The Joe Walker Podcast - The Moral Causes And Consequences Of Economic Growth — Benjamin M. Friedman
Episode Date: January 24, 2021Benjamin M. Friedman is widely recognised as one of the world's leading macroeconomists. He is currently the William Joseph Maier Professor of Political Economy at Harvard University.Read the full tra...nscript at: josephnoelwalker.com/ben-friedmanSee omnystudio.com/listener for privacy information.
Transcript
Discussion (0)
You're listening to the Jolly Swagman Podcast. Here's your host, Joe Walker.
Swagman and Swagettes, welcome back to the show. If you're new to the show, hi, I'm Joe.
Do make sure you subscribe or follow the show, depending on which podcast app you use, to ensure that you never miss new episodes.
We release them every Monday, Australian Eastern Standard Time, which is Sunday afternoon and evening for the Yanks and the Brits, respectively.
My guest for this episode is Benjamin Friedman. Ben is the William Joseph Meyer Professor of Political Economy
and formerly Chair of the Department of Economics at Harvard University. He is widely regarded as
one of the world's leading macroeconomists, and he is the author of several brilliant books,
including Day of Reckoning, The Consequences of American Economic Policy Under Reagan and After, The Moral Consequences
of Economic Growth, and most recently, Religion and the Rise of Capitalism.
I really enjoyed this conversation.
Ben is a gentleman and a scholar, and we speak about weighty topics, including especially
why economic growth matters for tolerance, social harmony, and democratic values,
and how religious thinking has imbued capitalism from its very inception.
I think you're going to find this interesting and enlightening.
So without much further ado, please welcome the great Ben Friedman.
Ben Friedman, welcome to the podcast.
Thank you. Delighted to be with you.
Ben, this is a real treat for me. You write the kind of books that I love. First, they're about
big questions. Second, they are interdisciplinary. And third, they are full of fascinating footnotes.
The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth, which was
first published in 2005, is one of my favorite books of all time. So when I heard that the author
had a new book coming out, which is titled Religion and the Rise of Capitalism,
and will be published on the 26th of January, which is Australia Day, I thought I have to
speak with him. And Ben, if it's okay with you, I'd like to touch on both books in this conversation. But before we do that, I thought that I would wind up going into law.
And I was very fortunate when I was a senior my last year at Harvard, I won a fellowship
to spend several years studying at the other Cambridge, Cambridge, England, where incidentally, for the first time,
I had the pleasure of meeting lots of Australians. We didn't have many at Harvard, but they certainly
did at Cambridge. And lots of my friends there were Australian, and that was a treat for me.
But in the course of my several years at Cambridge, I had to study something. And so I continued on with economics.
And the longer I went on with it, the more I realized that what I wanted to do was continue
with economics and do that for a career rather than go into law. So when I came back to the
United States after my fellowship ended, Instead of going to law school,
as I had originally planned, I came back and went to the Harvard Economics Department.
You taught Tyler Cowen, who has been a guest on this podcast,
PhD macro in 1984. Do you have any memories of Tyler as a student?
Not particularly. Our department, for better or worse, is very vertically oriented.
And so I'm a macroeconomist, and I interact very heavily with the students who are going into macroeconomics.
But then there's labor economics, there's international economics, there's economic theory, all of the various fields of economics.
Tyler was interested in game theory at that time.
And so he worked primarily with my colleague Tom Schelling, later a segment of the required first year course in
macroeconomic theory. All of our first year students have to take a full year of microeconomic
theory and a full year of macroeconomic theory. And each of those sequences is divided up into four pieces with four different
faculty members doing the teaching. And in those days, and for quite a few years after, I was
teaching one of the four segments of the required macroeconomic course for the first-year students.
And of course, Tyler was in it. And so I met him, but I only taught him for
six weeks and I didn't get to know him well. I've subsequently had interactions with him,
which have been a lot of fun. I like him. He's a very creative thinker.
Indeed. And that six weeks must have been impactful because Tyler has said that you
were one of his favorite teachers at Harvard. Which aspect of teaching itself is hardest to teach?
What aspect of teaching is hardest?
I think the part that I have found the most difficult over the years
is explaining to students ideas that I think are false.
In order to render our students well-educated,
we have to tell them what the menu of ideas is in the discipline. And my part of economics,
macroeconomics, is more than most, I think, subject to controversy. And unlike some departments, we don't just tell people what we think about one side of a controversy. We feel that in order to
prepare them to go on to their professional work, we need to tell them what both or in some cases all sides of the controversy are.
And so I think what I found hardest over the years was doing justice to ideas that I just didn't believe in.
There was a friend of mine, now unfortunately no longer living, who used to put it this way. He always said,
I can teach that the earth is round, and I can teach that the earth is flat,
but when it comes to the flat part, my heart just isn't in it. Well, I have the same feeling
sometimes. Which macroeconomic concept do you feel that most for? markets, perfect information, complete rationality on the part of all of the players in the economy.
And I think every one of those characteristics that I just indicated is wrong. And moreover,
this is then compounded in much of macroeconomics by a further assumption, which is that all of the individuals in the economy are identical.
Now, the idea that all of the individuals are identical makes possible certain analytical constructs, which are, of course, very convenient for economists to work with.
But for somebody like me who's interested in, for example, monetary policy and debt markets,
this is deadly, I think, because think of it this way, Joe. If you and I were identical in every way economically, why would you ever lend to me and why would I ever borrow from you?
In a world of identical people, there would be no private debt markets.
But a lot of my work in earlier years was precisely on how the bond market works, how one person borrows and another person lends. Well, this is just one example
that right in my face all the time in my work is the fact that people aren't identical.
So if you put together the frictionless markets, it never costs anybody anything to do anything.
The perfect rationality, everybody thinks things through correctly.
The foresight, everybody can understand what's happening in the future.
And the fact that everybody is identical, this adds up to a kind of macroeconomics that I just don't have a lot of faith in.
But when I teach macroeconomics, I feel obliged, alas, to tell students about it.
And so I do. But as my friend said, my heart isn't in it.
You were born in Kentucky, if I'm not mistaken.
Yes, that's correct. I am from Kentucky.
And you grew up there, correct?
I lived in Kentucky up until the age of 18 when I went off to Harvard as an undergraduate.
And Kentucky is one of the states hardest hit by the deaths of despair phenomenon.
Can you tell me what it was like growing up there and what it's like today,
socially and economically, if you ever get a chance to make it back?
Well, I'll duck what it's like today because I do go back from time to time, but I haven't lived there for a very long time. So I think listening to me on what it's like today
would not be very helpful. I was far away from the communities that are at the deaths of despair phenomenon. I lived in Louisville, which is not the capital
city of the state, but the largest city. When I was growing up there, it was a city of maybe
half to three quarters of a million people. Today, it's probably more like a million people. Standard of living was pretty high.
I lived in an affluent suburb of the city.
The deaths of despair phenomenon occurs, alas, in rural parts of the state, coal country parts of the state. There's an area called Hardin County, often the Appalachian region of Kentucky
that used to be, I wouldn't say prosperous, but at least people had the coal mines to work in,
and they had a few other things to do. Today, the coal mines are largely shutter on the way to
shutting. And so those are very difficult areas. They're characterized by
people who don't have a lot of education. In the suburb in which I grew up, most people had a
college education. Most of the people with whom I went to high school went on to college of one
form or another. So I knew about and occasionally would see something of these
coal mining and other rural areas, but you shouldn't think that I grew up there.
As I said, Ben, your first book is superb and we won't rehash the whole book here on this podcast
because it was published a while ago and you have a new book
out now. But I encourage people to read it, The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth.
And if it's okay with you, Ben, I would like to jump around just a few issues like lily pads,
because I think that The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth, while it was published a while ago now, is more relevant than ever. And today, if I may interrupt, you're not the only person who seems
to think that, Joe. This is the first time I've ever had a book that's been out that long,
in which the sales keep rising. And I think the reason, and this is very unfortunate, I'm sorry to say this, but
especially in the context of the events of the last week or two, lots of people have thought
that my 2005 book explained why we were going to get a Donald Trump and what the consequences of getting a Donald Trump would be.
And not that I want to personify this to Trump, but I think he has become, for better or worse,
the metaphor for a whole wide-ranging phenomenon describing the attitudes not just of hundreds of thousands,
but of millions, tens of millions of people in the United States. And it is true, I think,
that some of the things I talked about in my 2005 book explain why the Trumpism phenomenon would emerge as a result of the period economically that we've
been through. And I'm sorry that that's the case, but people do seem to think the book is relevant
in that way. And as I say, alas, the sales are going up. Let me quote from the book. So in the
book you write, I believe that the rising intolerance and
incivility and the eroding generosity and openness that have marked important aspects of American
society in the recent past have been, in significant part, a consequence of the stagnation of American
middle-class living standards during much of the last quarter of the 20th century. If the United States can return to the
rapid and more broadly based growth that the country experienced during the first few decades
after World War II, or more recently the latter half of the 1990s, over time these unfortunate
political and social trends will continue to abate. If our growth falters, however, or if we
merely continue with slower growth that
benefits only a minority of our citizens, the deterioration of American society will, I fear,
worsen once more. You hit it right on the head. And alas, the possible trajectory that I indicated third, namely the one of continuing slow growth
and continuing widening inequality so that the fruits of that additional growth would accrue
only to people who, by and large, were already at the top. That's the trajectory the United States has continued on in the 15 years since I wrote that book.
So we're now about 30-odd years into anians, worse than stagnation, outright decline for many Americans. happen to societies when they experience economic growth that's widely shared. And when societies
either don't have growth or have growth that's enjoyed only by a few, then good things don't
happen. And a lot of times bad things happen. And as we saw with the recent storming of the Capitol, the veneer of civilization is very thin indeed.
And there's an ominous quote in the book which makes a similar point, a quote by Alexander Gershenkron.
Yes, yes, that's the one that everybody quotes.
It's about, you can go ahead and read it, it's about a democracy without Democrats.
I assume that's the one you have in mind. Exactly.
Even a long democratic history does not necessarily immunize a country from becoming a democracy without Democrats.
Importantly, for your listeners who don't have the benefit of the book, when Alex talked about a democracy without Democrats, there's a small d on Democrats. He's not referring to the
Democratic Party. He's referring to Democrats in the sense of adherence of small d democracy.
In the book, you define growth for your purposes as rising living standards that are widely shared,
but your argument in support of growth is subtle.
It's not about the benefits growth delivers. In other words, it's not about levels of incomes.
Rather, it's about growth per se. In other words, it's about changes in incomes. People need to feel
a sense of forward progress, kind of like a cyclist who has to keep pedaling or he'll topple over, or a shark which must keep
swimming or it will die. A harmonious society has to keep growing sustainably or it will descend
into conflict and violence. And I want to kind of get to the crux of the argument of the book.
The crucial question is, why is it the case that when people feel they're doing better compared to some
reference point, whether that reference point is in their own past or in their parents' past,
do they consequently feel less need to get ahead compared to other people in the society?
Because at first glance, this seems highly counterintuitive. From the point of view of sexual selection,
what really matters is relative status. So why are relative success and growth per se substitutes rather than complements? Is it just a cognitive bias? Is it just Albert Hirschman's
tunnel effect that as people see others in their society moving forward, they're provisionally okay
with that insofar as
they believe that it is an economy-wide change and that their turn will come soon. What's going on
here? I don't explain it in the book, Joe. I frame the question exactly as you've indicated.
To step back a moment, we have an overwhelming amount of evidence that people do assess their material well-being
in relative terms, not absolutely. If you go up to a friend and say, how are you doing, Mike?
Mike is likely to look back at you and say, well, compared to what? That's just the way human beings think about the issue. And the two benchmarks that we have a lot of evidence to indicate that people use are,
one, their own past experience, and two, how are they doing compared to other people?
And in both cases, it's really very interesting, and I spend some amount of space in the book talking about it,
exactly how you define this matter of one's own prior experience and how you define who everybody else is.
So to start with who everybody else is, is that simply the friends in your bowling league?
Is that everybody in your office?
Is it everybody who lives on your block?
There's been a lot of economic work on that.
And the usual finding is that people compare themselves more locally rather than globally.
Most Americans don't get a lot of satisfaction from saying,
you know, I really live a lot better than those people in India.
That's just not the way people think.
And conversely, we have lots of different ways to think about how people assess their own prior experience. I quite
deliberately frame my ideas about this in an intergenerational way. I picture people asking
them questions depending on their stage of the life process, like, if I'm just starting out in life,
what are the opportunities available to me compared to what my uncles had? A little further
along, how am I raising my children compared to what I remember growing up in my parents' house?
A little further along, how's my career doing compared to how my father or my
mother did? So I put a long time frame on it. Now, with all that as background, we're now at your
question, which I'm really not able to answer. These two sources of life satisfaction, doing
better compared to how I or my family have done in the past and doing better than other people,
these could be complements or they could be substitutes. And here I have no argument for
why they turn out to be substitutes, but the book contains lots of empirical historical examples. I look at the history of the United States since our Civil
War in the 1860s. I look at the history of Britain since the Napoleonic Wars. I look at
France since the founding of the Third Republic in 1870. I look at Germany since the unification of the empire in, I believe, 1861. And again and again
and again, the evidence seems to comport with the substitutes idea, not the complements idea.
But it's absolutely true that I don't present a theoretical argument. I hope somebody will come up with one one day, but I didn't have one.
In 1974, the economist and historian Richard Easterlin argued that economic growth in Japan
has not made people's lives better by their own reports.
He then extended the finding to a number of countries, including the United States.
And as you know, Ben, his claim became known as the Eastland Paradox,
which suggests that there is no link between a society's economic development and its average
level of happiness. But then in 2008, three years after your book was published, Betsy Stevenson
and Justin Wolfers revisited the paradox and found no evidence of a satiation point beyond which wealthier countries could have
no further increases in subjective well-being. In other words, economic growth continues to
deliver happiness. On which side of the debate do you fall?
Both, and for a reason that I think is very clear and technological. But first, since you did not engage
in well-deserved chauvinism,
I'll do it for you.
Justin Wolfers is Australian.
He was our student at Harvard.
He's a wonderful man.
I taught him.
And because he did go into macroeconomics,
I know him very well.
And Justin is absolutely Australian.
And moreover, you'll get the picture, his first child is a daughter named Matilda.
So Justin is as Australian as they come.
Now, why do I believe both?
There was a technological development called
television. And back when Richard Easterlin was looking, doing his work, and even more so
when the data were collected for Easterlin's work. Easterlin did his work in the 1970s, but the data that he was using
were collected in the 1960s, actually at the beginning of the 60s. There wasn't much television
then. And so if you were a person living in, let's say, Lisbon or living someplace in Portugal, and I picked Portugal
because at that time Portugal was one of the lowest income of the original European 15
countries. If you were living in Portugal in 1960, the odds were pretty good that the people you compared yourself to were other Portuguese, or to take another country that was pretty far down the scale for Europe at that time, Greece.
If you were living in Greece, you probably compared yourself to other Greeks. Well, come forward nearly 40, actually no, nearly 50 years to when Betsy Stevenson and
Justin Wolfers were doing their work.
By now, everybody has television.
And so if you are living in Portugal, you know what life is like in the United States to pick a country that has a
higher income than Portugal. You know what life looks like in India to pick a country with income
a lot lower than Portugal. And so for reasons that are very consistent with this relative income idea, relative consumption idea that Richard Easterlin
outlined in his work in the 70s. Today, everybody in the world is comparing themselves to a certain
extent, at least, to everybody else in the world. And therefore, on average, Portuguese are
a lot happier than people in India, but they're not as happy as people in
the United States. But there's a reason why I think Easterlin was right in the 70s and why
Justin and Betsy are right today. Got it. So the facts have changed.
Well, the facts are there was one, I mean, as so often happens in economics, technology happens,
technology changes, and those changes are very important.
And you've hit on a perfectly good example.
Two quotations, Ben, and then a question.
First quotation, in a 1991 article titled The Allocation of Talent Implications for
Growth, Kevin Murphy, Andre Schleifer, and Robert Vishny find that,
quote,
in most countries, rent-seeking rewards talent
more than entrepreneurship does, leading to stagnation.
Our evidence shows that countries with a higher proportion
of engineering college majors grow faster,
whereas countries with a higher proportion
of law concentrators grow more slowly,
end quote. Second quotation, in their book, Deaths of Despair and the Future of Capitalism,
Anne Case and Angus Deaton write, quote, with lower growth, there is more pressure to shut
out less successful groups altogether. Lower growth sharpens the fight over resources.
It gives each group incentives to lobby
to get more than its share, and it poisons politics, much of which is concerned with the
division of resources. Since 1970, growth has predominantly gone to those who are already
better off, who are much better equipped to defend their share. When people feel they must protect
their economic position in a tougher world,
they divert their time and their resources to the zero-sum game of distribution and away from the
positive-sum game of innovation and growth. Rent-seeking replaces creation, and we can get
into a vicious circle that impoverishes everyone." Is rent-seeking better thought of as a cause or a consequence of lower growth,
or is it both? I would certainly think it's a cause of slower growth.
My own argument in my book on the moral consequences of economic growth is certainly consistent with the idea that slow growth creates rent-seeking, but that's not
an argument that I made directly. The consequences that I was after in that book were, and I use the
word moral in a self-consciously 18th century way were consequences for the public character
of the society. To return to the beginning of our conversation, to what extent do we have a
commitment to democracy and democratic institutions? To what extent do we want to make opportunities available to everybody rather than
just the sons and daughters and nieces and nephews of the people who are already at the top? How
about generosity toward people who, for one reason or another, we're not able to take advantages of the opportunities that are available.
How about tolerance? Tolerance with respect to what? As an American, I would immediately think
of race relations, but also I have in mind things like ethnic tensions and religious prejudice. These are all the kinds, the dimensions of behavioral consequences
of growth versus no growth that I looked at in the book. Now, I would be sympathetic if either
my colleague Andre Schleifer or somebody else were to come along with a theory and perhaps some evidence saying that in addition to these moral public consequences I documented, slow growth or no growth also leads to an increase in rent-seeking behavior.
But that's not something I've shown in my book. In thinking about the moral consequences
of economic stagnation and regression, may I augment the mechanism in your thesis and then
get your reaction? Sure. So recently I've been reading a lot of work by Peter Turchin and Jack
Goldstone, who are fathers of the field of Cleodynamics,
Cleo after the Greek muse of history, dynamics changes over time. And they look for big patterns
and nonlinear dynamics in history. It's not a deterministic theory. It's not a cyclical view
of history, but it is what they call structural demographic theory. And indeed,
in 2010, Turchin had what's now a very famous article in Nature, where he, in some sense,
predicted the political instability that the United States has unfortunately been experiencing
recently. And in Turchin's theory, Ben, popular immiseration plays second fiddle to what he calls elite
overproduction in generating political instability.
Because one of the consequences of inequality is an increase in the economic elite.
You know, there are now more millionaires and billionaires in the United States than
ever before.
And people who are economically very
successful also then have political ambitions. So they want to join the political elite.
But much of the seats of political power have inelastic supply. So there can only be one
president, so many senators, members of Congress, judges, etc. So when elite overproduction happens, intra-elite competition
intensifies, and that, in Turchin's view, is one of the main causes of political instability. And
then, of course, elites, if to the extent popular emiseration exists, elites are able to enlist
popular support as are counter-elites you know donald trump and steve
bannon would be now classic examples the reason that in turchin's view and and i might not be
paraphrasing it perfectly but the reason that elite overproduction seems to be more important
than popular immiseration in generating political instability is just that the elites have the power. So, to the extent that popular immiseration exists,
it can always be quashed and repressed through military and economic might in the hands of the
elite. And I thought it was interesting in your book, The Moral Consens of Economic Growth,
where you talk about the French Revolution,
and I'll quote a final paragraph from the book on page 96. So, you write,
especially when incomes overall are stagnant, the opportunity for some to get ahead also often
creates intense resentment of those who do. Edmund Burke, defending the pre-revolutionary
regime in France as a form of open aristocracy analogous to England's, hailed the ease with which a commoner could obtain a title by securing one of the, the practice of ennobling commoners had the opposite effect. The envy with which the newly made nobleman inspired his former equals
intensified their sense of being unfairly treated. According to Tocqueville, the result,
which is thoroughly familiar in the modern context as well, was more animosity towards
the recent creations than towards the old nobility, end quote.
But I guess my question would be, who is doing the envying here? And it seems that the people
who are doing the envying aren't so much the commoners, to use the language that would have
been used in the time of the French Revolution, but the nobles or the aspirants
to nobility. And in that context of elite overproduction, intra-elite competition intensifies.
And so I guess in very broad terms, the story of political instability resulting from inequality is more a story of elites than of popular revolutions.
Your reaction to that?
Let me begin by saying I'm not familiar with the elites, as you describe it, for these what Fred Hirsch would have called positional goods, only one president, only 435 members of Congress. That sounds exactly right to
me. The one addition I would make, however, is that there's a lot of room, at least in our system,
for people who would like to play in that arena to find themselves influential.
So to take an obvious example, Charles Koch, the billionaire, is probably one of the most
influential political figures in the United States. To my knowledge, he has never displayed any interest
whatsoever in running for elective office. Now, we can say Charles Koch is an extreme example,
being a multi-billionaire, but lots of people, as you point out, have enough money in the United States that they are able to make contributions to political campaigns and to political parties at a level that brings some influence with them, with it. And unfortunately, in a very regrettable Supreme Court decision some years ago in the so-called
Citizens United case, the courts determined that corporations are allowed to play in this game
as well. So we have a very money-buys-everything system in the United States now. Now, fortunately, the voters
don't always go along, and there are quite dramatic cases. I'm thinking of a governor's race in
California a few years ago, where some multi-billionaire decided that she would like to become governor of California and out of her own fortune
put an enormous amount of money into the race. And the voters said, thank you very much. We just
don't have the other candidate. You can go home. So it isn't always determinative, but the role of money in our politics gives people the opportunity
to compete in a way that you describe without having to think they have to be one of the 435
congressmen. So that part, that part I think rings true. What I would have to see worked out is why this leads to political
instability. It might lead to policies we don't like. It might lead to firms in some industries
being able to do the equivalent of bribing congressmen through political contributions to put features in
the tax law there that we don't like or prevent their competition from abroad from bringing
cheaper goods into the U.S.
Lots of bad policies can ensue.
I can see that quickly.
But why this would lead to political instability isn't clear to me.
I think perhaps because the stakes are so high, relative status is important,
conspicuous consumption starts to ratchet up and elite competition intensifies? One useful example to pick, Joe, would be to look at the experience in
the latter part of the 19th century, our so-called Gilded Age. As I'm sure you're aware, that's
the period that the economist Thorsten Veblen was looking at and trying to explain in his works, which coined the phrase conspicuous consumption.
So we certainly had that kind of competition, not so much in the political sphere, but conspicuous consumption, people putting on ever more lavish entertainments.
This was the period of Mrs. Astor and the New York 400 and all that. But the question then is
whether it led to political instability. And I'm not aware that it did. There was, of course,
a lot of political competition within each party. Different people
wanted to be president. There was competition between the two parties. We already by then had
the Democrats and the Republicans. But I don't see that there was anything unstable about the
situation. So the 1880s, 1890s on into the new century might well be an interesting
test case for that hypothesis. If the goal of the moral consequences of economic growth
was to persuade people that economic growth also has moral benefits, not just moral costs,
how would you rate the book's success? I think it's had some modest success.
I'm pleased that the book is frequently mentioned in the context of answering just the question
that I set out to answer. The question that I had in mind was a very America or Australia or Europe-centered question. It was,
why is it that we who live at a living standard that's so much greater than our grandparents did
and their grandparents before them, and also we who live at a living standard that's so much greater than the other two-thirds of the world,
why should we care about further economic growth?
And I think I provided a pretty good answer to that question,
and I'm pleased to see that in discussions of why growth matters, Growth Matters. The book is frequently cited and the book's emphasis on the implications of growth
for these non-material characteristics of the society get mentioned. So I'm pleased about that.
Now, one could have said that a higher standard of success would have been that our policymakers, at least in the United States, might have said, well, if growth is really that important and growth has to be inclusive for those beneficial effects to ensue, we better adopt policies that would make sure that the inequality stops widening and the fruits of further growth actually accrue to the broad cross-section of the American population.
And alas, that hasn't happened.
So if that's the standard, then new book, is deliciously counterintuitive because if modern economics grew out of the Enlightenment and the Enlightenment represents a departure from religion, then what has religion got to do with anything?
So what role has religion played in economics and capitalism?
I think it's been very important and in ways that cut against the grain of the Enlightenment, which is true.
And the Enlightenment was, we think, a movement away from viewing the world as a God-centered universe
toward what we today think of as we would call it secular humanism.
And that's also true, I suppose. And therefore,
people assume, by putting the two together, that the creation of modern economics by people like
Adam Smith and David Hume and Adam Ferguson and all of the other greats of that period must have had nothing to do with religion. I claim that's false.
This is meant to be a fundamental rethinking of where our economics came from. And the story
is that Smith and Hume and their contemporaries lived at a time when religion was more central and more important than anything we know or really
can imagine in today's Western world. And therefore, they were constantly in the middle
of religious controversies, whether they wanted to be or not. And that whether they wanted to be or not is very important for this
argument because we know historically that Smith and Hume and many of those other people were not
religiously committed individuals. This is not a case of religious believers self-consciously bringing their beliefs to bear on their professional work.
What is it?
It's a matter of what's in the air.
It's a matter of what you hear discussed at the lunch table every day.
It's what controversies are swirling all around you.
Another feature of their world is that intellectual life was much more integrated then.
When Smith was a professor at the University in Glasgow, there were only 16 members of the faculty who had the title of professor.
He was one, but there was a professor of theology.
There was a professor of church history.
These folks interacted with each other all the time.
Smith and Hume were both members of what we would call today a lunch discussion club,
the most intellectually prestigious one in Edinburgh.
And of the 30-odd original members of that club,, were Church of Scotland clergymen.
So these people were constantly exposed to what was new and interesting and controversial in the religious thinking of the day, exactly at the time when Smith and Hume were reaching young adulthood
and going on to do their professional work that led us to the economics we have today,
the religious ideas of the English-speaking Protestant world were undergoing a fundamental
transition, and that transition was to a new form of thinking that I think was remarkably congruent
with Smithian economics, which is our economics, and that in effect enabled Smith's thinking. It
opened the way for him to see this remarkable capacity of humans to take beneficial actions when they did so in the
right circumstances, which of course he understood to be competitive markets. So that in a nutshell
is why even though the argument may seem counterintuitive, I think it's true.
So what were some of the religious controversies swirling around Smith and Hume?
In brief, it was a movement away from predestinarian Calvinism.
And the three most crucial pieces of that transition were, one, the movement away from a belief in what Calvin called utter depravity,
the idea that humans were unable to see and to do any good in their lives,
movement from that to a much more benign, optimistic view of the human character,
which I characterize by looking at John Locke, one of the great figures
of the Enlightenment, but also a religious person. And Locke's metaphor was the candle of the Lord,
that humans were born with access to the candle of the Lord, and if they would just use the candle that was given to them,
they would see the way to do right. The second piece was the movement away from Calvin's view
of predestination. Calvin thought that whether any individual person was to be saved in the afterlife or condemned to an eternity of punishment of hell
in hell was something that the individual had no control over whatsoever. This was, again,
pre-destined, meaning that the decision for any individual was made before that person was even born. Indeed, long before that, before the
world was even created. So the idea that people could make choices, take actions to influence
their spiritual destiny was completely ruled out. And by analogy, if people can't affect that, well, maybe they can't
affect other things as well. And by contrast, in the period in which Hume and Smith were growing up,
the view was coming to be, no, no, predestination isn't right. To use the phrase of the first Archbishop of Canterbury,
who was appointed by William and Mary after the Glorious Revolution, people are able to cooperate,
that was his word, cooperate with the divine in effecting their salvation. Well, translated into the worldly realm, this creates a whole
different view of human agency. People are able to make choices and take actions that will,
in the end, make themselves and other people better off as well. That's the analogy.
And then the third piece of it was from the Calvin view that man's sole purpose of being here on
earth is glorification of God to the post-Calvin view that part of the reason we're here is that the divinely intended purpose
for us is to enjoy and be happy in our existence. And in some renderings, that's the principal
reason we're here. And therefore, if you believe that the principal reason we're here
is to enjoy existence, then it's not surprising
that the world would be structured and humans would have capacity that would enable them to
make themselves happy. And you could even extend that to the market economy. Why do we have,
why did markets evolve over history? Well, maybe because the divine wanted to have a mechanism available
to allow humans, through their own choices and actions, to make not only themselves but other
people better off as well. And then the great contribution, to repeat, that Adam Smith made
was to recognize that the mechanism in all this is competition
carried out in markets. So I think there is this congruity, there is this creating the right
atmosphere, this opening up and enabling of a kind of view of human agency, human choice, human action, that I wouldn't say would have
been impossible. This is not a necessary argument. But it would have been a lot harder
to think in this way back when everybody thought of in terms of predestinarian Calvinism.
And therefore, if the question we have is why did modern economics come
along when it did and in the form in which it did, I think this has a lot to do with it.
There's still one important ingredient missing from Smith's view of the beneficial consequences
of self-interested behavior, and that is ongoing technical progress, as you write in the book.
So talk about how the United States arrived on the scene in the early 19th century and
what that added to the picture.
Well, to begin, you're absolutely right.
Any reader of the book will, I hope, understand that I came away from this research as an enormous admirer of Adam Smith's
thinking. Whether I would have liked him as an individual, I have no idea. We don't know that
much about his persona. But as a thinker, I came away with great admiration. And indeed, I'll tell you, Joe, that when my editor at Knopf suggested that we use the photograph, not a photograph, that's wrong, use the standard painting, whatever it is, of Adam Smith as the frontispiece of the book,
absolutely, I said yes. So when you open the book, what you'll see is the very first thing
you come across is a full-page portrait of Smith. So I'm a great proponent of Smith. Having said that, Adam Smith absolutely did not understand the idea of ongoing
technical progress. My interpretation is that he lived too early. You could say that he lived right
in the middle of the Industrial Revolution, or at least the beginning of the first Industrial
Revolution, and therefore maybe he should have seen it, but he didn't.
And there's no evidence in any of his writings that I can see that he saw the possibility of ongoing technical progress.
If you want a smoking gun for that argument, it's the famous use of the pin factory example. Smith thought that increases in
the standard of living came from increased division of labor, what we would today call
specialization in production. And right at the beginning of The Wealth of Nations is this lovely example in which he talks about
how they make pins in a factory. Incidentally, in case your listeners don't know,
he isn't talking about hap pins or safety pins. Pin was the 18th century word for what we call
a nail of the kind that you would use to build houses. So he's talking about house nails.
It's a very practical thing.
If he had had any remote idea what was going on
and why the technology of the Industrial Revolution
would be important in the way in which it proved to be,
he wouldn't have picked a pin factory.
He would have picked something having to do with a textile factory
because that was the center of gravity of the Industrial Revolution.
So, in short, Smith missed it.
Now, come forward.
By the time we get to the half a century later,
call it the 1830s, especially in the United States, the role of ongoing
technological progress was absolutely unmistakable. Even in Smith's day, people understood that they
were living better than their grandparents had lived. That he did not miss. But people then thought of it as some kind of an upswing of what
they would have called a long wave in the economy. Too long to be, we wouldn't call it a business
cycle, but a long wave. But by the 1820s, especially the 1830s, people knew that it wasn't just a long
wave. They knew that they were living in a long-term upward trend in material living standards.
It was especially evident in the United States.
And therefore, it's no surprise that the person who, to as far as I can find, first introduced the concept of long-term technical progress into economics was
Francis Wayland. Francis Wayland was a Baptist minister. Here we do have
somebody who's a religious believer. Francis Wayland was a Baptist minister.
He was the president of Brown University Baptist Foundation. But more to the point,
for our purposes, Wayland wrote the best-selling economics textbook in the United States before our Civil War.
He wrote it in 1837, and the book has an unmistakable statement of the role of ongoing technical progress.
You cannot miss it, and Weyland interprets it as divine benevolence.
So there you have it. And Weyland interprets it as divine benevolence. So there you have it. And of course,
if Smith had lived into the 1830s, I have no doubt he would have understood it too. But he didn't. He died in 1790. His great book was published in 1776. He had some revisions, but he never revised that part. There's some evidence to say that Smith's favorite book of his was The Theory of Moral Sentiments, not The Wealth of Nations.
Which of those two books do you prefer?
Oh, I'm an economist.
I like both books.
I'm an economist, and so I'll go with The Wealth of Nations.
Remember, Smith never thought of himself as an economist.
Indeed, the word didn't exist then.
Smith was a professor of moral philosophy,
and his first book, which he published in 1759,
when he was only 36 years old.
His first book was called The Theory of Moral Sentiments.
It's a book on philosophy.
So maybe he liked that one better.
I don't know.
There is a view, which I talk about in my new book,
which I think is correct,
that he was put up to the economics aspect of it by Hume.
Hume was very clear in his writing that he thought the great project to be done in their era
would be to create a science of man that would be comparable to what Newton had done 75 years earlier for the physical
world. And many people think that Hume, who was Smith's mentor, he was a dozen years later,
they were closest, he was Smith's closest friends. Many people think that Hume put him up to the assignment and said, hey, why don't you go look at the economy?
That would be a place to start in creating our science of man.
Well, maybe that's true.
But regardless of whether Smith preferred the wealth of nations, I'm an economist.
And so that's the one I'll pick.
But I like the other one too.
You mentioned Francis Weyland. Let me quote from his Elements of Political Economy,
which was written just a few years after Tocqueville's visit to America. So Weyland
writes, to relieve the sick, the destitute, and the helpless is a religious duty,
and therefore should, like every
other religious duty, be a voluntary service. How did religion affect Americans' views of the role
of government? There was a great debate on this in the latter part of the 19th century. Wayland died right around the time of the Civil War.
But by the time we got to the 1880s, the 1890s, exactly the period you and I were talking
about a few minutes ago for the Torsten Veblen phenomenon, the conspicuous consumption, people were understanding that the growth of the economy was not,
as John Kennedy once said, this was not a tide that was lifting all of the boats.
Lots of people were being left behind. In, I believe it was 1879, Henry George wrote his
famous book called Progress and Poverty.
You know, earlier, people wouldn't have thought to put those two nouns together in a book title.
They would say, you know, if you're going to have progress, you're not going to have poverty.
By the time you got to the 1880s, 1890s, people understood that, no, that wasn't right.
You can have progress with a lot of poverty.
So a new movement then emerged within the American Protestant churches called the Social Gospel Movement,
in which people understood that broad parts of the population were not getting to share in this prosperity,
and they thought there was a role for the government to do something about it.
And further, they thought there was a role for the churches to steer, to advise the government in doing this. They understood that they and the churches
had no ability to make this happen, in part because they understood that the voluntarist
aspect of religious giving and sharing that Wayland had emphasized just wasn't adequate to the task. So their view was that government needed to step in
to correct the distributional problem, but they saw themselves in the mainline Protestant churches
as playing a key role in steering these policies. I've always been fascinated by the contrast between America and Australia in that regard
so Australia's religious origins are much more Catholic than Protestant Ben and I wonder if
that has sort of cast a long shadow over us socially in the form of, you know, the lesser entrepreneurship
in Australia than you would see in America, as well as the belief in government in Australia
and the much stronger social safety net we have here. We have grown up with first relying on the top-down provisions
and authority from the Catholic Church,
and then that sort of slowly grew into the same faith and expectation
in big government.
Of course, I'm completely speculating here,
but it is an interesting distinction between the two countries.
Well, let me not make any pretense whatsoever of being able to talk about Australia,
because not only have I not lived there, I very much regret to say I have never visited Australia.
It's one of the great failings of my life, I think, that I've never been there. I'm very, I'm, no,
I'm serious. I've always wanted to visit Australia. Going back, I mentioned before that when I was a
student at the other, what we call the other Cambridge, I had all these Australian friends,
and they were such wonderful people. And I've always wanted to be, go visit, and I've never
done it. So maybe someday I will. But so you may, I will. So you may be right, but let me give you a slightly different view,
and that is the Tocqueville view.
In Democracy in America, Tocqueville visited America in the 1830s,
the period we were just talking about, in the context of Weyland.
And Tocqueville wrote this two-volume book after he returned to his native France.
And one of the things that he remarked on in the book as part of America's democratic character was the role of private, as we would call them, voluntary, as he called it,
associations. And he explicitly compared it both with England, which he knew, and also with France, where he came from. And there's this wonderful passage in Democracy in America, and he said that for just the kind of endeavors in which in England you would see some great lord being the sponsor,
and in France you would see the government as the sponsor. In the United States, it's some private voluntary association created Bottom Up.
He was very taken with, again, this, not his word, mine, Bottom Up character of American society.
And so I wonder if part of what you're picking up in your comparison of Australia, which I don't know, and America, which I do, is not so much the Roman Catholic Church phenomenon, but in this case, maybe the Tocqueville phenomenon.
I don't know.
But if you were speculating, I've now speculated too, but at least on the basis of Talkville.
I think you're absolutely right. In American Grace, Bob Putnam observes that Americans choose their religion based on their politics. Why are Americans so weird like that? I don't know. I happen to agree with
Putnam. Now, incidentally, he's making a limited statement. He's not talking about Mormons. He's
not talking about Roman Catholics. He's not talking about Jews. He's talking about Protestants. Most Americans are Protestant of some form or other.
So what he's talking about is the choice of, do I want to be an Episcopalian?
Do I want to be a Presbyterian?
Do I want to be in the disciples of Christ?
That sort of decision. Now, I suppose the answer, and here I'm again speculating because
while some of the fact base that I'm drawing on is in my new book, the question you raise isn't,
I would speculate that across the different Protestant denominations in the United States,
the underlying theology is not sufficiently different to make people
super uncomfortable in one versus another.
Now I say that, and I know there will be people
who will step up and say, well, look, I'm a Missouri Synod Lutheran, and how can you tell
me that my theology is not different from the Episcopalians? Well, of course, I understand
things like that, but you're asking a broad question, and so I'm trying to give a broad answer.
By and large, the underlying theology in most of these Protestant denominations is non-predestinarian,
very few of them. Even the Presbyterian Church these days is not really Calvinist.
Most of them don't have strong views on other theological aspects.
And therefore, I think people are choosing on other grounds. You know, it's not unusual in the United States for somebody who's
raised as a Methodist to move to a different city and look around and decide, well, you know,
here in my new city, the group that seems most appealing are the Baptists. So,
instead of being a Methodist, I'll be a Baptist. So I think that's probably the
reason. But it would be interesting to know. I'm not aware that Putnam has a view on the subject.
Maybe he does. But then it certainly is the case that, and here's some, now we're getting into material that I absolutely talk about in the book,
and that is that different Protestant groups have, and other groups too, have very different
politics. So the Episcopalians politically look very different from the disciples of Christ. And so if you have strong politics,
you might want to go to a church where you're not afraid to say who you're voting for for president.
And then once you're at that church, you then adopt their theology.
In the last couple of years, there have been several brilliant books
explaining the impact of religion, specifically Christianity, on the West and Western thinking.
Tom Holland's Dominion, Joe Henrich's The Weirdest People in the World, and now Ben Friedman's
Religion and the Rise of Capitalism. Is that just random, or is there some underlying factor that accounts for
this interest? I don't think it's random, Joe. I think this is all part of the realization
that's been in place, I would say, for some decades, not just a few years. It's all part
of the realization that the so-called secularization hypothesis was wrong. If you go back to the early
decades after World War II, lots of quite eminent scholars had the view that the world was becoming
secularized, that religious belief was being left behind, that people might participate in the forms of religion,
but they weren't going to be believers. More and more people would drop out and the churches would
become empty. You know the story. And I would say that by the late part of the last century, it had become clear that that turned out to be wrong.
And the discussion was no longer about, let's think through the implications of the
secularization hypothesis and see where we're going. It was, let's think about why the secularization hypothesis turned out to be wrong.
And I think the fact that I and other people are interested in this subject is a kind of
reflection of that. We realize that we live in a world in which religion is pretty important stuff. To repeat,
it isn't important and central and institutionalized in the way it was in the England and the Scotland
of Adam Smith's day. But in terms of private thinking, it's still there nonetheless. And I
think we're aware of that in a way that people a quarter century ago, certainly a half a century ago, weren't.
I think that's the answer to what you're looking for.
I think at the same time, within the atheist movement itself, there's almost been a pushback against the so-called new atheism. I was raised as a Catholic but became, I guess,
what I would describe as an atheist around the age of,
I can't remember, 15 or 16.
But I've had this real sea change in recent years
where I've come to appreciate the importance
or the role that religion plays for better and sometimes for worse,
in part through reading moral psychology and evolutionary biology. I'm thinking specifically
of the work of John Haidt and David Sloan Wilson. But I think that new atheism has certainly gone astray in its vociferousness in tone, but also its
complete out-of-hand dismissal of religion in its substance. In The Weirdest People in the World,
Joe Henrich argues that the church's abolition of cousin marriage set the Western world on a pathway
to free markets. What do you make of Joe Henrich's thesis? The Church's Abolition of Cousin Marriage Set the Western World on a Pathway to Free Markets.
What do you make of Joe Henrich's thesis?
I don't want to comment on that one because I'm aware that there's some controversy over whether he's got the historical facts right.
I'm aware that I've read some reviews of the book that assume he has. I recently read one by Charles Freeman, a very well-known historian
of that period in the UK. Freeman, not like me, not F-R-I-E-D-M-A-N, Charles is F-R-E-E-M-A-N.
Freeman thinks that Joe's historical facts are wrong, and I don't pretend to know
the difference, so I'm going to duck that one. If I can go back to where you were a moment ago
on your own reactions, you might find helpful a concept that I refer to in my new book, the name I give it, and maybe others have used this as well, but I don't know, is post-doctrinalism. referring to when I said that a lot of these denominations that in an earlier era would have
thought of themselves as just completely different now understand that they're in the same business
and they don't emphasize the doctrinal differences among them. I'll give you only two examples to indicate what I meant, what I mean by that.
About 10 years or so ago, our local Mormon church right here in Cambridge, Massachusetts, alas, burned down.
Very tragically. Fortunately, they've rebuilt it. immediately after the Mormon church burned down, the local churches adjacent to them took in the various prayer groups.
So the Episcopalians took in at their church the 10.30 in the morning prayer group.
The Methodists around the corner took in the 2.30 in the morning prayer group. The Methodists around the corner took in the 2.30 in the afternoon prayer group.
The Congregationalists nearby took in something else, etc., etc.
If you go back 100 years ago, the possibility that the Episcopalians or the Methodists
or the Congregationalists would have taken in and given hospitality
to the Mormon prayer groups, that would never have happened. But today, nobody thought anything
of it whatsoever. They just thought of it as being hospitable to their neighbor who is in the same
line of work that they're in. And I'll give you a second example. There's a very well-known church
in California, the Saddleback Church, led by Pastor Rick Warren. Warren is very well-known.
He's the person who was invited to give the invocation at Barack Obama's first inaugural,
there's an account, there's a young scholar,
a religious scholar who wrote a book,
an interesting book on predestination,
the theory of predestination,
who in the last chapter of the book, describes his visit to the Saddleback Church in California.
Unfortunately, he didn't get an appointment with Warren, so he went over there and he talked to
one of the assistant ministers. One of the first things he describes about this church
is the absence of any signage
to let you know what denomination it is.
Turns out the Saddleback Church is part of the Southern Baptist denomination.
But if you did not know, you wouldn't figure it out.
There's no sign that says that.
And then this young scholar, I'll give a plug for his book.
His name is Peter Tuison.
Never met him, but I certainly admired his book.
Tuison writes that he keeps asking this assistant minister what the church's view on predestination is,
because, after all, that's what Tuison is writing a book about.
And he describes how the minister keeps deflecting him in his questioning.
And after he does it enough, the young assistant minister finally gets frustrated and a little testy.
And he says, why are you bothering me with these questions about predestination? Stuff like that
doesn't have anything to do with what we're trying to accomplish here. Well, my word for this is
post-doctrinalism. People have affiliations, people have beliefs, people want to connect to
the religious sphere of life. I'm referring to the United States.
I don't know if it's true elsewhere.
But for most, getting all exercised about this piece of doctrine versus that piece
is just not something that captures their imagination. A survey taken in 2010 found that 41% of all Americans expect that Jesus will
either definitely or probably have returned to earth by the year 2050. That's in 29 years, what are the economic consequences of such a large number of people holding such a
belief? Oh, gee, I have no idea. I find it fascinating that that number of people
have this belief. Incidentally, again, referring to this post-doctrinalism and the idea
that Protestant denominations in the United States don't differ very much in their theology,
you've hit on one point where they really do, and that has to do with the notion of the second
coming. Most of what we call evangelical denominations do very strongly
believe in the real worldliness of Second Coming, and most of what we call the mainline Protestant
denominations, that's the Episcopalians and the Presbyterians and the Methodists and the Congregationalists and so on, don't believe in that.
Now, I suppose that if somebody was really committed to that belief in advance,
now adverting to your question before, maybe that person would feel uncomfortable in the Methodist Church, but I doubt it. I think these post-doctrine,
these eschatological views are not sufficiently, people hold those views, but I don't think
they're sufficiently central that for most people they would govern a choice of denominations such that a person would say,
I'm just not going to be an Episcopalian because I don't want to sit in the pew next to somebody
who doesn't think that. No doubt there are some people, but I don't think that's too prevalent.
Ben, there is so much in your book, Religion and the Rise of Capitalism, that we haven't
had time to speak about today.
I recommend the book to people.
I want to say thank you for all the work that you do, and thank you so much for sharing
your time with me today.
Thank you for the conversation, Joe.
I enjoyed this enormously, and maybe someday I'll get to come to Australia and you and I'll have a pleasant
lunch together and we'll get to meet. But I enjoyed this afternoon's conversation very much.
Thank you for having me.
Thank you so much for listening. You will find the transcript for this episode on my website,
josephnoelwalker.com. If're enjoying the show i would hugely appreciate a rating and
a review on itunes i know everybody asks but it does help people find us and it does help us reach
the hard to reach guests the audio engineer for the jolly swagman podcast is lawrence morefield
our very thirsty video editor is al fetty i'm joe walker until next time thank you for listening
ciao editor is Alfetti. I'm Joe Walker. Until next time, thank you for listening. Ciao.