, gave a lot of speeches, a lot that were based on that narrative. And I did too. We both did. And it was kind of a double act, right? And he would address some audiences and I would address other audiences, right? And that's exactly what we were trying to do was to build a platform or more an environment, actually more an environment
Starting point is 02:59:58 in which one could have a serious conversation about emerging reform needs and then motivate the reforms that would be required. Because you're not in a crisis period and the narrative is based on 40-year projections, you can test things. And because as a politician your political window is three years at most, right, you don't actually have to expose yourself to the verdict of the electorate. So with that, you can be a little more comfortable about the ideas that you're expressing. the evidence is though that no matter how daunting those distant challenges are presented as being because of what you referred to earlier as hyperbolic discounting and maybe for other reasons the narrative has no impact it just doesn't grab people they just um oh well we
Starting point is 03:01:22 don't have to worry about that. We're worried about tomorrow, thank you very much. And with good reason. Most people are, and with good reason. Let's not worry about that. And I used to finish, almost every speech I gave on this, I would finish with the words like, we don't have to, like, we've got to do a lot of things. We don't have to do them immediately, but we will have to do them. Well, we still haven't done any of them. And we're 20 years in, right? That was 2002.
Starting point is 03:01:52 We're 20 years in. And by the way, the projections that we published in 2002, although they were 40-year projections, we had decadal projections. So we had projections for the first decade, second decade, third and fourth. If you compare had projections for the first decade, second decade, third and fourth. If you compare those projections for the first two decades against lived experience, against what's actually happened, they're pretty damn good, i.e. the disaster that we had outlined
Starting point is 03:02:18 is occurring. It's a slow-moving disaster, right? And surely people have been aware that the disaster is occurring. It's a slow-moving disaster, right? And surely people have been aware that the disaster is emerging. I mean, surely they're aware of Australia's atrocious performance in productivity growth, for example, atrocious performance in growth in gross domestic product per capita, all of those measures that matter to utilitarians, right? Surely they're aware of all that stuff and they're just allowing
Starting point is 03:02:47 it to happen. And moreover, no politician, no political leader has pointed to those things and said, oh, my God, this stuff that Costello was talking about 20 years ago, we've actually done nothing about it and look where we've actually done nothing about it, and look where we are, it's about time we did something. That's kind of deeply troubling, right? So I think it is possible to develop the narrative, but I'm not at all confident that you can get traction,
Starting point is 03:03:19 traction sufficient to motivate action. And is this like a problem that's unique to this period? Is this something that... No, I don't think it is, no. It's not. Interesting. No, I don't think it is. Interesting. And I think that's exactly the frustration that Keating was venting,
Starting point is 03:03:44 expressing anyway, in his 1986 Banana Republic statement. It's exactly that. We've got this slow-moving disaster. It's not going to hit us tomorrow. But if we don't do something pretty dramatic, it is going to hit us in some years hence. And so he, and I don't think he thought, well, I have spoken to him about this.
Starting point is 03:04:08 He was just expressing frustration. But, of course, what he was doing was constructing a burning platform. Yeah. That's what he was doing. He was making the counterfactual. Yeah, yeah, making it real. Yeah. And I really, you know, I've thought a lot about how one might
Starting point is 03:04:27 construct narratives to motivate change. And when it comes to major policy change, at least economic policy change and certainly tax policy change, nothing short of a burning platform will work. You've really got to convince people that we're all going to hell or somewhere worse. Oh, well, let's assume there's nowhere worse. We're all going to hell unless we do something
Starting point is 03:04:55 and do it pretty damn quickly. So, Ken, should I think of you as standing in contrast to thinkers like Mansa Olson, the public choice economist who wrote that book, The Rise and Decline of Nations, or more parochially like a Ross Garner who thinks that there are all these like almost like secular factors that now make reform more difficult. Should I think of you in contrast to those kind of theorists? No, I don't think so. I mean, I think those factors have made reform more difficult. Should I think of you in contrast to those kind of theorists?
Starting point is 03:05:25 No, I don't think so. I mean, I think those factors have made it more difficult. I'm just saying, I think what I'm saying and where you'd be able to find accommodation between my views and theirs is that I don't think it was ever easy. And I don't think we were ever very good at it, honestly. I don't think we were ever very good at it, honestly. I don't. I think there were circumstances that were largely,
Starting point is 03:05:54 I mean the circumstances were bad but it took somebody like Akitin to construct the burning platform to motivate action, right? That's with respect to the big things, some of the big things that were done. With respect to things like on the currency, which officials and governments have been wrestling with for a very long time before those decisions were taken in 1983. But, of course, the other thing is that other countries
Starting point is 03:06:40 from all around the world, most actually, I think, I could be wrong on this, but my sense is that most, certainly leading IMF members would have floated their currencies before Australia did. So it was kind of a, why are we not doing this? It doesn't tell you very much about Australia's preparedness for economic reform, I don't think. I don't think I'm doing that an injustice.
Starting point is 03:07:14 It's really in motivating public appetite for the difficult things like bringing the budget deficit back under control that you've got to construct that burning platform. like bringing the budget deficit back under control, that you've got to construct that burning platform. And that's what Keating did. And the only other times we've had it is when it couldn't be ignored, when we were actually in the middle, have been in the middle of a crisis, whether it's a global financial crisis or the pandemic or whatever if there's a problem with democracy that that implies like a bigger problem for capitalism right yeah because two sides of a coin yeah yeah like milton friedman's argument
Starting point is 03:07:58 that the only social responsibility of a business is to maximize profit for shareholders was predicated in part on the idea that governments could internalise externalities. Absolutely. I mean, more than in part. More than in part. I mean, it's very... Well, I guess the other part I'm contemplating is that individuals can internalise externalities as well.
Starting point is 03:08:18 Yeah, so, yeah. Well, let's talk about that. So, Friedman's perspective, as I read capitalism and freedom, is that, I mean, it's funny. So when I read capitalism and freedom, what I get from it is a perspective that says without functional democracy and governments playing their role in the public, i.e. the citizens who elect them, ensuring the governments play the appropriate role with respect to,
Starting point is 03:09:02 and Friedman points to, free and open competition and absence of fraud or deception, right? In those things in particular, he would say, and he does say in Capitalism and Freedom that, well, it's not going to work. But in saying that, he sets up an adversarial system, right, where the rest of us, and that's the expression he uses, the rest of us, as citizens in a democracy, we necessarily find ourselves in an adversarial position with respect to business. provided businesses seek to maximise profit and government does its bit to ensure that as consumers and workers and so on, we're not dudded by their profit-maximising activities.
Starting point is 03:09:52 What do you know? That's fine. Formally, in neoclassical economics, the expression is that the outcome is Pareto optimal. Now, there are, in the sense that nobody can be made better off without somebody else being made worse off, right? And it satisfies all the utilitarians. But there are other issues, and he canvases these other issues in Capitalism and Freedom, where he refers to the possibility of neighbourhood effects, which today we call externalities. And I mean, everybody's aware of the really big one,
Starting point is 03:10:28 which is climate change, which is clearly a negative externality of the operation of markets and businesses seeking to maximise profits and being allowed to do so without taking account of the damage that they're doing to the climate and to the environment and now to people's lives as a consequence of those commercial activities. But there are many other negative externalities that are a consequence of profit maximisation, and he admits that, more than admits, he sets out the way that one should think about the role of government
Starting point is 03:11:01 in dealing with those externalities, and he refers to essentially a balance sheet approach or maybe a profit and loss approach. Anyway, what we these days have termed something like a cost-benefit analysis of government intervention because one should recognise that if governments seek to intervene to address a negative externality and they're successful, they do some good,
Starting point is 03:11:28 but they could also be doing some harm as well, associated with the regulatory imposition, blah, blah, blah. You know, that. And he also talks about the other case for government, the other big case for government involvement, which is in the provision of public goods. But from memory, and it's a while since I've read it, but from memory, and it's a while since I've read it, but from memory,
Starting point is 03:11:45 aside from defence, he's pretty reluctant to endorse a case for governments getting very much involved in the delivery of public goods. I remember being absolutely shocked when I read that he could see no case for governments funding national parks. And the reason I find that one shocking is that I understand the argument that the beneficiaries, those who derive benefit from national parks are those who visit them. So rather than national parks being funded by the general body of taxpayers, they should
Starting point is 03:12:23 be funded by those who get to enjoy the national parks, i.e. those who visit them. The problem is that many of those, and even if you are utilitarian on this, many of those that you would hope get to visit national parks are not even born yet, far less of a voting age, and they're not capable of expressing the value that they attach to a national park by paying park entrance fees.
Starting point is 03:12:52 And so there's a complete ignorance in his writings of the important role the government has in preserving things for the enjoyment of future generations. And that, I think, is a significant weakness. But the other thing that's ironic is that it's not until, I think it's not until, I think it's in the foreword of the 40th edition because he kept revising that book. I think I read an interview with him at some stage
Starting point is 03:13:34 where he said it's the most difficult thing he ever wrote, which I think is why he continued to revise it. But I think he says in the foreword of the 40th edition that he, on reflection, wishes that he had paid more attention to the way that governments might discharge their responsibilities. I think he was thinking more of the contest between authoritarianism and democracy.
Starting point is 03:14:14 But I think, and I don't know if he had this in mind, but my perspective on it would be that he should have spent more time thinking about how capitalism operates when government is incapable, for whatever reason, of discharging its responsibilities, right? So what happens when government is dysfunctional, for whatever reason is incapable of ensuring that business does operate in a way such that profit maximisation does actually lead to a utilitarian utopia.
Starting point is 03:15:03 Two questions. If government is dysfunctional for secular reasons, does that imply that companies and other organisations are actually the real vehicles for social change? So all else being equal, today, should ambitious young people think less about the political arena and the public service and more about the startup world? So this is a good question.
Starting point is 03:15:36 All your questions have been good. So I don't know about the startup world. Like I wouldn't focus on that particularly, but I found myself having to, I didn't have to, but I chose to talk about these issues in an address I gave recently to a bunch of graduating students at the ANU. And I made the point that this somewhat dystopian perspective that I have, that government has essentially become dysfunctional, opens up enormous opportunity for people who understand how the system operates and who understand what it might take to achieve better social outcomes, including environmental outcomes.
Starting point is 03:16:28 And the point I made was that, like at an instrumental level, the point I made was that there is a role for smart people in achieving things that governments, for whatever reason, have demonstrated an incapacity to achieve. And what's at play here is that even if the vast majority of people don't understand the reasons for the bad things that they observe going on around them, they know that there's something wrong, right? And they are inclined to the view that business is at the heart of it.
Starting point is 03:17:25 And why not? After all, it's businesses that actually take the decisions that affect most people's lives, right? Businesses in one form or another who decide what gets produced, at what price, who gets a job, where the job is located, how much they get paid, what inputs are used in the production of whatever it is that they're producing, whether it's a good or a service, where those things are sourced from, what environmental damage
Starting point is 03:17:54 is tolerated in the production of those things, what social harm is done by people consuming the products that they produce, all that kind of stuff. It's actually businesses doing it, right? And I think people understand that, and I think they see businesses being, therefore, the source of the problem.
Starting point is 03:18:17 So as a policy-trained economist, I see government failure there. I think most people see business failure. Well, in that, there is enormous opportunity, right? So there is more interest now in people understanding the consequences of business activity. And so there's a lot of support now for enhanced disclosure regimes. So take, for instance, the Taskforce on Climate-Related Financial Disclosure that is voluntary, and yet, although it's voluntary, I know the new Environment Minister
Starting point is 03:19:02 has signalled, or maybe it was Chris Bowen, has signalled that one day these disclosures are going to be mandated for large public-listed companies, but nevertheless they're voluntary. But most large public-listed companies are making these disclosures now. Now, they're only making scope one and possibly scope two disclosures, not full scope three disclosures of carbon emissions associated with their activities. But they're nevertheless moving in that direction, right?
Starting point is 03:19:35 And why? The reason they're moving in that direction is because they understand that increasingly the expectation that investors have, so shareholders have, is that they will take some responsibility or some accountability is probably a better word, some accountability for what they're doing and seek to avoid those negative impacts. Workers don't want to work for such companies.
Starting point is 03:20:00 So if you're in the market for labour, as you are, as every business is, and that's an increasingly difficult market, you're going to find it increasingly difficult to attract people who want to work for you. You're going to find banks increasingly reluctant to lend to you because of the reputational risk, but also the credit risk associated with those lending decisions. And you're going to find customers saying, I don't want to buy your product. Bugger off. You know, I'll source product.
Starting point is 03:20:35 I'll satisfy my wants and my needs from other businesses that I just like the look of, right? I don't like the look of you. So the way to think about that in economics 101 terms is that it's actually those economic agents, so investors, credit providers, lenders, workers and consumers who are effectively imposing an externality tax on their business, on business generally. You can avoid this externality tax by changing your behaviour. You don't change your behaviour, you're going to have to pay higher wages to attract people. You won't be able to charge such high prices
Starting point is 03:21:10 to attract consumers. You're going to pay higher interest rates and you're going to have to be capable of paying higher dividends to attract investor support and that's probably going to dwindle and dry up anyway. So it's effectively disenchantment on the part of the public or members of the public generally in attributing the source of the problems to the activities of business, and understandably so, that is, I think, leading to an implicit
Starting point is 03:21:47 externality tax being imposed on businesses. And that is going to change behaviour. And what I was saying to this group of graduates at the ANU is there's enormous opportunity there. You think about everything that's going to be required to put that system in place, the information requirements, the data requirements, for a start, people who are capable of sitting inside businesses and guiding them on how they should respond
Starting point is 03:22:13 to this implicit externality tax in its various forms and what they need to do, massive change coming, I reckon, and it's going to go well beyond climate. It's going to go to the next cab off the rank is the Task Force on Nature-Related Financial Disclosure. That too will be voluntary, at least initially, and maybe for a very long time, but I nevertheless expect to see Australian businesses responding to that that and responding quickly and maybe even seeking
Starting point is 03:22:49 to be at the forefront globally in responses. Anyway, I certainly hope that that's the case. And you've also got other governments in other parts of the world that are not as timid as ours that are, yeah, not as timid as ours, I think that's right, that are taking decisions. Maybe they're protectionist, but of the sort, well, we're not going to allow our consumers to source product from countries like Australia that have such a poor record with respect to carbon emissions
Starting point is 03:23:30 or have such a poor record with respect to species extinction and so on, right? And that is driving change behaviour as well. And I think it's going to be an increasingly potent force. Were you working on anything around the social responsibility of companies before you left NAB? Yeah. Yeah, yeah, sure. I mean, it's kind of we were having a lot of conversations internally
Starting point is 03:23:58 about this topic and, in fact, we had turned out to be quite an expensive exercise on the whole question of social purpose and we developed through a long process and involving a lot of people in the organisation, certainly all of the board and all of the senior management, but it went well down into the organisation of developing a purpose statement for NAB. Yeah, we had a lot of conversations about it, and that included the stance that NAB should take with respect to its regulatory obligations.
Starting point is 03:24:57 And it's kind of ironic that, you know, we were probably more, I would say that NAB was more advanced on these discussions than any of the other banks. In fact, I'm sure that's true and had made substantial progress. But, of course, NAB had the wealth business, the MLC business, which it had acquired in 2000. And it had recently restructured or changed the business model in advance of everybody else in moving from a trailing commission model to a fee-for-service model.
Starting point is 03:25:38 And it was still in the process of being bedded down, and I would have to say, with huge problems, I mean massive problems. And we were aware of those problems and were engaging with the regulators on those problems. But that was just at the time that, you know, the legitimate angst in the public was escalating and we found ourselves in a royal commission.
Starting point is 03:26:17 Interestingly, that royal commission had the opportunity, because it was certainly within its terms of reference, to consider these issues. In round seven, I think it was, I was called as a – and it's funny how you get these invitations, because the invitation is to appear before the Royal topics of corporate accountability, governance and culture. That's sort of exactly what we've just been talking about in this interview. So they're big policy questions and I didn't get any questioning on these topics at all. And that's because I think it's just the structure,
Starting point is 03:27:08 the way the Royal Commission had been established and the way it was doing its work, and I'm not being critical in saying this, but it was operating more as a criminal court, the way a criminal court operates. And it was good theatre. And I'm not in any way wanting to diminish the seriousness of the issues that were under consideration because they were certainly serious, no question about that. But what it failed to do is it failed to grapple
Starting point is 03:27:42 with any of the policy issues. And that's a problem. And in fact, the big policy issues, the core policy issues that were at issue in respect of the financial advice part of NAB, the MLC part, which is what I got all the questioning about, they're still unresolved. And in fact, the newspapers, even this week, have been full of commentary about whether the Labor government will act on a subsequent review of those parts of the law
Starting point is 03:28:21 that the Hayne Royal Commission had failed to address. It's still ongoing. Who knows when these issues will ever be resolved, right? But, yeah, it's a bit of a shame. But, yeah, we were certainly working on these issues in NAB in the time that I was there, and I don't know what's happened to that work since. When you left Treasury in 2011, some coalition MPs had been openly attacking you since about 2008.
Starting point is 03:29:01 Yeah. And you'll remember in the 2010 election, as part of the negotiations with the crossbench, Oakeshott and Windsor extracted the red book and the blue book. And then the Treasury advice about Abbott's policy program being quite scathing and that leaked and Abbott was filthy and was no doubt prepared to be vindictive as he eventually was when he took government. Yeah.
Starting point is 03:29:32 That was years later though. Years later. Yeah. I guess I'm curious, like, what part of your motivation in leaving in 2011 was to protect the broader institution of the Treasury from political attacks? Well, it was certainly playing on my mind. It, but it's, I thought a lot about this.
Starting point is 03:30:07 Well, I thought a lot about it in the moment. Look, in the 2010 election, this is probably not known. I'm sure nobody has written this, but I don't think there's any reason why I shouldn't disclose it. I don't think I was in any confidential discussion, but in that period following the election when the discussions were going on with the crossbenchers and both potential governments were involved in those discussions, I was sitting in my office, I got an invitation
Starting point is 03:30:46 to go across to Parliament House and meet with the Liberal leader and the Deputy Liberal leader, which I willingly agreed to do, of course, even though they'd been bagging me for years, or at least the party had. And so I met with Tony Abbott and Julie Bishop. The only other person in the room was Peter Credlin. And the purpose of the meeting was simply for them to ask me whether in the event that they were able to get the support of the crossbenchers and form government, I would give them an undertaking to stay on as Treasury Secretary.
Starting point is 03:31:31 And I said I'd be very pleased to do so, and I would have stayed on. Matter of fact, Tony Abbott said he would be honoured if I did so. Anyway, I would have stayed on and I would have expected to have had another term as Treasury Secretary had I done so. My term was up in April 2011. I think had I stayed on, I probably would have had another term So my term was up in April 2011. I think had I stayed on, I probably would have had another term. But the thing is that politics is fickle, right? And it is not just about, I mean, it's largely about personalities, of course, because that's the way the game is played.
Starting point is 03:32:24 But politicians on both sides can be absolutely brutal with people and with institutions when they choose, when the circumstances suit them. And I had absolutely no confidence that where I had to stay on that was going to improve the quality of the relationship between the Treasury and the coalition government. And so I didn't think it was in the Treasury's interest that I stay on.
Starting point is 03:32:58 But mind you, I certainly didn't think it was in my interest that I stay on either. I'd had a gutful. And, yeah, and so, and anyway, I'd been doing the job for 10 years and I thought it was the right time to hand over and certainly to hand over to Martin it was the right time. So I've never, a lot of people have asked me whether I ever, because I was only 53 when I left, and a lot of people have asked me whether I've ever had any regrets about leaving when I did
Starting point is 03:33:33 and maybe occasionally, but not very often. Not very often, which isn't to say that I don't miss it. I miss it enormously. Like I don't miss it. I miss it enormously. Like every day I miss it. What I miss, I miss the work. I miss the colleagues. I still think about the issues. Like every day I think about the issues, but not in the way
Starting point is 03:34:02 that I was once able to think about the issues. I mean, what an extraordinary privilege it is for a person interested in policy that if they wake up in the middle of the night with an idea or a thought or even a burning question, within a few hours they can have a team of very, very smart people working that issue to death and then before the day is out be engaging in a robust debate with those same people about the various issues, right?
Starting point is 03:34:42 I mean, that's extraordinary. Who gets that opportunity? And I lived that for years and years and years, right? I mean, that's extraordinary. Who gets that opportunity? And I lived that for years and years and years, right? And it was just wonderful. I guess it's just a shame for the country that you were cognizant of the scapegoating dynamic in leaving Treasury but not in walking into the Banking Royal Commission. Yeah, well.
Starting point is 03:35:11 No, that's right. Possibly I'm drawing a false equivalence. No, you're not. No, I don't think it is a false equivalence. Well, I don't regard, I mean, it's false in the sense that I don't think it's mean, it's false in the sense that I don't think it's such a loss for the country that I left NAB when I left NAB. Because, I mean, honestly, whilst I felt that I was having
Starting point is 03:35:36 an impact on NAB, and I know I was, and by the way, I think it has, from everything I read, the institution has continued to improve in the years since I left, which is not all that long ago. In those roles, no matter how much you do, you can't achieve the sort of change that you can achieve and have the sort of impact that you can have when you're, you know, you're working in the Treasury.
Starting point is 03:36:09 I mean, you just can't. And so those roles, those very senior policy advising roles, they are, they're just in a completely different space from what people have been able to achieve in the corporate world or, you know, in all of those, many of them extraordinarily worthwhile NGOs that we have around, which are vital parts of the civil society that, you know, that underpins Australia. And they're certainly, you know, they're more than much in a very different space from what academics, even the world's best academics, are able to achieve with their work. Of course, they're highly influential on, or should be, on those senior policy people, but they don't have the same proximity to the action.
Starting point is 03:37:05 They don't have the ear of the policy decision makers and cannot in quite the same way. And, of course, they wouldn't even seek to, right? Would impact their independence. Yeah, so there is something very special about it, and I don't think you can really... So there is no equivalence in that sense. Nevertheless, there is something in the, what is it?
Starting point is 03:37:40 I don't even know what it is, but it's kind of, there's nevertheless a sense, I mean, there's obviously a bit of a sense of personal loss, although certainly nothing as profound as losing one of those senior policy roles. I mean, the people who, like Martin years later, who was unceremoniously sacked by Tony Abbott only to be brought back by Malcolm Turnbull. I mean, you just can't get your head around this stuff, even though I understand how all that happened.
Starting point is 03:38:22 But I think I do. I mean, that's really bloody devastating, right? Losing that sort of role for absolutely no reason. At least when I walked away from NAB, there was a reason for doing it. It was very much in the interest of the NAV reputations that I considered that somebody in my job, i.e. the chairman of the company, stand up and say, well, you know what? And it took me a while to get to this point, and I know that's my own failing,
Starting point is 03:38:56 but you know what? As chairman of this outfit, I just have to take accountability for this. And by the way, there used to be a parallel in public service. It was called ministerial accountability. And it was much the same thing, which is that, motivated by much the same idea, that, of course, if you are the minister with responsibility for an agency and the agency misbehaves in some way, right, in some big way, even if you couldn't possibly personally have had anything to do with that, you are nevertheless accountable and you must resign. And that's the doctrine of ministerial responsibility, right, which we don't have any longer in Australia.
Starting point is 03:39:49 We had it up until some way through the Howard government. I don't know, you may recall that in the, I think, the first 12 months of the Howard government, I think there were six ministers who lost their jobs. Not all of them on the doctrine of ministerial responsibility, but some, yes. And it's a peculiar feature of the Westminster system and it's a really odd, somebody has to be seen publicly
Starting point is 03:40:30 to take accountability for failings. And where is the buck going to stop if not on the desk of the minister or on the desk of the chairman of the company? You know? So I think it's actually, it should be seen as a strength of our system, not a weakness of our system. To finish the conversation, I thought it would be fun. Fun.
Starting point is 03:41:01 Fun to ask you a few questions about specific policies. Oh, yeah. And these will be high variance questions. Uh-huh. So either- And I'm not going to say, well, that's hypothetical. Yeah, you can't say that. No.
Starting point is 03:41:16 But either the questions will be kind of daft or they could actually provoke really interesting responses. So let's- we'll see how we go. What would it take for Australia to build a major new city and where would you put it? Yeah. Okay. So that is a question I've thought about.
Starting point is 03:41:39 Yeah. Oh, wow. Great. I know. Did Treasury ever look into this? Yeah, yeah, yeah. So I, oh, yeah, yeah, yeah, yeah. Oh, interesting. Oh, wow. Great. I know. Did Treasury ever look into this? Yeah, yeah, yeah. So I, oh, yeah, yeah, yeah. Oh, interesting.
Starting point is 03:41:47 Oh, yeah. So when was this? Oh, goodness me. It was, it must have, well, yeah, I was Treasury Secretary, certainly at the time. And I remember having a conversation. Pull your mic up. You can lean back, just pull it.
Starting point is 03:42:12 I remember having a conversation with Kevin Rudd only a few days after the November 2007 election. In fact, it was the first conversation I had with him after he became Prime Minister. And we were just talking about a whole range of issues. And he said, I think he said something like, oh, and by the way, what do you think the maximum sustainable population for Australia is?
Starting point is 03:42:46 And I said, probably 15 million thereabouts. And he thought I said 50. And he went forward and he said, 50 million. Ah, right, good. I said, no, no, no, I said 15. Having you say that, population's already much more than 15. And I said, I don't think you can argue that human activity on this continent is sustainable, not in any way I think about it.
Starting point is 03:43:11 And so I think we'd have to cut our population quite a bit if that's all we were going to do in order to achieve a sustainable population. And he was obviously shocked and obviously disappointed. He may even have been appalled. I don't know. And then I said to him, but although that's my view, it's also my view that it would be possible to construct a set
Starting point is 03:43:41 of policies that would sustain a population of 50 million, 5-0. That's possible. But it would mean that we'd have to do a lot of things very differently. And in that conversation, I said, for example, we might have to build a whole brand-new city for 10 million people, one that doesn't presently exist. So then we subsequently, in the department,
Starting point is 03:44:02 and it wasn't just in the department, there were other people involved in this as well, started exploring where you might build not a whole brand new city of 10 million, but say a number of cities of 1 million where you'd put them throughout Australia, right? And there, and so I'm not trying to avoid the question, but here's the thing. The reason we don't have a very fast train in Australia
Starting point is 03:44:42 from Melbourne to Brisbane is obvious, right? And everybody knows it. It's because we don't have the population that would support it. That doesn't mean we don't have sufficient population in total. It's the distribution of the population that makes it ridiculous, right? But if the population were distributed differently, like along a corridor that a train line might run through with maybe five stops, something like that, maybe a few more,
Starting point is 03:45:14 because not every train has to be an express, then it is possible to think about those things, right? And so in specific answer to your question, I think there's a lot of spots along a potential rail corridor where you could build such cities. Of course, there are environmental issues associated with every one of those spots. So those are issues that factors that have to be taken into account.
Starting point is 03:45:47 But we don't avoid those issues by allowing the continuing suburban sprawl in Melbourne and Sydney and, oh, Perth, for heaven's sake, and Brisbane too. All those cities that are going to become, probably going to become megacities. Maybe Brisbane won't ever be called a megacity, but it's going to be a big one and Perth's going to be a big one. And Sydney and Melbourne will be called megacities globally, right, if we don't do something smarter. So transport infrastructure, I think, is quite a big part of it. And, of course, there are other things that would have to be attended to,
Starting point is 03:46:37 but I would start looking at that corridor. That's so interesting. Have you heard of the Bradfield scheme? Oh, yeah. So, as you know, it was this- To turn the rivers back. Yeah, this really ambitious project back in 1938, I think it was first suggested,
Starting point is 03:46:58 basically to create an inland sea in Australia by filling up like air and then diverting rivers to it. And the idea was that this would basically drought-proof much of Queensland and South Australia. Except that it would be saltwater, right? Presumably, yeah. Well, it would. Yeah. Yeah, I'm not actually familiar with the details of how they were going to get around that particular problem.
Starting point is 03:47:19 Well, I don't think they were. I don't think they thought about it. Right. Well, that probably explains why it doesn't exist. No, no, I don't think that's about it. Right. Well, that probably explains why it doesn't exist. No, no, I don't think that's why it doesn't exist. There might be other reasons as well. Yeah, I think there might be other reasons. Yeah, okay.
Starting point is 03:47:32 Fair enough. But regardless of the merits of that particular scheme, I guess just thinking on that level of kind of like crazy ambitious nation-building projects, what incredibly ambitious project are we not building currently that we should be? Yeah. Outside of kind of new cities. Yeah, outside of new cities. See, I would start, I actually would start with new cities. That's why I was so well prepared for that. I'm glad I asked. For that question. Yeah, I would start with new
Starting point is 03:48:03 cities. But others, oh, look, the renewable energy space offers huge challenge and huge opportunity, right? And we're kind of, look, this is a gross generalisation. So it's not, it's nowhere near close to being accurate, but we are applying much, to date anyway, to date we've applied much the same thinking and policy analysis to the accommodation of renewable energy projects as we have anything else.
Starting point is 03:48:41 Even though we know we've got a pretty good sense of the size of the transformation that's going to be required. And, of course, whenever anybody talks about it, I say, oh, my God, we've got to do, you know, what we've already done. We've got to do it 10 times over and we've got to do it within 10 years or something, you know, things to that effect. And I know some people are thinking about an entirely new approach to this like just turn the way we think about these issues on their heads and let's just say okay let's aim to achieve that
Starting point is 03:49:11 outcome right what are we going to have to do in order to achieve that outcome it does bring you back to locational issues like where you're going to locate the cities um it it forces you to think about transmission infrastructure, of course, in a way that we haven't to date thought about it. It forces you to think about things like local electricity networks using battery storage or a whole variety of different possible pumped hydro storage or a whole variety of different possible pumped hydro storage or whatever, every one of those projects would be multi-billion dollar projects. They're huge.
Starting point is 03:49:58 And as a country, aside from Snowy Hydro, and not even Snowy Hydro 2.0, it's not of the scale that's going to be required of some of these other projects. It's not even big enough. I mean, some of these projects that we are going to have to invest in will be much bigger than Snowy 2.0, right? What sort of policy thinking do you have to bring to projects of that order of magnitude?
Starting point is 03:50:39 And it's kind of pressing, right, because it's not as if we can avoid these challenges. So that's another one. Here's another one. When I was working for the Gillard government leading the development of the white paper in Australia in the Asian century, this idea popped into my head. I was in Darwin and I thought,
Starting point is 03:51:17 why doesn't Darwin look like Singapore? So that's a good one to think about. What would it take? I like that. Yeah, what would it take? What could you do? And I know what's happened since to the port of Darwin makes some of these questions problematic. But if there's enough money and enough will,
Starting point is 03:51:43 you could build a second port of Darwin. Would it be possible to do a deal with the Singapore Port Authority or whatever it's called with respect to entrepot activity. You think of all those ships that sit for weeks and weeks and weeks off Singapore merely to drop their cargo, for that cargo to be sorted and then picked up by another ship. It's going to take it somewhere else. It's not like it was never heading for Singapore
Starting point is 03:52:20 other than to allow for transference from one vessel to another vessel. Darwin's a few hours south of Singapore, of course, and as the ship would sail, I'm not sure how much additional time it would take, but, I mean, if you're going to be sitting for a couple of weeks off Singapore, why not divert to Darwin and it'll cut your time massively and get the activity undertaken there. Why not see the port of Darwin as an export port for some of the natural resources that are going out through the port of Gladstone?
Starting point is 03:52:57 A lot of them are located in Western Queensland. What would it take? You're getting the vibe here. I can see by the expression on your face. What would it take to have that cargo sent west and then north out through the Port of Darwin? And then what are the other opportunities that would be available in essentially a tropical city in the north of Australia, very close to all of Southeast Asia. I mean, I think I did see it.
Starting point is 03:53:37 When I was consulting on this project, I visited the then Chief Minister of the Northern Territory and stood in his office and he's got this. I'll bet it's still there. I'll bet every Chief Minister of the Northern Territory hangs onto this. It's a wall map. And, of course, Darwin is at the centre of it, right? So that's how the world is drawn.
Starting point is 03:54:01 That's how the world map's drawn. It's wonderful. And then there are these concentric circles identified by flight time or maybe it's kilometres. Anyway, it doesn't really matter. It's an easy translation, right? And it just shows how many Asian cities are closer to Darwin than is Melbourne or Perth or Sydney.
Starting point is 03:54:32 And it allows you to think about Darwin playing a completely different role as a significant Southeast Asian city with obvious connections to several very big cities in Australia. Right? Mm-hmm. Yep. There's another idea for you. This is great. My high variance questions are going well so far.
Starting point is 03:54:53 Oh. Okay. Here's another one. So we have a decentralized privatized super system. Yep. Two trillion of disengaged money. Mm-hmm. And that's a honeypot for fraud and misbehavior.
Starting point is 03:55:10 Mm-hmm. ASIC has to be the arbiter of that fraud. Has ASIC been set up for failure? Does it have enough resources to oversee a honeypot that large? Okay. So, no, it doesn't. I mean, clearly it doesn't. It has to rely on reporting and information systems,
Starting point is 03:55:40 data collection systems that are, well, they're getting better. But, I mean, it's, I don't want to sound alarmist. And I'm not really alarmist about it because, actually, things have gone pretty damn well. You'd have to say things have gone pretty damn well to date. But it's going to become increasingly challenging obviously for ASIC to stay on top of that and in part that's because I mean it's not just fraud
Starting point is 03:56:16 but there's also the risk of internet-based activity, the so-called cybercrime, for which I don't think any regulatory agency in the world would regard themselves as exceptionally well-placed to deal with. It's just an increasingly difficult set of issues for we humans having invented the capability to now deal with. I mean, I say I am. So that's under KYC provisions, know your customer provisions. Very sensible.
Starting point is 03:57:15 Understand it. Understand it completely. But I'm old enough to remember a time when you'd never have to do that. And of course you didn't have to do it because the risks to which you're exposed or were exposed back then are several orders of magnitude less than what they are now. The risk of identity fraud or identity theft and then fraud that can be perpetrated once the identity theft has occurred.
Starting point is 03:57:53 I mean, all the spam emails and so on that you get. And I was in this extraordinary conversation with a very helpful person in the bank and I said, look, I've received this email from you. Well, it looks like it comes from you, but I can't be sure. And the reason I'm worried about it is because I've heard your CEO say, be wary of spam emails. We'll never send you an email that asks you to click on a link to anything.
Starting point is 03:58:28 I said, have a look at this email. It's got 12 links in it. Turned out it was a genuine email from that thing. Like holy hell. Now, is that just a case of the left hand not knowing what the right hand's doing? I don't know. But it's hugely complex and the exposures that we all have
Starting point is 03:58:54 are of a diabolical order of magnitude, right? And so, yeah, the simple answer to your question is that, no, I don't think ASIC could possibly have the resources that would be required to prevent fraud in all cases, and that's probably not its objective. I mean, it's probably looking to a more realistic objective, which is to provide a level of deterrence that minimises some level of comfort, the amount of fraud that's going to be undertaken. And that's not a comfortable place, but it's a realistic place.
Starting point is 03:59:40 And by the way, that issue raises its head because of the interconnection, because of the way in which our financial system is wired, including the superannuation system. That issue is there no matter whether the superannuation funds are privately owned as they are or, you know, if we had one mega superannuation fund in public ownership, you'd still have the issue. I mean, if the Commonwealth Bank was still in public ownership, it would still have the same issues that all the other banks have got. True. So on my most recent podcast episode, I interviewed Palmer Luckey, who's a US tech entrepreneur.
Starting point is 04:00:22 He's founded a couple of unicorn companies. The second is Endural, which sells weapons tech to the US government, the Australian government, other Western governments. Oh, wow. And I think he's designed a lot of the tech himself. But he was telling me about how the defense industry in the US is grossly inefficient. Contracts are awarded on a cost plus basis.
Starting point is 04:00:51 And the incentives are structured such that sometimes there's almost a competition to see who can put in the most expensive bid, not the cheapest bid. Is this problem similar in Australia as well? And I guess like as a corollary of that, could we view the nuclear subs decision through that lens? I don't think that's not the lens that I would use in looking at the nuclear subs issue.
Starting point is 04:01:28 The issue that has bedevilled defence procurement in Australia is, yeah, it's in part to do with, let's call them inefficiencies or cost padding or cost overruns on the part of vendors or contractors, that's part of it. But there's a part of me, because I'm an economist, I kind of accept that it's a fact of life that people will seek to get away with whatever they can get away with. Sorry, that they will get away with whatever they can get away with.
Starting point is 04:02:15 And I know that's harsh. And I know actually I hope it's the case that most of the people I know are not actually like that. But look, it's not a bad working assumption if you're a policy economist, right? And so I think more about then what you can do in respect of institutional arrangements and policy guidelines and whatever to protect yourself or to protect the system from that, right? So, all right, you know, we can lament that people are greedy and we can lament that greed encourages people
Starting point is 04:02:55 to behave dishonestly. But isn't there something that we can do to protect government, protect taxpayers, protect citizens against that? Now, the big issue in defence procurement, for as long as I had any visibility on it, our determination, infatuation actually, with bespoke assets, the development of bespoke assets. It cannot possibly be the case that a piece of military hardware used anywhere else in the world is suitable for Australian conditions,
Starting point is 04:03:40 even if we have no intention of ever using it in Australia but could only ever deploy it to a foreign battlefield. What were the origins of that infatuation? Isn't that a great question? And I don't know the answer to that question even though I saw it play out time and time and time again. It is possible that those running that line. So that's all about it would be a mistake, Prime Minister,
Starting point is 04:04:11 to build an off-the-shelf product. We have to build it here. Now, because there is no off-the-shelf product that suits us. Was that a bullshit argument that was really motivated by a desire to protect local industry jobs? Yeah, probably. I'm not sure, but quite probably. And when you look at the connections between the military and domestic suppliers,
Starting point is 04:04:45 that's plausible, right? And you look at, as in the US, that military people on leaving military positions tend to pop up in jobs, in supply firms. Yeah, well, you know, it's plausible. It's plausible that what's at play there is the protection of domestic industry jobs. But I remember having this conversation with somebody
Starting point is 04:05:19 who used to run defence procurement, and his take on it was that, yes, well, that may be true, but then on the other hand, doesn't it make sense for Australia to sustain a capability in the construction of military assets? Because you never know, right? And the answer to that question has to be, well because you never know, right? And the answer to that question has to be, well, yes, okay, right? Of course it does, right? So the policy challenge here is actually quite tricky. In many cases, the policy conclusion would be buy off the shelf.
Starting point is 04:06:12 But then on the other hand, there is a policy argument for sustaining a local build capability, not of everything, but, you know, who knows of what? We just don't know, right? So that's how I think the policy issue should be should be dealt with and there shouldn't be um and it should be dealt with in an open in an open way right we are we are we really are trying to sustain this domestic industry capability yes we are and we're not going we're not making any secret of that we're not trying to hide that um but that's why we're doing it we're not doing it because australia is unique uh and needs heavily modified things knowing that there's a very high probability that the
Starting point is 04:06:54 modifications are going to lead to extraordinary cost overruns and time overruns and in some cases and there are some cases i'm aware of where it's rendered the asset completely inoperable and it's had to be scrapped. And I'm talking about projects worth more than a billion dollars, but I'm not going to name them. The economist Vernon Smith had on my podcast a couple of years ago. As a factoid, he actually shared the Nobel Prize with Danny Kahneman. They got it the same year.
Starting point is 04:07:30 Yep. So he wrote a book on the US housing bubble a few years after the Great Recession. And he argued that the Bipartisan Taxpayer Relief Act of 1997, Clinton's Act, which exempted home resales from capital gains taxes, is like the prime suspect for the trigger that caused the US housing bubble because suddenly you have this kind of exogenous shift where people start to view homes as a speculative asset. You mean they've become more Australian?
Starting point is 04:08:07 Is that what this question's about? I think you can see where I'm going. I guess, like, let me phrase it this way. To the extent that, well, at least in the 2000s, Australian house prices were overvalued or certain housing markets in Australia were frothy. Could we tell a similar story? Could we say that the Howard government's decision
Starting point is 04:08:26 to halve the rate of the capital gains tax in 1999 was the trigger for some, I'll call it whatever you want, bubble or valuation, et cetera? I think we'd have to say it had a significant impact. Yeah. Would that be the prime suspect? Prime suspect. I don't know.
Starting point is 04:08:47 There's a few things at play here, right? So in my view, definitely one of them, right? So prior to that, we had capital gains tax indexation. So the cost base of the acquired asset was indexed along the CPI, and you paid capital gains tax on the difference between the sale price and the index cost base, right? So you pay capital gains tax on the – but full, at full marginal rates, on the real gain, the bid over inflation.
Starting point is 04:09:26 Now, in high inflationary times, that is where the CPI is rocketing and house prices are just kind of chugging along, that means you get a lot of protection from having to pay capital gains tax. But, of course, if monetary policy is effective and the Reserve Bank is successful in keeping inflation within the range of 2% to 3% on average over the site, well, even let's leave it there. If keeping it within that range of 2% to 3%,
Starting point is 04:10:00 then there are going to be many times, at least Australian history suggests, there are going to be many times at least australian history suggests are going to be many times in which um it would be rational even to expect that house price growth is going to result in uh very substantial real gains and of course the howard government change did mean that those real gains would be taxed at a much lower rate, right? Basically, half the rate, right? Most of the gain would be taxed at half the rate it would have been taxed at previously. That's with respect to rental property. And of course, owner-occupier property has always been exempt, right?
Starting point is 04:10:36 Back from 19 September 1985, has always been exempt. And so you've got, you had particularly through those, I don't know, through the years 2001, 2002, 2003, I mean, we were dealing with accelerating house prices through those years. to say that the capital gains tax decision played a significant role in what was happening in the housing market, because what we saw was a lot of people jumping into investor housing. I mean, there was more debt being taken on by households around occupier housing as well, but there was strong investor interest. And we've seen that strong investor interest in every house price run up in the subsequent period, every one of them. Whenever the house prices take off, investors pile in.
Starting point is 04:11:36 And those investors have got a blend of debt finance and increasingly, increasingly pretty close to 100% equity acquisition because they're baby boomers who have retired and are wondering where they're going to put all of that cash that they didn't manage to get into a tax-preferred superannuation vehicle, right? Where are they going to put it? Put it in investor housing. You won't have the interest deduction that you would have had
Starting point is 04:12:07 had your debt financed. You know what? You're going to make a capital gain and you're going to walk away laughing because only half the capital gain will be included in your taxable income. Yeah, I think it's a significant part of the story. And also, and it was in the way that you phrased the question, I mean this idea that what's motivating it
Starting point is 04:12:28 is speculation is, I think, true. It's true. I think what happens when these house prices accelerate is the people who jump into the market are jumping in for speculative reasons. It's not too much of an oversimplification to say that everyone who's negatively gearing is by definition speculating. No.
Starting point is 04:12:55 No, probably not. Probably not. Because after all, it's an investor asset if it's negatively geared, right? So we're not talking about anarcho-pars. But you're also losing money on the carry, so presumably you think you'll make it back in price appreciation. You got it, right? I mean, otherwise it's nuts.
Starting point is 04:13:14 Yeah. And I don't believe that people who are doing this are mad, right? Quite the converse. And I remember having discussions about this around the Reserve Bank board table from time to time and just saying, well, what, if anything, can the Reserve Bank do about this? After all, it's not its mandate to control house price inflation. Its mandate is to look at consumer price inflation and keep consumer
Starting point is 04:13:41 price inflation between that target band of 2% to 3%. Okay, on average over the cycle. But with respect to speculative assets, including property, it has no particular mandate other than to wring its hands and be worried that if bubbles burst, they could cause some instability in the financial system, which is a concern, and they could lead to broader macroeconomic impact, so affect the economy more generally,
Starting point is 04:14:17 which would be a concern of the Reserve Bank. But the Reserve Bank does does not to date anyway have instruments at its disposal that would allow to address asset price inflation as opposed to consumer price inflation now we have in recent years under the present governor seen some use of so-called macro prudential instruments. These are instruments that APRA holds, not the Reserve Bank. If it is the case that the Reserve Bank, and we don't know because we've never been told, but if it is the case that the Reserve Bank has been leaning on or instructing or in some way influencing APRA to make use of those macroprudential instruments, then that's a curious thing, right?
Starting point is 04:15:11 Because that's, and I presume that is what's happening and I'm not being critical of it either, but it doesn't sit well with the idea that the board of the Reserve Bank determines monetary policy in Australia and exercises monetary policy independently. Yeah. I mean, I guess I kind of empathise with the difficulty of the Reserve Bank situation in the sense that if on the one hand you say to them that it's
Starting point is 04:15:40 not their mandate to lean against the wind, then if they find themselves in a situation where they're very concerned about a build-up of household debt, presumably there's got to be some other way of addressing that. Oh, no, no, no. Don't get me wrong. I'm not being critical of them. I'm not being critical of them.
Starting point is 04:15:56 I'm not saying you are. No, no, no. I think the position is, well, it's not, I guess it's not diabolical, but it's a very difficult position that they're in. And I can understand why they would be from time to time very concerned about asset price inflation, particularly speculative-driven asset price inflation. And of course, it makes perfectly good sense
Starting point is 04:16:20 that they'd be concerned about that. But if their only instrument is the overnight cash rate, the target cash rate of interest, then they are simply not capable of dealing with that issue. I mean, if house prices have been running, have been increasing at 15% per annum for, let's say, three years. And there are several periods in Australia's recent history where you can see that.
Starting point is 04:16:50 It's highly likely that people who are purchasing property as a speculative asset have got in mind that for some time, house prices are going to continue to increase in double digits, right? So at what rate, to what level are you going to have to lift? Suppose they do have a mortgage. To what rate are you going to have to lift the overnight cash rate of interest to convince them that that's a dumb thing to do? And the answer, I think, on every occasion I've looked at it,
Starting point is 04:17:27 is that you'd have to lift the cash rate of interest to a level that would generate a recession because it would just kill the rest of the economy. So that's the problem. You need additional instruments. And it makes sense. You've got now more than one target you got a target for consumer price inflation you got a target now for speculative assets
Starting point is 04:17:52 a speculative asset price inflation you're probably going to need more than one instrument yeah mm-hmm Tinbergen real Tinbergen yeah yeah one goal one instrument mm-hmm um not to to spend too much time on this, but I mean, I think it's now quite clear that the Reserve Bank did consciously lean against the wind in the early 2000s. Was that the right decision in those circumstances? Yes. Whatever you think of like-
Starting point is 04:18:21 No, no, no, I do. No, no, no. Well, I was on the board at the time. How could I say otherwise? But no, I do. No, no, no. Well, I was on the board at the time. How could I say otherwise? But no, I do think it was the right thing to do. They actually did more than that, right? There was an exercise of what's collectively referred to as jawboning.
Starting point is 04:18:37 You know, so Governor McFarlane was out there publicly talking about the risks, all right? One should not, I forget the precise words, it doesn't really matter, but it was to the effect that you should not, nobody should assume that house prices are going to increase at these rates forever. And those who are operating with that premise in mind are taking on an increasing risk, right?
Starting point is 04:19:03 And during that period, of course, I know even people you'd talk to socially would say to you, but house prices never fall. That's how poorly informed markets can be, right? So house prices never fall. It's a one-way bet, right? Hmm. I mean, in more recent times, I think there's a broader appreciation of the fact that there is a significant risk that house prices could fall and could fall by quite a lot, right? And you may find yourself in negative equity territory, having to sell a house and recover less than what you owe the bank.
Starting point is 04:19:43 And I think that's, you think that people find that really confronting. I mean, that's not part of the Australian mindset. But then neither is it part of the Australian mindset that you should expect to lose money when you find yourself in front of a poker machine. But anyway. Okay. Last question.
Starting point is 04:20:12 I think for me, this is one of the more interesting questions. But let's see what you think. Why hasn't Australia taken a populist turn to the same extent as the US or UK? I think the jury's still out. Do you have any explanations as to why it hasn't happened so far? I think there have been periods at which we have been at considerable risk of doing so. Yeah, so, gee, how do I answer this question
Starting point is 04:20:57 without getting really, really personal about particular, you know. Look, the risk is obviously on the right, let's call it the right side of politics. Pretty much, I think, because the issues that left-wing populists have been able to exploit in other countries are not as obvious here. So we do have income inequality, of course we do. And we do have wealth inequality, of course we do. And the wealth inequality is probably increasing, yeah. But we have also, we avoided much of the global financial crisis, right? Whereas in North America and Europe, that really brought these issues to everybody's consciousness, right?
Starting point is 04:21:56 And that's when you had the Occupy Wall Street movement and so on, right? As a consequence of that. And it really gave voice to, I know they're not all left wing and actually some of them are right wing, but anyway, it gave voice to disaffected elements that are a bit more extreme than what you see in Australia. So I think that's part of the story. And the challenge that I think the left side of politics finds itself dealing with in Australia is really a challenge from, it's more from the environmental movement, right?
Starting point is 04:22:38 And that's not an extreme or populist challenge at all. It's actually a deeply conservative challenge, if you think about it, because it's motivated by conservation. It's motivated by a desire to protect what we have, what we have left. And it's a movement that would like to see government do more, not less. So I think it's more on the, I think the risk for Australia is more on the right side of the political spectrum than it is on the left.
Starting point is 04:23:19 And there was a time in the 1990s when I think the major political parties on the right side of politics were deeply concerned about what was happening there and how to deal with what was happening there. And what do you do? I mean, you either ignore it, and there's a good reason for ignoring it, which in economics, I don't know what they call it
Starting point is 04:23:49 in political science, I don't know, but in economics it's referred to as Hotelling's Rule on spatial location, really. Are you familiar with Hotelling's Rule? So the simple idea is you've got your town is just a ribbon development, right? So you've just got one road running through the town and you've got two stores and they sell the same. Well, they don't necessarily sell the same product,
Starting point is 04:24:14 but actually part of our tellings rule is that they will sell the same product. But anyway, two general stores, right? And where do they locate? And let's start with the proposition that one locates at the western end of the town and the other one locates at the eastern end of the town. That being the case, either one of them would have an incentive to move closer to the centre because if they move closer to the centre, so let's suppose the one at the western end of the town moves closer to the centre, they will
Starting point is 04:24:41 retain all of the customers to their west and they'll get half of the customers to their east, right? And so they end up side by side. Converging. Right in the middle. And they end up selling exactly the same products and being located in exactly the same place. It's a place and this is why duopolies end up with identical behaviour, blah, blah, blah, right?
Starting point is 04:25:01 So that's hoteling's rule. And in political science, I don't think they call it that, but they've got the same proposition, that it makes sense for the, if you've got two major political parties, it makes sense for them to sit in the centre, right, with virtually indistinguishable policies. And for many, many policies in Australia, for many years now, that's what you've seen. It's exactly what you've seen.
Starting point is 04:25:30 So if you were in charge of running, had responsibility for the right wing of that political system, and you saw an extreme right movement out there, a valid response is to ignore it. political system and you saw an extreme right movement out there, a valid response is to ignore it because, after all, it's not as if those people are going to jump all the way and direct their preferences to the left side of politics. That ain't going to happen. So provided they remain a fringe group or a small group,
Starting point is 04:26:03 you're going to end up with their preference flow anyway. You don't get that in the United States. There's no such thing as a preference flow, right? In any way, voting is optional, right? But with exhaustive preferential voting and compulsory voting, such as we have in Australia, it's a legitimate thing, a valid thing to do, maybe a smart thing to do, to just ignore what's happening out there and just rely
Starting point is 04:26:26 on getting their preferences eventually at the end of the day. Trouble is, that relies on a lot of people being able to hold their nerve, right, and there's something else. And, look, I'm no expert on the Liberal Party, but remember the Liberal Party is a... Well, if you go right back to the formation of the Liberal Party, I mean, for goodness sake, you had the free traders and the protectionists get together.
Starting point is 04:27:01 I mean, and they got together in order to produce a party that was in opposition to the Labor Party. That was the only reason they got together. And you've got free traders and protectionists in the same party. It's not going to be happy on policy. We'll never be happy on policy, right? And so that was in the party that predated the Liberal Party, but it still is in the Liberal Party.
Starting point is 04:27:38 You've got both free traders and you've got protectionists and you've got so-called moderates and you've got right-wingers and you've got, you know, I mean, you've got everything there, right, everything that's non-Labour, which I think basically means don't like trade unions. I think that's what it means, which seemed to be a disappearing issue. And so the question for the moment is really about the identity of the Liberal Party. I think it is. And if you'd like to see the Liberal Party remain attractive
Starting point is 04:28:21 to those who tend to be a bit right-wing in their thinking, you're going to want to keep the stake in the ground right there, right? Because if you follow the alternative that I was describing earlier, that the hotelings rule would drive you to, when you see the emergence of a political party in the extreme right, that would push you further to the centre, further to the left, right? That would be the smart thing to do, according to our tellings rule.
Starting point is 04:28:55 But if you're ideologically really uncomfortable with that and you can only ever imagine yourself occupying the right, then you're going to seek to do battle with the extremists on the right. And I think that's the real risk. The real risk in Australia, I think, is that in these terms, and I don't want to overstate it, but I think it is nevertheless a risk, is that a principal, a major political party, decides that it wants to occupy an extreme position over there
Starting point is 04:29:28 on the right, and that's what's happened to the Republican Party in the United States. I don't think we should rule it out as a risk, even though I think it's a low probability outcome. But then what is a higher probability outcome? A higher probability outcome is probably that the Liberal Party becomes a different party. Maybe it formally dissolves the coalition arrangement
Starting point is 04:29:55 with the National Party. Doesn't mean it would not, obviously doesn't mean it wouldn't seek to rely upon the support of the National Party for supply, informing government following an election. I mean, that's how coalitions operate around the world in many, many countries, right? But they're not, they don't see themselves as being part of the same party and they just come together in a marriage
Starting point is 04:30:22 of convenience. Coalitions are very unstable. Very unstable. And that's a possible future for Australia. Yeah. Can I, so yeah, that's all super interesting and makes complete sense. I also just want to offer one speculative explanation for why we've avoided the same levels of populism as the US and the UK have experienced and get your reaction
Starting point is 04:30:52 to it. Because I think it's an underrated explanation and maybe someone listening can do this as an honest thesis or something, but we're a highly urbanized country. This is an exaggeration, but you could almost say that Australia's population is distributed like bimodally. You have a lot of people in rural centers and then most people in the massive conurbations. Yeah. And we don't have that middle category of like the medium-sized cities that you have
Starting point is 04:31:21 in the US and the UK. Oh, wow. You think they're all redneck cities, do you? No, no, no, no. But what I do think is when globalization and automation kind of hollowed out the manufacturing centers, so say in the UK, that's like Sheffield in the US, Dayton, St. Louis, Milwaukee, you have large swathes of the population disaffected, angry,
Starting point is 04:31:48 suffering the indignity of unemployment. Yeah, this is really interesting. And that's dry tinder waiting for a demagogue. Yeah, yeah, yeah. We don't have that. And to complicate this picture further, the Australian cities, which would have a legitimate claim to kind of bang our versions of Detroit and Sheffield, have actually maintained
Starting point is 04:32:14 their progressive identities. That's true. Newcastle, Wollongong, Geelong, Adelaide. Yeah. So it's a puzzle, but I think it's worth thinking about. I don't know if you have any reactions. I do, I do, I do. No, I like it's worth thinking about. I don't know if you have any reactions. I do, I do, I do. No, I like it.
Starting point is 04:32:26 I like it. I do like it. And it's certainly true. You travel through, yeah, you're absolutely right. You travel through North America. You travel through the United Kingdom. I mean, you see those rust belts exactly. Yeah.
Starting point is 04:32:38 And these are the cities that kind of turned against the European Union and the UK and voted for Brexit en masse. I see the same thing playing out in Scotland too. It's the other way around. But, you know, people I think still blame Maggie Thatcher for the closure of the shipyards up there or something. Somebody was trying to explain this to me. They said they'll always vote Labour.
Starting point is 04:33:03 They'll always vote Labour. Yeah, right. I don't know whether that's true or not, but they intended to. Yeah. So, no, that makes perfectly good sense. And it comes back to something that we were discussing earlier, right, which is about the dangers, the risks associated with people losing their jobs, losing their self-esteem,
Starting point is 04:33:29 losing their capabilities to, well, actually to function properly in society. And, yeah, I mean, that's fertile ground for the demagogues, as you say. Absolutely. Sure. So, no, I find that quite an attractive, if also unattractive, explanation. Yep. Good.
Starting point is 04:33:51 Ken, this has officially been my longest podcast ever. Oh, my goodness. But I have enjoyed every minute. Thank you so much. No, it's been a pleasure. I don't often get to talk to anybody about these issues and certainly not in this depth and length. And I never get questions of this quality. So there you go. Thank you. It's my honor. Thank you. things before you go. First, for links, show notes, and the episode transcript, go to my website, thejspod.com. That's thejspod.com. And finally, if you think the conversations I'm having are
Starting point is 04:34:32 worth sharing, I'd be deeply grateful if you sent this episode or the show to a friend. Message it to them, email them, drop a link in a WhatsApp group. The primary way these conversations reach more people is through my listeners sharing them. Thanks again. Until next time. Ciao.

There aren't comments yet for this episode. Click on any sentence in the transcript to leave a comment.