The Joe Walker Podcast - Peter Tulip — What Will It Actually Take to Solve the Housing Crisis? [Aus. Policy Series - LIVE]
Episode Date: March 25, 2025This episode is the fifth instalment of my Australian policy series, recorded live in Sydney on February 12, 2025. I speak with Peter Tulip—Chief Economist at the Centre for Independent Studies,... and a former senior researcher at both the Reserve Bank of Australia and the US Federal Reserve. We go deep into what's driving Australia's housing crisis, the problems with heritage rules and height restrictions, critiques of both NIMBY and YIMBY thinking, the sobering 10–20-year timeframe that even an “extremely ambitious” supply plan might require, and the cultural shift needed to reach a new equilibrium where housing is truly abundant.See omnystudio.com/listener for privacy information.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Hey everyone, a quick note before we begin the episode.
This is a recording from one of my live Australian policy salons, so the conversation is held
in front of a live audience and we have some audience questions at the end too.
To my American, British and other overseas listeners, you might find these Australian
policy episodes a bit parochial.
Or not, I'm sure many of you will find them interesting anyway and you're
of course welcome to come along for the ride. I'll be back to my usual style of episodes
with a more international focus after this series. One last thing before we get started,
this conversation contains some visual elements which occur part way through, so it's best
watched on video. If you'd like to watch the video, the easiest
way to do that is to go to my YouTube channel, just search Joseph Noel Walker in YouTube.
And if you could also subscribe, that would be a great help to me too. Enjoy.
Okay, thank you all for coming. Before we start the conversation, I want to place it
in a broader historical context.
So for most of human history, the stuff we needed was scarce, and because it was scarce,
it was expensive.
This was true until quite recently.
Economic historians tell us that in 15th century England, about 80% of personal spending went
to food, with 20% of that on bread alone.
But since the Industrial Revolution and thanks to innovation, the human story has largely
become one of ever-increasing abundance.
We know this because the price of the things we need measured in terms of how many hours
work it takes to buy them, from bread to cars to televisions, has been falling, often steeply,
over time.
But one particular durable good has broken this pattern of progress, housing.
It's become a fact of life that the cost of the structures we live in, or more accurately
the land underneath them, keeps rising even as the prices of the stuff we fill them with
keep dropping.
Over the last quarter century, Australia's house price to income
ratio has roughly tripled, depending on how you measure it. And according to the latest
demographia report, Sydney and Melbourne are the second and seventh least affordable cities
on the planet. Australia's unaffordable housing market has meant that too many of us have
to live too far from the jobs in which would be most productive.
It means that we have to shoulder enormous debts or live with the precarity of renting.
It means that we don't get to live close to our friends or relatives.
It delays family formation, contributes to urban sprawl.
Australia's housing crisis is the defining social policy disaster of our times.
But I won't belabor this point. Presumably, you're all here because you agree.
Rather, the real questions are what's causing it and how do we fix it?
To help us answer these questions, we have joining us one of Australia's
leading experts in the economics of housing.
Peter Chulip is chief economist at the Centre for Independent Studies. Before that,
he was a Senior Researcher at the Reserve Bank of Australia and at the US Federal Reserve.
As a mere corpora, I used to be much more concerned about the re-emergence of a housing
bubble in Australia. But it was largely through reading Peter's work and engaging with Peter
that I became convinced that that isn't the
main issue today. The main issue is rather one of constricted housing supply. So it's
a pleasure to have Peter finally on the podcast. Peter, welcome to the show.
Thanks, Joe. Good to be here.
So since you left the Reserve Bank, we've caught up for a beer or coffee every couple
of years. And I'm hoping tonight's conversation can be the latest iteration in our series of chats,
but with two major differences.
Number one, we have an audience this time.
Number two, I'm gonna try and dial up
the disagreement tonight.
Are you ready?
We'll pretend.
So first question, constricted housing supply
isn't a problem just in Australia.
It's also a problem just in Australia.
It's also a problem in the US, the UK, Canada, New Zealand, Ireland.
So what's your general theory as to why this phenomenon seems to be common across the Anglosphere
in particular?
It's a good question and I actually don't know the answer.
One thing that many English speaking countries have in common is high rates of immigration.
So the pressures on us to supply more housing are much stronger and clearer than they are
in many other countries.
But that's a partial answer and there are a lot of exceptions on both sides to that.
A common argument is that the English tradition, the English-speaking government and culture,
that tradition places a lot of emphasis on local control and it gives neighbouring residents a lot of say as to what you can build on your property.
And that, as we'll get into,
gives rise to all sorts of terrible problems.
But it's a good question,
which I don't know that anyone's had a good answer to.
So if we go back to the 1970s, correct me if I'm wrong,
but I think this is when zoning regulations
start to become a problem for countries like Australia.
Do you know what the historical shift was
or what was it that happened beginning around the 1970s
that saw these rules start to pile up?
So in Australia, a lot of it was,
we had in fact much stronger population growth in the 1960s
and 1970s.
But this was an era in which people were getting cars, and you could do car-based sprawl relatively
inexpensively, and it was attractive going out to the suburbs. But as those commutes went from one hours to two hours
to even three hours in some cases,
people said, this is crazy.
We have to stop going out, we have to start going up.
And that's combined with just the natural size of cities.
I mean, sort of as Melbourne and Sydney got up to three,
four, now five million people, you can't go out,
you have to go up. And as
you go up, the zoning restrictions are much more severe and much harder to get around.
So again, it's a good, difficult question, to which I don't know that the research supplies
a clear answer. There isn't any dramatic legislative change.
Well, sorry, there are changes, but they're in different times in different states and in
different countries. So it's difficult to tell a story directly attributing it to any clear
institutional change. It's just this unfortunate combination that, well, a simple way of putting it, over
a period of several generations, demand for housing seems to have been increasing about
3 per cent a year, whereas the supply has just been increasing about 2 per cent a year.
And so demand is just continually outstripping supply. And there are lots of cycles about this rising trend, but that incompatibility between supply
and demand means that prices have to rise over time.
Thinking about what motivates the typical NIMBY in Australia, if we go to the literature,
there are two distinct sets of motivations.
One is the kind of home voter hypothesis, which says that NIMBYs are selfishly trying to protect their home equity values.
The other is the kind of neighborhood defenders hypothesis, which says that NIMBYs are actually acting altruistically on behalf of their neighborhoods to kind of protect the amenity and local character of those neighbourhoods.
Which of those two motivations is more accurate?
The statistics seem to show that the second story is more important.
That there are lots of glaring exceptions to the rule that NIMBYs are selfish, sorry, financially motivated.
For example, lots of renters seem to be NIMBYs. And that very naturally lends
itself to the second story you talked about of just wanting to protect their
neighborhood. I think it's a mix of, well, obviously it's a big mix and lots of NIMBYs have different motivations.
I think the financial story matters most
in that the story people like I are trying to sell
is that Australian society would be better off
if houses were more affordable.
That is if house prices fell. And that's an unattractive and unconvincing argument to people whose entire wealth is in
housing. So it's hard to make the case to a majority of voters because of the financial
factors. Consistent with your second story about being
neighborhood defenders.
It's consistent with that, but putting it in
slightly different words.
A lot of it, I think, is just fear of the
unknown.
That and in
particularly you see this because just
I and I imagine many others have had the
experience of hearing
neighbors or friends or relatives say,
we strongly oppose the development at the local shops, but now that we see it, it's actually not that bad.
And we like the new cafes and the restaurants and the more frequent bus service.
And it's very common to hear stories of people changing their mind once they see the actual product, which suggests, if not irrationality,
that people were worried that these developments
are gonna turn out much worse than they actually do.
So a kind of status quo bias.
Yes, very much so.
And in fact, Brian Kaplan, who I think has been a guest on a previous
episode of US, he strongly emphasizes the status quo bias, that it's strongly demonstrated
in the psychological literature that people will strongly prefer the status quo to changes,
regardless of the relative merits of the alternatives.
And that seems to be clearly a factor in housing also.
It does feel kind of difficult to falsify
the home voter hypothesis though, right?
Because I mean, people are always going to cloak
even selfish financially motivated concerns
in altruistic language.
You're not going to persuade a local council by saying,
I wanna protect my home equity values.
You're gonna say, I wanna protect the unique character
of the neighbourhood.
Yeah, well, yes, there's clearly a lot of bad faith in this.
One thing we haven't mentioned is a lot of existing residents
don't like the new people
that would be coming into a neighborhood
if flats were built, partly for ethnic reasons,
partly for class reasons.
And that's probably more important in mixed race societies
like the US than it is in Australia.
But again, that seems to be a very strong motivation.
But again, the opponents don't like to word it that way
because it's socially unacceptable.
So you do get a lot of the rhetoric
about neighbourhood character
that's actually quite difficult to believe.
Right.
So a little bit earlier,
you mentioned that home equity values
are more important at the kind of state or federal policy level.
I just want to make sure I'm understanding correctly.
So it seems like, OK, maybe these amenity concerns are relevant to the local level.
But when we're talking about national policy or state policy, it's the home equity concerns that are more relevant? No, I was, the argument I was trying to make was that home equity just is a counter argument
to what I, to my argument that we need to improve affordability.
I see.
That when I say that, it becomes fairly clear to most people that I'm talking about a reduction
in their wealth.
Yeah. And they say, oh, in that case, it's nowhere near as attractive. Absolutely. becomes fairly clear to most people that I'm talking about a reduction in their wealth.
And they say, oh, in that case,
it's no end here is attractive.
Absolutely.
I have several questions on this,
but I'll save them for kind of more towards
the end of our chat.
So next question, obviously not all zoning regulations
represent a deadweight loss, right?
So there's this classic example of Houston.
I think Joe Stieglitz wrote
about it in his book last year, but Houston has very light zoning regulations and you have situations
where there are like kink friendly adult stores right next to preschools. So when you think about
zoning regulations in Australia or maybe you want to just narrow it to New South Wales, whichever you like, how many of them,
or which ones are on your chopping block?
Height restrictions are the worst.
Okay.
That because it's understandable that as density spreads
and encroaches into detached housing neighborhoods,
that it will change the character of those neighbourhoods
in a way that going up does not.
Especially around train stations,
there's a huge demand to live within walking distance
of train stations.
People will pay top dollar for it.
It doesn't really change the character of the neighbourhood.
These are already busy, lively areas.
And that is, and yeah, I mean,
and what I'm saying is not new to anyone.
I mean, this is a standard argument
in the planning literature that we want more
transport-oriented development, and that's what the New South Wales and Victorian governments
are very strongly pushing, and I strongly agree with that. I think that priority is exactly right.
So height restrictions are the worst. Okay. What would come after that?
So heritage restrictions are not super important,
but they are pretty stupid.
That everyone agrees that we want to protect,
preserve buildings that are unusually old
or unusually attractive.
But our heritage laws go far beyond that,
protecting huge swathes, I mean, entire suburbs
in some cases, of what's pretty ordinary housing.
And the legislation imposes these restrictions
without consideration of costs or benefits.
It's just some architectural ex- well, they call it an expert in the fact they're hired guns,
says, you know, this ordinary suburban, you know, Californian bungalow is architecturally distinctive.
And so it gets a do not build stamp on it.
I mean, it's important in the old suburbs
of Sydney and Melbourne,
I mean, which is a minority of council areas.
So it's not decisive to the affordability,
but it is, yeah, that's at the top of my list.
So height restrictions and heritage.
So I'm sure you probably have some other regulations
that would warrant being placed on the chopping block,
but let's just start with those two.
So I wanna understand the maximum kind of upside here
if we've got rid of those zoning regulations.
So you have a paper with Ross Kendall, which shows that zoning's contribution to house
prices was 42% in Sydney, 41% in Melbourne.
Then you had a later paper with Keaton Jenner, which showed that zoning's contribution to
apartment prices was 41% in Sydney, 16% in Melbourne.
But obviously that doesn't necessarily mean prices would fall by that much without zoning apartment prices, 41% in Sydney, 16% in Melbourne.
But obviously that doesn't necessarily mean prices
would fall by that much without zoning,
because these are just partial equilibrium models.
But you're not kind of building a larger model
of the economy that looks at what would actually happen
to supply and demand if you remove zoning restrictions.
But could you still help me understand,
what's the kind of ballpark upside here
for how much we could bring prices down
if we got rid of height restrictions,
we got rid of some of those heritage laws?
What can we look forward to?
So the other really big thing we would need to do,
which is directly relevant,
in particular to the paper I did
with Ross Kendall, is we need to allow detached houses, or what Americans call single-family
houses, with medium and high density.
And that, in fact, has been where the real payoff has come in New Zealand has done is leading the world in changing
zoning regulations. And they've done it largely through townhouses. The huge swathes of Auckland
and parts of Wellington are being replaced with two and three storey, relatively densely packed buildings. And as a result, I mean, their construction has doubled
in those industries.
The housing stocks increased by several percentage points.
Prices have fallen by, I think the estimate is about 28%
in Auckland and 21% in Lower Hutt,
which is the leading municipality
of Wellington that's done this.
So that's, I'll add that to the list of reforms
that needs to be done.
So sorry, just before you go on,
that's kind of, that's zoning as conventionally defined.
Correct.
Yeah, because I'm conscious in this conversation,
both you and I will probably use zoning to refer to,
really the broader set of what might be called
planning restrictions, but the kind of, probably use zoning to refer to really the broader set of what might be called planning
restrictions.
But the kind of what can you use this land for is traditionally what's meant by zoning.
So you're adding zoning, heritage, height restrictions.
So then, Gabe, we cut these things.
Change all of those.
So those estimates of the zoning effect, we called it, I mean, I think they are a reasonable approximation
to what would happen to housing prices in those cities.
If you were to completely liberalize the markets.
Now, but that's not what we're suggesting.
To be politically realistic,
our aims are much more moderate than that.
But ultimately, if you would take it to extremes,
that's where it would hit.
Yes.
And so how much more moderate are your aims than that?
So I think the national cabinet target of 1.2 million homes
over five years is sensible. That is, I mean, the numbers that we were talking
about before with this pure free market deregulation
would involve something like 10 or 20% increase
in the housing stock in Australia.
And you clearly can't do that overnight.
In fact, you can't do it within
any reasonable planning period.
But you can build a lot more.
And the national target of 1.2 million homes
essentially takes the previous peak in construction
that we saw before the pandemic and said, let's
hope we can do that on a sustained basis. And that strikes me as a feasible short-term
objective, feasible both economically because we've built at that rate before, but also
politically in the sense that
the community accepted those rates
of construction in the past.
I can run the numbers on what that would mean
for affordability if you want.
Yeah.
Okay, so one million homes is sort of a baseline neutral,
is a neutral baseline.
And that was the original target. And so the National Cabinet
target of 1.2 million homes is 200,000 on top of it. We have a national housing stock of 11 trillion
homes. So those 200,000 is about, with a bit of rounding, 2% increase in the national housing stock.
As a rough rule of thumb, every percentage point increase in the housing stock reduces
the cost of housing by about 2.5%, so that 2% increment that National Cabinet is targeting
would give you a 5% reduction in affordability.
That is relative to a baseline of housing prices trending up.
So in real terms, house prices outpace inflation by about 2.5 percent over a very long average. It's more or less than that
depending on exactly when you take the average from. So you take five percent over five years
from that and we're still and prices are still increasing in nominal terms. Right. So it's not
five percent lower than today's prices, it's five percent lower than the counterfactual in nominal terms. Right. So it's not 5% lower than today's prices, it's 5% lower than
the counterfactual in five years. Yeah, 5% lower than what was a pretty unattractive counterfactual
of continually deteriorating affordability. This feels like an incredibly thoroughly modest
achievement. It's a start. Right. It's a start and if we can get everyone agreeing
that affordability is a problem
and the way to solve it is to set,
I'm gonna call it an ambitious target
and start meeting that,
then that's somewhere to build on.
And as I said, one of the constraints
is the capacity of the construction industry.
That is, it's just very difficult
to ramp that up very quickly.
We can go back to what it was in the previous cycle.
Let's get there and then talk about
increasing it even further.
But that's beyond this five year horizon.
I see.
So I don't quite know the best way
to phrase this next question,
but I wanna try and understand what the worst case scenario
is if we don't allow housing supply to be more responsive.
So say we, I don't know,
continue with the current trajectory of net migration,
maybe interest rates stay
about where they are at the moment, how much worse can it get? So how much, I
don't know, how much worse can the price to income ratio get? Go to San Francisco
or Manhattan or London. In particular, I mean the numbers on all of
these things are very sensitive to how big you'd define those cities.
But if you go to the central neighborhoods of those cities,
the only way you can afford housing there is to inherit it
or to win the lottery or to run a high tech company.
And as a result, you see all the disastrous consequences of unaffordable housing.
Homelessness is terrible in those cities.
The social divisions are severe.
All the young people are leaving.
All the entrepreneurial dynamic people are leaving, all the entrepreneurial dynamic people are
leaving. It's very bad for their productivity growth. The inequality is terrible. There's
all sorts of terrible problems. But they're an example of, yeah, things can get worse
and in some places on the globe they have. Right. It can get even worse. It can always
get worse. Well, and that's the way we're trending.
Sure, sure.
So like you, I would consider myself a Yimbi.
But I said I would try and dial up the disagreement
in this conversation.
So I want to try and push a couple of critiques
of the Yimbi movement and get your reaction.
Sure.
So the first critique is, at least as I see it,
there are two broad objectives in the YIMBY movement.
One is to make housing more affordable by increasing supply.
And the other is to get these gains from agglomeration
by densifying our cities.
And the problem is there's an interaction or tension
between those two objectives.
Because if you increase supply and densify
cities, the gains of agglomeration make it even more attractive to live in those cities.
So people become even more productive, that's reflected in higher incomes, and those incomes
ultimately push up prices and rents.
Now YIMBYs will tell me that the supply effects just dominate the agglomeration effects.
And I'm perfectly happy to accept that.
And you've mentioned your rule of thumb that in Australia about a 1% increase in supply
will lower prices, average prices by about 2.5%.
Meanwhile, I think doubling city size gets us pretty modest productivity gains.
So if that's true, doesn't this mean that the Yimmy movement is just massively overstating
the gains of agglomeration objective?
Productivity isn't everything, but it's almost everything someone said once.
Paul Krugman said it.
Don't dismiss gains in productivity. That's the big thing that drives living standards.
If you can do anything to boost productivity,
then you've got a policy that is more clearly advantageous
than most of what governments do.
Right. I don't mean to contest that productivity is important. I'm saying that building supply
is just a really slow means of actually getting those productivity gains.
Sure. Yes, I agree. I mean, the big,, well for me, okay, so the MB movement is a very broad
coalition. I mean there are a few members here today and some of them come from the
far left of the spectrum and some come from the far right and some are very difficult
to categorise. And so they have a lot of different views. But, and I'm not sure that'll buy
into your description of what they say. But I think where they does unite them is the
sense that more housing supply will improve affordability. And that is one of the very top social problems in Australia at the
moment.
And so it may, it will have a lot of other effects on a lot of other variables but if
you can improve housing affordability then that's enough.
Second critique, so let's talk about how we might improve the movement at its current margins.
Recently I've been thinking, what are the major bottlenecks that YIMBYs are not paying
enough attention to?
And it seems to me like the major bottleneck is that YIMBYs don't acknowledge the importance
of aesthetics and architecture.
And I think that's because they're always fighting people who cynically invoke heritage concerns.
And so they've developed this thick skin.
They don't want to admit that beauty is important,
but I think it is.
And unfortunately, I mean,
the survey evidence kind of goes both ways,
but I just have this deep intuition
that if the mid-rises and high-rises that we built
were just as beautiful as the old heritage buildings, people would be much more accepting of those mid-rises and high-rises that we built were just as beautiful as the old heritage buildings,
people would be much more accepting
of those mid-rises and high-rises.
And I don't know, here's one anecdote.
Recently, I was chatting with Sam Hughes.
He's one of the three guys who was a co-author
of that UK Foundations essay.
He was saying that, so Ben Southwood,
another one of the authors, published this report
a few years ago about doubling the height of all of the heritage buildings in South
Tottenham.
And I'm told it was met with universal acclaim.
And it seems like that was because there were very strict design codes in this plan.
And if there weren't, people wouldn't have been as accepting.
So what do you, I mean, what's your reaction to this idea
that Yimbi should be thinking a lot more
about the importance of aesthetics and architecture?
And you want to get your beautiful buildings
by some government committee of bureaucrats?
Well, I mean, so last year I had a conversation with Lucy Turnbull
and she was pointing out how all of the lovely terraces in Paddington,
the inner suburbs of Sydney, were all built with pattern books
in the late 19th century.
So why can't we have pattern books that they make it easy,
you know, any kind of builder can follow them
and you just get these very nice consistent designs.
Yeah, so it's a genuine issue and
Okay, so one common argument is that tastes stiffer, right?
But I mean, I think there's pretty general agreement
People go to Paris and almost everyone agrees. It's a beautiful city. Mm-hmm
It's typically seven storey
apartments everywhere and then they cross the channel to London and universally agree that
all the buildings are ugly. You spoke, asked earlier about the English speaking tradition.
spoke asked earlier about the English speaking tradition.
We build ugly buildings.
And I don't know why that is.
And so as a result I don't know how to put that in legislation.
You can't call Baron Haussmann back from the 1870s and say do it again.
We don't know how to get a city filled with beautiful buildings.
I mean, I think it's a genuine question. The big problem is that I don't think it's representative of the overwhelming majority of planning debates we have in Australian cities. That in particular the Minns and Allen governments, talking about transport oriented development.
Okay, so most people here are from Sydney.
Many of you will have caught the train in from a typical suburban Sydney train station, which is surrounded by two story shops.
And no one is going to call them attractive.
Almost no one. I mean, I'm not gonna claim that your typical block of flats is a marvel of art and aesthetics,
but it's not demonstrably worse
than the stuff that it's replacing.
If people want to design beautiful buildings,
I have no objection to that,
nor do I know how you go about doing it.
Yeah, I think to begin with you need...
But I do know that preserving mediocre suburban tracts of land is not how you get beautiful
buildings. I will say one other thing, though. What makes attractive streetscapes is not how you get beautiful buildings. I will say one other thing there. What makes attractive streetscapes
is not the age of the buildings,
it's not even the appearance of the buildings, it's trees.
And there's huge amounts of evidence
that streets with trees, everyone likes.
And so the argument about aesthetics really is how do we get more trees?
It's not an argument about which buildings we have or don't have.
Okay.
And upzoning a suburb where you're, okay, so the way you get more trees, the big enemy of trees
is overhead wires in most of suburbia. And the way you get rid of that is to bury them.
Ordinarily, that's very costly. But if you're upzoning a neighbourhood, then you're disconnecting
all the utilities and digging up the pavements anyway, the marginal cost of burying
the wires is quite is relatively low and that's your opportunity to put in tall trees that,
okay, for 10 years or so won't be much but in 50 years will be magnificent.
Right, okay, I'll grant you the trees.
I still think facades are important, though.
I want to try and prove this right now
with a very non-scientific poll.
So I've printed out some images of different facades.
I'm going to ask our lovely audience to vote
on which ones they prefer.
So I'm going to give, we'll do two sets of two alternatives.
And I just want show off hands.
The question will be,
which facade do you personally find more beautiful?
So, okay.
Do you want me to hold one and you hold the other?
No, it's okay.
You're my guest.
I'll do this.
I just need to work out what the comparisons are.
So, okay.
Here's the first set of facades.
So, okay.
Raise your hand if you prefer this one.
Okay.
Raise your hand if you prefer this one.
All right.
So that was the loser and that was the winner.
We'll do the second set.
So again, here are the two facades.
So again, here are the two facades.
Okay, now raise your hand if you prefer this one.
All right, raise your hand if you prefer this one. Okay, so the clear winner of the first was this,
which is a Victorian terrace from Potots Point, probably made in the late
19th century. And the other clear winner was this, which is a house mania apartment from
Paris made in the sometime in the mid 19th century. The two losers are two of the three winners of the New South Wales government's 2024
Mid-rise apartment competition.
I rest my case.
So one issue is you can't put car parking with a houseman apartment.
They look great, and in fact I lived in one, but they have functional problems that the demand doesn't exist.
But anyway, okay, I mean that's an interesting question for architects and planners to decide.
I mean how do we get our blocks of flats looking a bit more attractive?
That's not the policy question facing Australia. No one is, almost no one
is talking about pulling down house and apartments. What they're talking about is pulling down
Californian bungalows and just large areas of detached suburban red brick or fibro housing.
That's the relevant policy question.
And I wish we had a slide of that.
Well, in fact, we don't need a slide of that because as you go down,
I mean, I think there's a shop underneath here selling postcards.
And you'll see, okay, when you go to Paris,
you see lots of postcards of all the house and apartments.
Nobody takes postcards of Roseville suburban houses.
And that's the housing that we're protecting that really no one actually considers as especially attractive.
Sure, sure. My point is just if the IMI movement wants more mid-rises and high-rises, people would be much more accepting of that if they were as beautiful as some of these other buildings.
I have no objection to it. Beautiful buildings.
Fantastic. Great. Well, I think we've made progress.
So next question, in anticipation of some possible questions from our audience on
negative gearing
and the capital gains tax discount. I just want to put to you how I understand the significance
of those tax concessions and then you can edit my story or tell me if you think it's
correct. So what's important is the interaction of the two. And until the capital gains tax discount was introduced in 1999,
negative gearing had proven to be a mostly insufficient incentive for property investing.
But as soon as we had both, what it meant was that property was disproportionately favored.
Although the capital gains tax discount applies across any asset class, obviously, property is
the one that is much more leveraged.
And what that meant was that the gains of a property investment
were taxed at precisely half the rate at which the costs were
subsidized.
So it really capped the downsides of property investing
relative to the upsides.
And I think what that meant is that there
was a new kind of fundamental value for housing.
And in moving to that new equilibrium,
a lot of investors overreacted to that. A lot of momentum traders were, so to speak,
were attracted to the market. And we have these kind of like self-sustaining price rises in the
early 2000s that created that little, you said the big word, created a little bubble we had in the early 2000s. But then if you
come to today, the impact of those two tax concessions working in concert is very small.
So a lot of the research shows that somewhere between one and four percent of prices are
attributable to negative gearing and the capital gains tax discount. So that's my story. Does that make sense?
Is there anything you'd change?
Yes.
The big problem with thinking the changes in taxes of 25 years
ago lit a fire under the housing market
is that you had huge increases in house prices all around the world, and
especially in those English speaking countries you mentioned earlier, in Canada, the United
States, the United Kingdom, New Zealand, and many other countries, house prices all took
off.
We have a good explanation for that.
World global interest rates and in particular long-term interest rates,
will falling and we know both empirical and theoretical reasons
that that will drive house prices up.
So what happened?
Okay, there are residuals around it, but the basic story is not really a surprise.
What's puzzling is if people somehow think
Australia is different because of its tax concessions. It wasn't. Since then
prices have more than doubled depending on how you measure it and your
benchmark and the tax concessions are worth between one and four 4%. So you took off those tax concessions,
what did it take us back to our prices where we were in June?
Where we were having exactly the same conversation.
I mean, I think there are good reasons for looking at the tax concessions
and in particular capital gains on the taxation of capital gains on housing.
Right, the sort of equity concerns.
And fiscal policy reasons and tax policy considerations.
I mean, it was brought in by,
there was a review by the Ralph Committee in 1999
that recommended these changes.
I don't think things have turned out
the way that committee recommended.
I think there is a good argument for revisiting these provisions, but it doesn't belong in
a conversation on housing affordability.
So capital gains tax discount and negative gearing can't explain all or most of that
early 2000s run up because similar run ups were happening
in other countries around the world.
So we need some kind of common factor to explain it.
Which we have.
Yeah, interest rates.
Okay, so I wanna talk about your policy goal.
Yep.
And your transition plan.
Okay.
So, just to briefly understand your policy goal
and sort of a 30 second answer here is plenty,
but do you want to see prices fall
or do you just want to see growth slow?
I would like housing to be much more affordable.
And that is essentially the ratio of prices or rents
to incomes.
You could achieve big improvements in affordability by holding prices
and rents flat at their current nominal levels and let incomes keep rising by three or four
percent a year. We should be so lucky to get that. Current policy is not delivering that.
So I'd like us to be doing a lot more.
Talking about long-term objectives,
this is, I'm not sure it's relevant.
Yeah, I mean, I would like,
and I think we ultimately could get
very big increases in affordability,
we ultimately could get very big increases in affordability.
But to be relevant, the main question is we need to be building more.
And so we need to have some downwards pressure
on prices and rents, which we don't currently have.
So earlier in our conversation,
you mentioned that to get those kind of 40% price falls
in Sydney and Melbourne, it would require increasing housing supply by, did you say
10 to 20%?
Yep.
How many years would that take, roughly speaking?
Well...
Have we gotten rid of those zoning regulations on the chopping block?
As a simple calculation, if we increase the housing stock 1% a year, it would take 10
to 20 years.
That's doing it over and above what we'd normally do.
Okay.
So over and above the current baseline?
Yeah.
Okay.
And?
But even that is extremely ambitious.
I mean, so what the national target that we talked about before is an increase of 200,000 above baseline over five years.
So that's what, 40,000, just 40,000 a year.
Yeah.
So if we removed all of the zoning regulations
on your chopping block,
how quickly do you think we would get that 10 to 20 percent increase in supply?
No one has bothered to do that calculation, I think for good reasons.
What are the reasons?
It's just not realistic.
It's not realistic and it's not on the agenda.
And no one is proposing it. Yeah, I don't I'm not proposing
Substantial or immediate changes to the legislation or the process or how we approve houses
The all we need to do is relatively simple
Under existing processes we need to set higher targets for local councils
That will add up to 1.2 million homes. So that's being done in the New South
Wales and Victorian governments. And that just means local councils need to start approving
a block of flats in every third or fourth suburb every few years.
every few years. Relatively modest changes in the built form of our city will over time amount to a substantial increase in supply. And you don't need any change. I mean, there are good reasons
for changing the process, but they're not necessary to deliver housing affordability. We just need councils to stop saying no and
start saying yes. And that can be achieved. I think what the New South Wales and Victorian
governments are doing is basically right. They've set, they're setting ambitious targets for councils.
The next step that they need to take is to announce how they will be enforced,
which hasn't been done yet.
And there is a real worry that once these plans are lodged before councils, councils
will start saying no, and then you do get a fight between the state government and the
councils.
And it's not clear that the state governments
have the stomach for that. So I'd like them to pre-announce automatic remedies for councils that
don't make satisfactory progress towards their targets. But even if we do achieve that national cabinet target of 1.2 million new homes over five years,
you're saying that it's only going to lower prices about five percent relative to the counterfactual.
And that is ambitious. I mean, if that's and I kind of I buy your point that realistically,
that's probably as good as we can expect from our
political system.
I'm now just kind of feeling a bit deflated listening to you.
It feels like we're not we're actually not going to solve the housing crisis.
All the people who say we should be cutting immigration, they're probably right.
Like that seems like the only solution.
So 5% reduction after five years, but then you do it again the following five years.
And that adds up to a 10% reduction,
and so on.
I mean, this was a problem that built up over generations.
So it is going to be very difficult to solve it quickly.
It will take time, particularly as it requires a very substantial increase in our construction
industry, which has difficulties.
I mean, we can do it.
Other countries have done it.
Auckland doubled its construction workforce,
but it will take time and requires changes to training
and immigration and accreditation and wages.
Do you think over those five year intervals,
we can ratchet up the amount of supply we provide each time?
Is that the kind of base case?
I would hope so.
Okay.
And do you think that's more likely than the opposite?
I guess maybe people come to accept it
or people realize it's working
so you can add more supply each time.
That's a good question. or people realize it's working so you can add more supply each time?
That's a good question. I mean, so what's happened in Auckland
is you've had two effects.
One is people have seen that it works,
that rents are substantially lit,
have risen substantially less in Auckland
than in other New Zealand cities,
but at the same time you've got a backlash that some people think that the new buildings going
up are ugly and there's this fear of change element we talked about before and it very often
happens that when you change what people are used to,
they're uncomfortable with that and they object.
Right.
And how those two balance, we don't know.
Right.
So it certainly feels as though achieving that 1.2 million homes
over five years target is going to require a lot of political will.
If we want to do even better than that,
it's going to require even more political will.
I want to talk to you about what your transition plan is.
Because the expectation that your home equity values
will increase handsomely over the course of your lifetime
is so deeply entrenched in Australian society
and so entwined with how people plan
for how they'll build wealth, how they'll
retire that it seems like you need to have that conversation with them and offer them
some kind of alternative.
Let me just kind of quantify how deeply entrenched this really is in Australian society.
So obviously there's a home ownership rate of about 65%.
I think that equates to about 10 million Australians who own their own homes.
Our residential real estate market amounts to about $11 trillion in total, which is about
three times the size of the total value of the pool of superannuation. And people view
their homes as nest eggs. Older people think that's what they'll use to retire on when they downsize.
Younger people think that's how they'll build wealth.
Obviously tax concessions enable this.
Primary residences aren't subject to capital gains taxes.
They're not subject to the pension assets test.
You also have a lot of mom and dad property investors.
So on the last ATO data,
about 15% of Australian taxpayers
own at least one investment property.
Half of those taxpayers are negatively geared.
So in other words, most of them are probably only invested
because they're expecting capital appreciation.
And property is the largest source
of net capital gains in Australia.
I think it accounts for about, again, on the last tax data, maybe about 40% of capital gains.
So property is the way the middle class builds wealth in Australia.
What's the Peter Chulip alternative?
You're talking about this as though it's somehow normal and natural, which it's not.
I don't think it's good.
I mean, this is mainly a Sydney
culture, where the affordability problem is terrible. Okay. And the culture changes depending
on what the property market does. There are... Okay, it is true that housing is also very expensive in the other big cities, but as you go to small cities
and regional centres, the housing becomes affordable.
And those people are perfectly normal and natural and they have a sensible culture.
It adjusts when the prices adjust.
And I don't think people that live in regional towns, where you can get a large
family house for just a few hundred thousand dollars, just a fraction of what it costs
in Sydney, that they somehow think their wealth accumulation is unnatural or there's something
wrong with it. I mean, they save in other ways.
That's great. But I think you still have to convince the homeowner and constituency, or politicians will need to. That is definitely true. And you mentioned
before that two thirds of Australians own their own home. And that's perceived. A lot of people think that they, as a result,
you won't get a majority voting for lower house prices.
And there's a strong element and of truth in that,
but what it misses is that those homeowners
care about their kids.
And they are aware that the housing market we have at the moment is locking their children out of the opportunities that previous generations had, and that that's unfair.
And it's also driving the kids away from the neighborhoods they grew up.
away from the neighborhoods they grew up.
And so the wealthy homeowners in Sydney's affluent suburbs,
the North Shore Eastern suburbs in the West
have to ask themselves the question, do I want to drive to Bathurst to babysit the grandkids?
And many of them will not want to do that.
And so they will want a housing market
that lets the rest of their family
live near where they grew up.
Right.
So if we want to achieve this political compact
between all these different groups in society, all these different stakeholders.
I wonder why we haven't tried anything like the Hawke Government's accord, but for housing.
Do you think that would be a good idea and why hasn't it happened already? been agreement on what needs to be done. That, I mean, so a lot of the conversation we have
just been having are ideas that were not in circulation even a few years ago, you mentioned the Yimbi movement,
which has grown from zero to being one of the more
influential grassroots movements in current society.
Right, only in the last kind of three or so years, right?
Two years, well, Dom, when did Sydney Yimbi launch?
About just a year and a half ago?
Coming up on three years today.
Yeah. And, you know, with Canberra and Melbourne a little before that, Brisbane a bit after.
Yeah. And so that, so one reason we haven't had this national conversation or the national accord, and we still have,
and I think what I'm saying is very widely accepted
amongst economists, but there are important people
in this debate who are not economists,
who don't trust market forces, and in particular large
numbers of town planners and architects, and in particular the academics who assume the
role of spokesmen for those professions, actually very sceptical that you can rely
on the market to improve affordability.
So there's not agreement that this needs to be done and there's certainly not agreement
that house prices need to fall.
So in five years time we realised this was all too politically challenging and the
boosting supply, cutting zoning project has failed.
Where would you refocus your energies? What's the second best set of reforms? Is it land value taxes or what is it?
At the moment we're winning.
So I'm I've had no reason to think about your question. We've gone from,
I mean, very substantial opposition to
the ideas that I was saying or what the Yimby's were saying
just a few years ago to now substantial,
I'm not sure you'd call it,
whether it's a majority depends on how you measure it,
to very substantial agreement.
So the pendulum is all our way.
Yeah, the question is what happens if we're too successful?
Hypothetically, what would be the second best set of reforms?
I'd work on something else.
Give up on housing?
So, the...
Housing reforms.
Sydney is a great place to live, except for two things.
House prices and traffic.
So, number two is congestion pricing. Right, right. But I'm asking about housing reforms specifically.
Like if the kind of boosting supply agenda
through de-zoning fails, what else have you got?
Yeah, no, it's a disaster.
You're right.
Great.
Well, I've left plenty of time.
Well, actually, I've left plenty of time.
Well, actually I'm running exactly on time.
So we've got time now for audience questions.
If you'd like to ask a question, just stick your hand up and we'll get a mic to you.
I'm going to prescribe three things.
As always, my two heuristics for asking good questions.
Please ask a question to which you genuinely want to hear the answer.
And secondly, the more specific your question, the better.
Also add a third thing, just think of the clearest and most concise
version of your question and just say that don't cycle through three different
articulations of the same question.
So hands up and we'll get a mic to you.
This episode is sponsored by Eucalyptus, the Aussie startup providing
digital healthcare clinics to help patients around the world take control of their quality of life.
But this message isn't about Eucalyptus' products.
You see, Australia stands at a crossroads.
The world order is unraveling.
We're likely entering an era of intense geopolitical instability, the likes of which we haven't
seen since our grandparents or great grandparents days.
Meanwhile, our decades old economic paradigm of housing and mining is running on fumes.
And our culture of indefinite optimism, as instantiated in the she'll be right attitude
and our disproportionate love of gambling, has become a ball and chain.
If we want to keep our prosperity and security, we need to build, to think smarter, to choose
ambition and excellence.
But how?
We can't look passively to politics for solutions, the policy-making apparatus is straining,
incapable of delivering the kind of leadership or reforms that we extracted from the system
at our last major crossroads in the early 1980s.
As an individual, what can you do?
I maintain that more talented young Australians should be thinking
about building valuable new companies.
Building a startup can be one of the highest leverage ways to help both
Australia and humanity because innovation powers economic growth and a wealthy society is a more just
and more secure society,
a society in control of its future.
This doesn't have to mean being a founder,
you can still make a large counterfactual impact
by joining an early stage or well-funded startup.
That's what I did as an early employee at Forage,
a Sydney-born US-based ed tech startup.
It was the most intense period of my life.
We scaled the company, helped millions of students, and I formed
lifelong bonds with colleagues.
So if you're an ambitious young person, wondering what to do with your career.
While your decision is a deeply personal one, let this message
plant a seed in your mind.
Consider joining a well-funded startup like Eucalyptus or
any other excellent
startup. You can check out Eucalyptus' open roles at eucalyptus.health
slash careers. That's E-U-C-A-L-Y-P-T-U-S dot health slash careers.
This episode is sponsored by Vanta. Trust isn't just earned, it's demanded.
Whether you're a startup founder navigating your first audit
or a seasoned security professional scaling your GRC program,
proving your commitment to security
has never been more critical or more complex.
That's where Vanta comes in.
Businesses use Vanta to establish trust
by automating compliance needs across over 35 frameworks
like SOC 2 and ISO 27001,
centralized security workflows, complete questionnaires up to five times faster, and proactively manage
vendor risk.
I have personal experience here.
Startups I've worked out have used Vanta, and I've always found it reliable.
Vanta can help you start or scale your security program by connecting you with auditors and
experts to conduct your audit and set up your security program quickly.
Plus, with automation and AI throughout the platform, Vanta gives you time back so you
can focus on building your company.
Join over 9,000 global companies like Atlassian, Dovetail, and FireAnt who use Vanta to manage
risk and
prove security in real time.
For a limited time, get $1,000 off Vanta at vanta.com slash joe.
That's V-A-N-T-A dot com slash J-O-E for $1,000 off.
Just go just there in the front row.
My question was about the transition question, which I think was an interesting one.
And my observation is that the pain of the transition is not all, in fact, most homeowners
aren't exposed to it.
If you've got a fully paid off house, then you sort of own a unit of housing.
So it seems that's probably a smaller problem for highly leveraged millennials such as myself.
And do you not think that we can solve that with a more targeted solution?
A good way of rephrasing what Tom says is that most homeowners are sitting on hundreds of thousands, possibly even millions of dollars
of net worth.
And the prospect of that not growing quickly is not something that should really worry
us.
That these are people that have benefited enormously over if they've owned a home for any period of time.
And so the fact that they're upset that their wealth doesn't keep growing is not a big problem.
Is that a good paraphrase?
And I agree.
Great.
Next question.
Maybe we'll just go across to Mitch in the front row.
You've spoken about this briefly, but there's some literature suggesting the general public
is either skeptical that increasing housing supply will lower house and rent prices or
even actively believes the opposite, that more housing will push prices up.
Most economists see it as fairly obvious that increasing supply will lower prices. Do you have any thoughts on why this belief persists and should policymakers and public
intellectuals be doing more to correct it, to reduce opposition, to create a development?
Yes, it's a really important question because this supply scepticism is one of the biggest
obstacles we have to better housing policy.
For those who don't know, opinion polls, when they ask people, would extra supply in your
neighborhood raise prices, lower them or keep them about the same? The answers tend to be about a
third, a third, a third. So a third of the public gives what economists would think
is exactly the wrong answer, that they say extra supply
is actually gonna make prices worse.
And so obviously selling them on the idea of extra supply
to improve affordability is very difficult.
And interestingly, you get pretty much exact the same opinion poll
results in Australian polls as in the United States, a third, a third, a third.
The...and why that arises is difficult to say. I think one factor is that when economists are talking about an increase
in supply, it's natural for them to think that they're holding everything else constant.
And so you're talking about a policy experiment where, for a given level of demand, we dump
a few thousand more apartments in an area. But that's not what the general public sees or thinks of when they're thinking about
increases in supply. They see these extra thousand apartments go up and almost invariably where they
have gone up has been in response to stronger demand. And so the actual the correlation
And so the actual correlation goes the other way. That extra supply is often associated with higher prices.
And the general public sees that.
And so they think that that's what's going to happen if more apartments appear.
And that is obviously realistic and consistent with their experience, but we need to explain
to them that observation isn't what's relevant to an experiment where for a given level of
demand we increase supply.
And the empirical evidence that that will improve affordability is just extremely strong.
Great. David.
Thanks again. Wonderful commentary. So on the financial issues, particularly the capital gains issues, you know, one of the serious simple ways of thinking about it is, look, there's two thirds of Australian households that own a home.
They like having the capital gains as one third that don't, and they complain because
the prices are going up.
But if you actually go to those young people, and I've asked many young people who are currently
renters and say, well, you know, you're currently renting, you've got home, you've got housing
services, you're living in a place and doing what you need, why are you so passionate about
owning a home?
They say, ah, because I want to get on the property ladder, meaning I want to start getting
the capital gains as well.
So if you go to them and say, well, think of a government that would come along and
say, I'll tell you what, you know, instead of quibbling about the price, let's just do
enough policies to keep the prices flat, no capital gains for the next 30 years.
Suddenly they lose all interest in buying a house.
So the question is, these people that were complaining about, look, I want to get in, it's too expensive, are
they just quibbling about the price? Whereas as soon as they've got it, then they want
the highest rate of capital gain and offload it to the next poor chap that comes in after
them and make their capital gain. In other words, do we really have any constituents that truly want to keep house prices low
and not have this continued wealth generation strategy, at least here in Sydney?
I think the premise of your question is incorrect.
That we do see housing markets without rapidly exploding prices, in particular in the South and Midwest of the United States.
And in fact, those areas tend to have higher home ownership
that people are more willing to buy a home
or maybe more accurately,
are more able to buy a home if prices are low,
even though they don't get the capital gains
that people in San Francisco and New York are enjoying.
So I don't think that that's an obstacle.
And in fact, I think if prices were more affordable, young home buyers would actually enjoy that.
But do they have a history of knowing that's the way to make your wealth over time and
comparing it against that?
That's the key question.
Once that's embedded, I think it was Joe's question, once that psychology is embedded,
how do you get out of it, including for the people that would like to buy a home and jump
on the bandwagon?
If you and Chris supply the price will fall.
Okay, let's just go behind you, David,
and then we'll work our way back.
So we were discussing the aesthetics
of how the homes that we want to look at
are quite different to the homes we seem to be building.
I wonder how much of that,
and I'm not sure if you would know the answer to this,
but how much of that, and I'm not sure if you would know the answer to this, but how much of that might be that the houses are built to be sold,
either to people who want to live in them or to people who want to rent them out.
And the houses that people want to live in might be quite different to the houses that people want to look at,
and yet the houses that people want to live in are the ones that actually get built because those are the ones that, you know,
the money comes into building.
Yeah, there is a clear externality in housing.
I mean, as there are with cars and clothing
and all sorts of other property.
I mean, we don't insist that our neighbours wear nice clothes
or drive attractive cars.
Yeah, so there is an externality there. The available evidence suggests that it's worth
very little to people. That people much prefer a comfortable, affordable house
to a house surrounded by pretty buildings.
So with one qualification to that, people will pay a lot more for a
neighborhood with a lot of trees.
They do consider that to be attractive.
The other the other buildings.
It's hard to see that in an effect of that in the data.
How big is the tree premium?
I can't I can't remember. But substantial. Alright, next question. Let's go to Tim. On the topic of externalities in
housing, so if there is a disproportionately negative externality
to me, if I'm in the suburb that's proactive
about adding housing and another suburb is not as proactive, why can't the government
just compensate me for that negative externality and say, yeah, that was nice of you guys to
let more housing in.
We're going to actually, because no one's giving that property right to those people.
And sort of Coase's theorem in economics would say if you had that property right, you solved
the problem.
Yeah.
So many housing economists in Britain in particular pushing that argument, in particular arguing
for street votes to allow developers to essentially buy out the neighbors.
I'd be, I'd like to see that as an experiment.
I am skeptical that it would have much effect,
partly because the opponents of housing
deny that they're doing it for any financial reason.
But yeah, maybe that maybe would change. Anyway, I mean, I'd like to see it tried.
But I'm skeptical that it would have big effects. What would it take to get street votes up in
Australia? Would you would it be, change New South Wales legislation?
State thing?
That's a good question. I don't know.
Next question. Yeah, we'll go to the guy in the hat.
Joe mentioned earlier, we don't have to worry about agglomeration offsetting the supply
effect because it's quite slow within a city. But the agglomeration benefits between
cities is realized immediately when you move. And so since the premium on say apartments is so much
bigger in Sydney than it is in Brisbane, would we expect that like New South Wales or Sydney has a
version of the free rider effect where if we increase the supply of apartments and you offset
that zoning impact and bring prices down significantly, you'll get interstate migration that essentially offsets that because they realize the agglomeration straight away.
There's a mix of effects in your question.
One is the effect of interstate migration.
What happens if one state or one city up zones and other states don't?
And we're sort of seeing that in reverse at the moment, that a lot of
people, in particular young people, are leaving Sydney. And it ties in with what you said about
productivity, because the people that are leaving tend to be our most dynamic entrepreneurial citizens.
So that's bad for our city's productivity. And that's a strong, and that's an argument for why we need central government control
to coordinate the up zone to up zone everywhere.
Responses to prices are going to be much, much larger than responses to productivity.
That, I mean, just in terms of the magnitudes that, I can't remember what you said about the effect
on productivity and supply.
A 10% increase in supply maybe boosts productivity 1%, but it's going to have a 25% change in
affordability in prices.
And that's what's really gonna drive
the interstate migration.
Right.
And it is a factor, but because of the price differentials
rather than the productivity differentials.
Why are the state governments so ineffectual
versus the councils?
And is there anything the state or federal governments
can do about that?
and is there anything the state or federal governments can do about that? So state governments have not had the stomach for a fight with councils in large part.
Historically, that was because I don't think they had the votes behind them. That is changing now and we now have state governments in New South
Wales and Victoria that are committed to housing policies that are being strongly opposed by some and what happens when decisions start being made
that where the state and local councils disagree,
we don't know what's going to happen there.
The state governments have said they're going to push it
through and insist that the councils meet their targets.
What happens when the councils start saying no remains
to be tested?
Does that answer the question?
Sorry.
Well, no, it clearly doesn't.
Is there anything else they can do?
It clearly doesn't answer the question.
Is there anything else they can do?
I mean, it seems that's actually how this problem gets addressed.
So I worry that we are heavily reliant on the courage
of politicians, which is something that's very variable.
And I would feel what the governments are doing
is much more secure if the remedies were pre-specified
in legislation and were automatic,
rather than relying on, I mean, I think the current setup
invites obstructionist councils to call the state government's bluff, which is sort of what
Kuringi Council did in 2020. They basically said to Rob Stokes, who was the then planning minister,
they basically said to Rob Stokes, who was the then Planning Minister, we're not interested in meeting your target. And anyhow, that process was unsatisfactory and I think we need
for the remedies to be automatic.
Right, let's go to Trent at the very back.
All right, let's go to Trent at the very back. Thanks.
I'm just wondering how much of the supply is being held back by what parts of the economy?
Is it councils?
How much?
Is it to do with the feasibility of developments?
And that's sort of to do with prices of land going up heaps,
and maybe construction costs or whatnot.
And then if you know how much zoning,
how far is supply away from zoning under current zoning?
So the constraints on the housing sector vary a lot
from area to area.
In the expensive areas of Sydney, it's a zoning issue.
Once you get west of Parramatta,
then the feasibility of apartment buildings
becomes quite marginal.
And of course, zoning is not an issue at all
for many country towns.
I mean, no one wants to build it,
put a skyscraper in Tiburrurra.
Even if they were allowed to,
it wouldn't make any difference.
But substantial bits of the outskirts of Sydney are similar to that. The high-rise housing is not feasible there. But there's still huge areas, I mean, but in the areas where people really want to live,
which are the inner suburbs, zoning is the constraint.
And so that's where we should be, we should focus of allowing the building where people
want to live, which is our inner suburbs.
Next question.
Somewhat related, you talk about construction constraints in regard to the 1.2 million houses
target.
But if you believe in market forces, largely all we need to do is make sure there are the
right incentives.
So if we were to enact your sort of zoning deregulation
wishlist, why don't you think there will be sufficient
incentives for the construction industry to respond
and actually build more housing?
So the construction industry in Australia
is extremely cyclical, more so than almost every other
sizeable industry.
From peak to trough, it will often go up and down 50%.
And we're seeing that again.
And every time you have a boom,
there are worries about where do we get the workers
that it's going to be difficult to ramp up construction.
that is going to be difficult to ramp up construction, but they get drawn from other areas of the economy.
And that does require adjustments in wages, adjustments in immigration, adjustments in
training.
But this is not a new problem.
I mean, this happens every cycle
and every cycle we address it.
That will need to be done now.
And it's not trivial.
It may not even be easy,
but it is a problem that we address every single cycle
and we manage to build a lot more houses.
And so if we were to go the other way as opposed to having a target and just kind of deregulate
zoning and not really worry about the target, like is that not feasible?
Yeah, no, well so that is, it's more than feasible.
I mean, in fact, that's sort of the New Zealand model where that rather than setting targets
for local councils, the central government said, we want all of these areas that were
reserved for detached housing, you now have to let townhouses be built there.
And these other areas, you now need to have apartment blocks there. And these other areas, you now need to lay out apartment blocks there. So there's
another, you can go two ways with upzoning. And my view is that you want to do a mix,
that they're setting a numerical target. But this, well, sorry, I should also say that's
what the transport oriented development is doing. It's specifying to local councils essentially the form of housing that
needs to be built in large areas. I think I've got away from your question but yeah I mean so
there is another approach and we don't actually know I mean there guesses, but you don't actually know how many dwellings
will be delivered by transport oriented development,
or even more so by the low to mid rise housing policy
that the government is pursuing,
or some of the other proposals.
So another lively agenda item is to allow granny flats.
You can pass legislation saying granny flats are legal everywhere,
which in fact Los Angeles has recently done.
It's you don't know the numerical response.
OK, next question.
So we're producing housing in a culture, a pretty decent clip compared to, you know,
everybody else according to various OECD reports, where, you know, like the top three or four
consistently and the other guys who are producing dwellings at a greater rate than us actually
flips around a lot. To me, that tells me that either
that, you know, it's the demand side, not the supply side, relative to everywhere else in the world,
is our issue. And so the question becomes, what is the right growth rate for the population?
What's the terminal? I know that we have a plan for Big Australia,
or there is a plan for Big Australia. What do we think is a fair terminal population,
given the constraints that we have with simple things like water, right?
Immigration policy is complicated with a lot of difficult trade-offs and very controversial and people have very different values driving all of that.
My view is that that is a separate conversation to housing policy, that we have a democratic process for making those trade-offs and deciding
those issues.
And whatever population outcome comes out of that, we then need to build enough houses
to accommodate them.
Okay, I mean, as I said, it's complicated.
There's a lot more that I could say that, but, and what you do on immigration clearly
changes the numbers for what you're doing on housing, but it never changes bad arguments
into good ones or good arguments into bad ones. So however we decide housing policy, the principles will
always be the same regardless of what we're doing on immigration.
Hey, so for transport-oriented development or feasible development, you need transport and a large
part of Australian cities don't have sufficient transport like the Northern Beaches here in
Sydney.
But there's also a lot of media commentary saying that large transport projects such
as Metro West in Sydney and the suburban rail loop is kind of crowding out housing through
competing with the workforce.
I was just wondering whether you think
this is a legitimate concern
and whether we should be building,
we're building the right amount of transport
to support housing or we should build building
more or less.
We need to better integrate our transport decisions
with our housing decisions.
That when you put a new rail line in,
such as the north out,
we've just put it out at the northwest suburbs,
and now we're building one to Bankstown,
that should always be accompanied
with high density at the stations.
The public transport and housing density
are complimentary goods,
that either of them by themselves will often be marginal,
but together they're an attractive package.
Both of them make the other worthwhile.
And so you mentioned the suburban rail loop in Canberra,
the tram out to Woden,
many cities are facing this issue of as they grow they need more public
transport. And in fact this is, we haven't mentioned federal politics much, but this is a very
important lever that Canberra should be playing, pulling on, because Canberra subsidises many of
these projects and it should only do so contingent on high
density being built at the train stations. Just on that, how likely is it
that that proposal gets adopted? I've not heard anyone in Canberra mention it so Okay. Unlikely. Okay. Okay. But hopefully that will change after tonight.
Right. Next question.
Oh, no, no, sorry. That's actually not quite right.
The federal opposition policy is to spend $5 billion on housing-friendly infrastructure,
which they think will unlock 500,000 houses.
Now, mainly they've been talking about roads and sewerage, which in fact are the biggest
infrastructure needs of housing. But in principle, those arguments apply just as much to public transport. So the opposition policy is very much along the lines
of what I was saying before of coupling infrastructure spending with housing. And
to just to be clear that I'm not partisan on this, while I say that the federal opposition
has a constructive useful housing policy, at a state level it's the opposite.
It's the Labour governments that are driving the country.
So the partisan mix is different between state and federal politics.
Is there some kind of structural explanation for that
or is that just random?
So there's a huge amount of randomness in this.
I mean, if you look at debates within the Labour Party,
the Liberal Party and the Greens,
there are very big divisions within each party.
You've got very strong yimbees and very strong nimbies
in each of the parties. So it does seem, I think it's random. I mean, I think there's
very large random element.
Interesting. Okay, so I think we've got time for about five more questions. We'll go there
and then back. Hi, Peter. Just picking up on the demand side issue from another perspective. So like house
prices, households have become a lot more indebted over the past 20, 30 years. Banks
provide the overwhelming majority of housing credit. They're encouraged to do so. It's secured, attractive risk weights and so on.
Australian banks' resilience is often predicated on the fact that housing is very safe and when
appra speak about stress testing banks, they often talk about the unlikelihood of house prices
falling significantly enough for banks to fall into trouble. So how do you weigh or how do you see the role of the financial system in causing
the housing unaffordability issue and how do you weigh any stability risks
associated with it?
So we know from the global financial crisis that big collapses in housing values
can have catastrophic effects on the financial system
and hence the economy.
So that's something we need to be worry about a lot.
The appropriate policy to deal with that
is to ensure high capital requirements of the banks
so that if they do start making large losses on their mortgage book,
that they have the equity to cover that.
And you need to do that pretty much regardless of whatever your housing policy is,
whether you're building a lot of houses or not many, you need unquestionably strong financial institutions.
So I think they're really separate policy questions.
Yeah. Yeah, sort of building on that, to what extent do you think that expanding access to credit
to buy houses is welfare improving?
It's mixed that we clearly have big obstacles to credit that seem to be inefficient.
You hear many stories of borrowers that
have been comfortably paying the rent
for a long period of time.
They decide to buy a house.
The interest payments are actually less than the rent.
And the bank says, no, you can't service the loan.
I think, appRA's financial regulations,
I mean, this is straying off housing policy,
but I'll take the opportunity.
APRA has a lot of just very silly financial regulations
that prevent borrowers and loans coming together
to make mutually advantageous trades.
If you were to expand credit, for example,
okay, so they just did it today
by loosening the HEXA arrangements
in how they measure serviceability.
But more importantly, Senator Andrew Bragg has an inquiry
that is suggesting reducing the 3 percent serviceability buffer. That would boost credit
and raise house prices. Were you to do that? I mean, there are strong arguments for doing that,
but if you wanted to avoid the affordability problems,
you would wanna couple that with measures to boost supply,
or you would take away some of the less defensible measures
that support demand, such as first homeowner grants. And so you could do a
demand neutral shift, allow more extra credit while reducing the first homeowner grants,
and that would be welfare improving. Maybe just to maybe put it the other way then,
would measures to reduce access to credit be welfare improving?
On their own?
These are people that are happy to pay well above the cost of supply for housing,
and you're telling them, no, you can't have it.
That's a large and clear welfare reduction.
Okay, so we can do about three more questions.
Yeah.
It appears to me at least that Australians
broadly trust institutions, experts and public servants,
especially on non-partisan issues
that don't get a lot of attention.
To what extent is our housing issue partly driven by the fact that until Proofish pushed into their face, people assumed that when Coorangai Council knocks back units, it's probably got a good reason
to do so, despite the fact that we probably both agree it's probably a pretty crap reason.
It's probably a pretty crap reason.
It's a good question. I don't know the answer. Sorry.
Yeah, I not I don't know. I haven't thought about it, to be honest. Sorry.
Do you have thoughts?
I think it's I think significant.
We have a lot. I think we have a lot of trust in institutions.
People don't usually think there's a lot of insidious things going on
in boring parts of public service, be it town planners, whatever. That doesn't's a lot of insidious things going on in boring parts of public
service, be it town planners, whatever, that doesn't get a lot of attention, especially
given that it doesn't get a lot of attention because the City of Morning Herald is not
usually covering a huge amount of local council stuff there.
So people just don't look at it to see that they're getting screwed.
Right.
Next question. Yeah, very back.
Are developer charges helpful?
And if not, what's a smarter way to finance the new infrastructure
that's required when you build more housing?
I like developer charges.
That we...
I like developer charges that if we were to get to a position where we were building more housing,
we have to decide where it goes. And one of the very important factors in that is
different locations, the cost of supplying housing is very different. It's relatively low cost to supply extra housing in the inner suburbs, sorry, low cost to the government because the infrastructure is already in place and there's a lot of excess capacity,
whereas it's extremely costly to do it the further you get from the city.
Water costs and the road costs in particular increase with distance from the centre.
And that is one of many factors that the government needs to concern.
Whereas setting targets for local councils,
we have to decide, do we want our extra housing
to be on the outskirts or in close?
And that's one factor.
I think it's a relatively small factor.
Oh, sorry.
And having developer charges makes it easier
to make the correct decision.
That the relevant decision makers will factor
the costs of different locations in.
I think it's greatly exaggerated including,
as Alan Koller did a 730 report the other day
where he was going on about the costs of providing housing
and the outskirts, the infrastructure, that's trivial relative to
the demand supply imbalance.
That in inner suburbs, people will pay, in some cases,
a million dollars over what it costs to supply the housing.
There's a huge excess demand in the inner suburbs,
whereas that margin is quite small on the outskirts.
And that is the decisive factor in terms of where we want to locate our housing. We should
be putting it where people want to live, not where utilities find it easy to link things up.
find it easy to link things up. Okay, who wants to do the final question?
Phil?
Yeah, you've been rather supportive of fringe housing, Greenfield over in Sydney, maybe
that makes sense, but all the Imbies kind of hate that. So just tell me why
you think fringe housing is still okay and what effects of the filtering effect have over
fringe housing if we build more in field housing. And you might want to explain the filtering effect
as well. Well I'm not sure what Phil means by filtering in this context. But why don't I answer the first question and then you can explain what you mean by the second one.
If the costs in particular of utilities
are properly charged for to the buyer,
then government should be relatively neutral
as to whether we have
green fields fielding on the outskirts
or high density infill in the inner suburbs. People can decide for themselves what housing suits them.
And when I say the costs need to be charged,
that includes externalities of carbon emissions and traffic and utility costs
and urban heat and there are a bunch of things you can think of as being relevant.
As much as possible we want to internalize them for buyers so that they can decide.
But I wouldn't want to say that I'm especially supportive of green fields in Sydney.
I mean, I think overwhelmingly the excess demand is for infill in the inner suburbs
and in particular, and we haven't talked about it much, but I think there's a lot of demand for high rise
in inner suburbs.
Where Greenfields is most attractive,
and the biggest priority is in regional towns.
That you have a lot of towns, particularly along the coast
in tourist areas and other attractive areas.
Where, so in Byron Bay is one example,
extreme but illustrative.
Land within the town of Byron Bay
can cost a million dollars for an average block.
And you can walk down the road
to get to horse paddocks or open fields
where the land sells for just a few percent of that.
And the difference is that the expensive land
is zoned residential and the really cheap land
is zoned rural.
And Byron Bay is having a housing crisis
and it's screwing down on Airbnb and other short-term accommodation.
A lot of shop assistants and cleaners can't work in town.
They're commuting.
They have 30- or 40-minute commutes,
driving through all those horse paddocks I mentioned to get to work, when they could easily be provided with land within walking distance of the CBD.
And that is a problem that I think runs up and down the coast of New South Wales, to an extent, Victoria and Queensland also.
And there, I mean, yeah, apartments in the CBD would be useful,
but the easy solution to that problem is Greenfields.
Just allow the towns to build out a bit more.
I mean, because you're still just a few kilometers from the center of the town.
And Phil, did you want to explain the filtering thing?
So if you're building in the inner city, people move one suburb closer and the effect of affordability reverberates throughout the whole city. So how important, like, can people put it
in their head that that is a lot more important than building a Greenfield suburb in Sydney? Like, by what
effect do you think, like how much dollars or whatever? I don't know an easy way of quantifying
it, but the principle is exactly right. That You build housing anywhere of any type
and it will make housing throughout
the whole market affordable.
That applies to locations, but also old versus new,
hot luxury versus down market,
down market, density versus detached.
On all of these margins, there's a lot of substitutability. And if you increase the supply of one kind of housing,
it makes all other kinds of housing more affordable.
Great.
That's a pretty important point to finish on.
So that's all we have time for, three quick things before we finish.
So firstly, we have only two more salons left in this series.
We'll be back here in two weeks with Sam Roggeveen from the Low Institute to talk about defense
policy.
And then in case any of you happen to be in Melbourne, we'll be in Melbourne on the 6th of March to talk with Judy Brett about Australia's political culture and compulsory
voting. Secondly, we've got some more food coming out. If you can stick around and have
a chat, that would be great. We had an event here with Andrew Lee a few weeks ago talking
about inequality, and I bought everyone a copy of Andrew's book. I bought an excess
number of copies. So there are a few left on that table there
if you'd like to grab a copy.
And then last but not least, Peter,
you've been patiently and articulately
educating the public about this issue for several years now.
Very grateful that you also gave up your time to educate us tonight.
Thank you so much, and please join me in showing Peter some appreciation.