The Jordan B. Peterson Podcast - Bjørn Lomborg

Episode Date: December 8, 2018

I spoke December 7, 2018 with Bjørn Lomborg, author and President of Copenhagen Consensus Center, a singularly innovative and influential US-based think tank. Mr. Lomborg and his team have done the ...hard conceptual and empirical work necessary to turn good intentions for global improvement into implementable and economically efficient strategies. That's really saying something.

Transcript
Discussion (0)
Starting point is 00:00:00 Welcome to the Jordan B. Peterson podcast. You can support these podcasts by donating to Dr. Peterson's Patreon, the link to which can be found in the description. Dr. Peterson's self-development programs, Self-Authoring, can be found at selfauthoring.com. Thank you. Bjorn Lomberg is a Danish author and president of the Copenhagen Consensus Center, a project-based U.S. think tank where prominent economists are seeking to establish priorities for advancing global welfare. He's the former director of the Danish government's Environmental Assessment Institute in Copenhagen. Bjorn became known internationally for his book, The Skeptical Environmentalist, in 2001, and How to Spend
Starting point is 00:01:16 $75 Billion to Make the World a Better Place. Cool It, in 2007, which is also a movie, and lately, published in 2018, Prioritizing Development, a Cost-Benefit Analysis of the UN's Sustainable Development Goals, among many other works and books. And so I'm hoping we'll have a very productive conversation today, and welcome to this discussion. Thanks a lot, Jeremy. All right, so why don't you just start by letting people know what you've been up to over the last, let's say, two decades. I know that's a very broad question. And why? I mean, I've been interested in talking to you because I read a number of your books a few years ago, and I was interested in your economic analysis and as a way of determining which crises, let's say, or which potential crises
Starting point is 00:02:07 are real and also how they might be managed most intelligently. Thanks a lot, Jordan. And so, you know, fundamentally what I try to do is to say, and this really is very, very obvious, we only have a limited amount of resources. So let's make sure we focus those resources on the places where we can help the most where we can do the most good remember what is it that we mostly focus on in the world it's very often the things that get the headlines the things that people talk about to talk about and very often that ends up being the things that have you know the cutest animals or the
Starting point is 00:02:40 most crying babies of the groups with the best PR and surely that's not the right way to prioritize the right way should be to look at if I spend a dollar or a peso or a rupee here will I do more good than if I spent that same dollar a rupee a peso over here so basically asking across all the different areas you can spend resources where do I help help the most? Now, obviously, that's a huge conversation in and of itself, because it's not easy to just determine that. But the basic idea is simply to say, let's focus on the places where you can do the most good, rather than the places where it makes us feel the best about ourselves. So that's really what I've been trying
Starting point is 00:03:21 to do for two decades. And, you know, prioritizing the world and trying to say, where should you spend money, of course, makes the projects that we say, these are the really, really great interventions. They all love us and think we're like the best things at sliced bread. But of course, the projects and the policies that are not so effective, they think we're terrible. So, you know, it creates a lot of antagonism and makes a lot of people annoyed and interested. But I think it's crucial to ask these questions. Well, one question would be, what's the alternative? You know, like when I was looking at the UN development goals, for example, if I remember correctly, there was something
Starting point is 00:03:57 approximating 200 of them. And this was a few years ago, I worked on a UN panel. And I thought, well, the problem with 200 goals is that you can't have 200. They're not goals if there's 200 of them, because you absolutely have to prioritize in order to move forward, assuming some limitation on resources, which is exactly what you just described. And so then the question would become, well, how do you calculate benefit? would become, well, how do you calculate benefit? And that's a really difficult problem, which is, I think, why it wasn't addressed with the mishmash of 200 goals, apart from the fact that you're going to offend people by rank ordering their priorities. So why don't you tell people a little bit about the methods that you used? Because I think they're extremely interesting. So you're absolutely right. The Sustainable Development Goals, we actually work with the UN back in 2015 when they were doing this. It was about 60 to 90. It was very unclear. UN ambassadors, I actually met with a quarter of them in New York and talked to each one of them and said, shouldn't we try to focus on the targets that would do the very most good. And of course, each one of them said yes, individually. But the combined
Starting point is 00:05:07 effort of all the UN ambassadors was, of course, not to actually do the best goals. It was to get everybody's goals in there. So, you know, the Norwegians had three ideas, and the Brazilians had four, and everybody else had, you know, three or four that they wanted in there. That's why we ended up with 169 targets, which of course simply means you promise everything to everyone everywhere. And that means a lot of people are going to be very disappointed when 2030 rolls around and we haven't actually dealt with all the things that we promised. Right. So what happens there is that you, the people who are doing that and including everyone on the list, maximize short-term emotional well-being of the people who are doing that and including everyone on the list maximize short-term emotional well-being
Starting point is 00:05:45 of the people who had been doing the consultation at the cost of medium to long-term progress. But then again, they're not going to be around in 2030 in all possibility to suffer the consequences of that. Or at least nobody's going to see that we failed to do as much good as we possibly could because we will have done a little bit of good everywhere. But doing a little good everywhere is not nearly as good as doing an enormous amount of good in the places where you can do the very most good with extra resources. Again, remember, we're estimating the total cost of the SDGs is somewhere in the range of two and a half trillion dollars. And the actual amounts available is
Starting point is 00:06:25 about a hundred and forty billion dollars so we literally have five percent of what we're promising so we're promising the world and then we say hey here's a small amount of money and let's spread it thinly so everybody gets a little bit of it okay so that's that's so that's partly where you derive your premise that we're dealing with limited resources is that you're actually using a real number and the number you're using is what's actually available and when you wrote how to spend 75 billion you basically took half of what it was available that yes that was a book much
Starting point is 00:06:56 much earlier on and that was mostly sort of a it's a fun idea to say how would you spend a specific amount yes and that was half uh so so we weren't saying we should spend all of it in the exact way that we were talking about okay so to agree with you so to agree with you people have to agree that everything can't be done for everyone all at once at infinite expense and that it's useful practically and and also even in a utopian sense in the desirable sense to rank order so that the obvious money that's available, the money that's genuinely available, can be targeted best. And so then the next question would be, how do you go about that in the least controversial and most empirically
Starting point is 00:07:36 sound manner to do the rank ordering? So we use cost-benefit analysis, which is a very well established economic tool that tries to say, all right, for each of the proposals that you come up with, how much will that proposal cost? Now, remember, this is not just economics. Most of the cost will be money. But for instance, if you want to immunize small children, you also have to ask the mothers to spend perhaps a day to go to the place where their kids will be immunized. That'll both cost them labor. They can't do labor that day. Maybe they'll have transportation costs. They'll have food costs. There'll be extra other costs. So we try to add all of those costs up
Starting point is 00:08:15 and say, so what's the total cost of this project? Then we look at all the benefits. And remember, the benefits are both economic, yes, but they're also social. For instance, kids not dying or kids not being sick. And they are often also environmental. So we try to take all of those benefits, so both the economic, the environmental, and social benefits, add them all up into one number that is denominated in dollars or rupees or whatever your currency is. And then you can say, well, for this many dollars, you can do this much good. And that means you can also say for every dollar spent, you can do this much good. Now, obviously, I'm simplifying this. But in a sense, what it means is if you do
Starting point is 00:08:56 it right, and a lot of economists spend a lot of time trying to make this right, if you have all the same parameters across all these different areas, it actually means you can start comparing different interventions across all the different areas and say, where do you get the biggest bang for your buck? And of course, that is what matters if you're actually going to do good. So we did, and this is not, please don't buy this book because this is a very long and academic book. But we did this long and academic book with more than 50 of the world's top economists looking across all these different areas. But the beauty is you can actually put it in just one chart. And I'm going to show you that. And we'll also put it up on your website. So this is the one page chart that has all the targets here. And for each of the targets,
Starting point is 00:09:43 there's an analysis that says, how much will this cost? How much good will it do? And then it shows for every dollar spent, how much good will it do? If it's a long line, it'll do a lot of dollars of good. If it's a short line, not so much. So it really becomes this very simple menu for the world to say, where can you spend your resources? And of course, this doesn't mean, you know, just like when you go into a restaurant, you get a menu, doesn't mean you buy the cheapest thing or the most nutritious thing. Maybe you're in the mood for, you know, an unhealthy cake, but it's incredibly important to know what is the cost and what's the benefit. And knowing this makes it a lot more likely that the world is going to focus itself on some of the really long bars
Starting point is 00:10:26 Where it can do a lot of good for every dollar or rupee or peso spent. Okay, so now if I was thinking about critiquing this let's say from a social science and or a political perspective the first thing that I would object is well How do you how is it that you know that your calculation of the costs and the benefits are accurate? And how do you know that they're essentially as free as possible of any undue political bias? Your critics, no doubt, will object, as perhaps they should, that there will be, let's call them, implicit biases, even though I'm not a fan of that idea in some sense. There's going to be underlying presuppositions that weight the manner in which the economic calculations are made. And then, of course, you also have to buy the idea that the cost-benefit analysis approach is actually valid. So can you tell me what you guys did to forestall such,
Starting point is 00:11:25 to take such criticisms into account? Sure. And so first of all, we don't just ask one team of economists. We also have other teams critiquing those economists. And we exactly try to make sure that there's sort of critiques from both sides, if you will. So we know that this is not just an ideologically driven number, but it's actually an empirically pretty clear number that says, for instance, if you focus on vaccinations, you're actually going to do, and what we find is, you're going to do $60 of social good for every dollar you spend. Now, you could argue, well, what would be sort of the ideological spin you could put on that? Well, one thing is to say, well, did you measure all humans as equal?
Starting point is 00:12:08 Yes, we actually did. And of course, you could argue from an economic point of view that they're not. I think very few people would want to do that. But what we do is across all these areas, all people are ranked as equally important, that is equally valuable. And that's obviously a political consideration. But I think one, if we're looking across the world, that is the right one. If anything, that probably means that most rich country people are valued at way too little compared to what they're actually willing to do themselves. But this means that we actually get
Starting point is 00:12:42 the waiting right in the sense of saying, where are you going to spend extra money if your goal is to help the most in the world? Right. Okay. So you used an approach that was basically, I would say, a solid measurement approach from the theoretical perspective. Because the idea would be to have multiple measures of the same phenomenon or set of phenomena and and to see where they uh dovetail and so that would be an issue of reliability so if you have multiple teams of economists and they all converge on something that approximates an agreement and you look at a diverse range of opinions then you can be reasonably certain that you've converged on something that's real and then you also have an element of peer review in there. Yes. Another way of filtering. Go ahead. And exactly. Both of these are obviously important to make sure, as you say, that you get the reliability and that you actually get
Starting point is 00:13:35 something that resembles somewhat of a truth. But the real point here is, of course, in some way, if we just take a step back, this is not a question about getting the absolute numbers exactly right. I mean, that would be wonderful if we could do that. But when I just told you that, you know, vaccination, every dollar you spend will give you $60 back in the dollar, it'd be very, very unlikely that that's the right number. But it's much, much more about getting the order of magnitude right. Is it 60 or is it 6 or is it $600 you get back? Because really the point here is to compare across all these other things that you could also have spent that money on. And there we have a much greater sort of reliability because we're pretty sure that even if you change the assumption very much, you will still get much of the same
Starting point is 00:14:24 kind of picture. You won't get exactly the same picture, but will still get much of the same kind of picture. You won't get exactly the same picture, but you'll very much get the same sort of picture, which indicates that there's a few targets that will do an amazing amount of good, and there's a lot of targets that will just do a little good. And so again, we try to say is do the amazing targets first. Okay, so the critical thing for you guys to get right is the rank ordering and not the absolute magnitude. So as long as your method is stable across all the different domains, then the rank ordering should be relatively stable. Now, did you get a Pareto distribution with regards to positive impact of investment? Like, is there a handful of interventions that are clearly head and shoulders above the rest in terms of generating positive
Starting point is 00:15:06 economic outcome? And what proportion of the total number of, say, 170 goals, like if you did, if you accomplish 10% of the 170 goals, how much of the economic bang for your buck would you accrue? I should actually just say, I didn't plant that question. That's wonderful, because that's exactly what we tried to do. So if you do across all these areas every dollar spent will do about seven dollars of good if you just did it across all of them equally which is probably unreasonable to assume but it's not unreasonable in the sort of first order approximation. If you spend it on the best 19 targets you would do $32 of good.
Starting point is 00:15:46 So more than four times more good. So you can simply spend the same dollar and do more than four times more good than you would do if you just scattershot it across all areas. And again, what you also have to remember is a lot of the things that we're looking at, which are really, really really effective also things that are much easier to do so two of the best things that we point out is actually contraception so family planning for women why because if you do that not there's a there's about 13% of women that still don't have access to contraception and if they got that access they would be able to better space their kids. And we know that that means that you can actually have your kids when you're ready to have them. That
Starting point is 00:16:29 means you put more effort and investment into your kids. So they'll grow up better, they'll be fed better, they'll have a greater chance of surviving, but they'll also become more productive in the long run. It also means fewer of those kids are going to die, fewer moms are going to die. So we actually estimate you'd see about 600,000 fewer kids die. And you would get a demographic dividend that is basically because you have slightly fewer kids, you can invest more in them, you get better return on every kid, you have slightly higher growth rates. And so we estimate for every dollar you spend on family planning, you will do $120 of social good. The other great thing is invest in free trade. Free trade is something that we've sort of forgotten. We actually had the last big free trade discussion from Doha back in 1999. It's basically stopped being a concern, obviously with Trump, but also
Starting point is 00:17:26 with many other people who've sort of given up on free trade. Yet, we have to remember that one of the basic things that have made us wealthy is the fact that we trade with each other. You do what you're good at, and I do what I'm good at. And that means when we exchange, we actually all get better off. There's some issues here. Maybe you could tell people in some detail what that would mean practically. What are the sorts of barriers that you guys determined were particularly troublesome that need to be addressed? So we actually estimated what would it take to get a reasonably successful Doha round, which would not be free trade, but it would be freer trade. So it would simply be reduced tariffs, make it easier for everyone to trade across the world, especially
Starting point is 00:18:11 from the developing world to the developed world. And one of the outcomes we found was not only that on average, every person in the world would be about, sorry, in the developing world would be about $1,000 richer per person per year in 2030. So by the end of these sustainable development goals, we would lift 145 million people out of poverty. But we would simply make everyone better off because if you're in a poor country, you would be able to sell the things that you do best a little easier, a little cheaper, and hence be able to market more of it. And you'd be able to buy back more from other developed countries. And that would make everyone better off.
Starting point is 00:18:50 So again, this is not rocket science. If you look at China, for instance, China over the last 30 years lifted 680 million people out of poverty, very largely driven by the fact that they could trade with the rest of the world. Imagine if we could make that happen for sub-Saharan Africa, if we could make that happen more for Latin America. So again, it's more about realizing that for very little money, some of these things can do an amazing amount of good.
Starting point is 00:19:16 And we tend to forget because there's no focus on these issues. We don't think about family planning or free trade or indeed vaccinations. We think about all kinds of other things like plastic waste or global warming or many other things that have a lot of sort of attention from celebrities and get in the newspaper. And that's not because there are no problems, but it's about getting a sense of what's the magnitude of how much good we can do with little money and let's talk about global warming because my okay so my my i've talked to lots of people about your work and you know you obviously have a lot of admirers and you have a
Starting point is 00:19:57 lot of detractors and i'll be listening to the detractors because i believed after i had reviewed the un development goals I'd come to the same conclusion that you had come to before I knew what you had done which was these things need to be rank ordered because otherwise it's it's not a plan it's not a strategy and so then there has to be some mechanism for rank ordering them and I ran across your work and I thought well that seems to be exactly right to me from a from an agnostic perspective let's say it's an interesting idea because what you have to start with is the willingness to be agnostic about what the worst problems are and and while the worst and most solvable problems let's say at the same time you have to be agnostic about
Starting point is 00:20:36 that and I actually think that that's part of the reason why what you do bothers so many people because they have an a priori commitment to what constitutes the most salient catastrophe and that's clearly at the moment is is the i the idea that uh climate change um or global warming depending on how you want to phrase it um constitutes such an immediate and pressing threat of of overwhelming economic magnitude that a sacrifice of any amount is worth some probability of forestalling that. And so one of the things that's striking about your list, and maybe what I should do is have you tell us what the top seven or eight are, just so that we have some sense of what the priorities are. Because one of the things I noticed was that they don't tend to include measures that are designed to forestall global warming.
Starting point is 00:21:28 Yeah, so we actually, we had two Nobel laureates look over all of this evidence and set priorities and come out with 19 targets that they focused on. And actually, one of them was stop fossil fuel subsidies, which is obviously a stupid idea in so many different ways. Remember, this is most in developing countries, where it's very often done to basically pacify the population a little bit like you make subsidies for bread or other things. But of course, the idea of subsidizing fossil fuels like Venezuela has done and Indonesia has done is basically a way of subsidizing fairly wealthy people to drive their car, that you have to have a car in order to enjoy
Starting point is 00:22:10 this, and drive it more and actually create more congestion, more air pollution, and with very few benefits. So clearly what you should be doing is scrap those subsidies for fossil fuels, not only because they lead to more air pollution and CO2 emissions, but also because they're just terribly bad use of public resources that could have been spent on education or health or other places where they could have done a lot more good. But just to give you a sense of some of the other ones that we were talking about, expanded immunization, as we talked about, that's an incredibly good way. We know that we're right now cut child mortality, that is under five mortality, from about 12 million kids dying every year in 1990 to about 6 million.
Starting point is 00:22:55 That's a fantastic achievement. But of course, 6 million is still a mind-boggling number that's way, way too large. And we actually know that by investing about a billion dollars, we could save a million kids every year. You've got to almost say that again. For a billion dollars you could save a million kids lives every year. Why the hell is that not one of our top priorities? That's also why we show for every dollar spent you'll actually do $60 worth of good. Another incredible investment is in nutrition. So, you know, everybody kind of
Starting point is 00:23:27 knows that it's not right that people are starving. And we know that we could actually feed everyone. The main reason why people are still starving is because they don't have enough money. It's not because we can't produce it. So it's because they're poor and they don't actually have the demand capacity. But the real tragedy of malnutrition is that if you get it when you're really small, so from zero to two years of age, your brain develops less. And that means when you get into school, you're actually less able to learn. And that stays with you for your entire life. You stay less long in school, you learn less, and you come out and you actually are not very productive. We know this now. We've had this as a theoretical argument for a long time. But researchers and some
Starting point is 00:24:11 of the researchers that we work with have now actually proven this, because they went back to an old study done in Guatemala in the late 1960s, where researchers went to two small villages in rural Guatemala and gave the kids there, so the really small zero to two-year-olds, good food. And then they took two other rural villages nearby and gave the kids essentially sugar water. Of course, you couldn't do this today. But the brilliant thing about this is our researchers then refound these kids. They're now in their late 30s, early 40s.
Starting point is 00:24:41 And you could see what had happened. And it was exactly what the theory predicted. If you had gotten good food, you stayed longer in school, you'll learn more every year in school. And so when you came out, you were much more productive. And one of the ways we measure that is you had higher incomes. If you avoid it being stunted, you had 60% higher income. That's just a phenomenal outcome. So again, spend money, for instance, on malnutrition by getting good food and also research and development into better yielding varieties. And you can do an incredible amount of good for every dollar. We estimate $35 or thereabouts. Right. And so what you're doing is
Starting point is 00:25:19 forestalling cognitive deterioration in the first two years. And because cognitive ability is a great predictor of long-term success, then you're producing people who are much more likely to be economically productive for themselves and for other people right and so yeah the crucial bit is it's also for other people right if you're if you're good you're likely to make other people better too yeah right oh yes that's an absolutely crucial issue so so yeah so so it's quite striking it was quite striking to me when i came across your work to find out to what degree it was focused on targeting children's health in some fundamental sense in the developing world that seems to be i mean if you had to put it in that nutshell correct me if i'm wrong that seemed to be
Starting point is 00:26:02 where you guys focused or where that where your focus took you and so what else can i just say because there's also some other very low-hanging fruit for instance uh what you're seeing increasingly across the world is that more and more people die not of infectious diseases because we've actually tackled many of those but they die from old age diseases like cancer and heart disease those are by far the biggest issues cancer it turns out to be fairly costly to deal with but heart disease we've actually now figured out pretty much how to deal with not to the extent that we will live forever but that we can make people live much longer and that's basically by giving very cheap
Starting point is 00:26:41 and off patent heartent heart medication. So we give this to a lot of middle-aged people in the developed world, and it's very, very cheap to also do in the developing world. So we can save about three years of life for these elderly people, both men and women, and it costs peanuts, and you can basically make all lives longer. And so that's one of the places where we also show there's a huge benefit. We also emphasize, and this is again, one of the depressing things, that we should be focusing a lot more on tuberculosis. Tuberculosis is now the world's leading infectious disease killer. It's no longer HIV AIDS. That's still a good idea to invest in,
Starting point is 00:27:21 but it's actually an even better idea to invest in tuberculosis. But again, because it's an old disease, it's been with us for hundreds of years and we've kind of learned how to fix it a hundred years ago, it's not an issue in the developed world so most people don't want to hear about it, don't care about it. But it's a crucial killer that kills 1.4 million people every year in the developing world and we have the means to eradicate pretty much all of those deaths very very cheaply so again that's one of the places where we say spend money here because you can do an amazing amount of good so I think we're just simply looking for where are the really good deals if you want to do something about global warming as you then you
Starting point is 00:28:02 should ask yourself well how are we going to fix this so there's two things to global warming one is as you mentioned there's a sense in which uh people believe it's the overwhelming danger that's going to undermine the entirety of human civilization and just like pretty much all other problems that's just not true this is a problem it's not the end of the world uh if you look at the economics that's been done, the Nobel Prize was just awarded in climate economics to William Nordhaus this year. And he's been a guy working almost three decades on what are the costs and the benefits of climate action. And he finds the cost of climate, so climate change is about, and he's backed up by a lot of other economists, is somewhere between two and four percent of GDP by the end of the century. So
Starting point is 00:28:52 remember, by then we'll be, you know, say four or five times richer, so we'll be 405 percent as rich as we are now, but we will see a drop in our incomes worth about 2% to 4% less than we would otherwise have had. That's a problem, but it's by no means the end of the world. And that's the first thing you sort of need to recognize. This is a problem. It's not the end of the world. Because if you think it's the end of the world, as you rightly pointed out, then you're willing to throw everything and the kitchen sink at it. But if it's a problem, you will act exactly like what I think we should do with all problems, say, all right, there's a lot of problems. Let's ask, where can we spend a dollar and fix most of that problem? And unfortunately, that's not climate
Starting point is 00:29:35 change. It's actually really, really hard to just change a tiny bit of climate change with a lot of money. And that's why we find that most of the interventions that you do for climate change with a lot of money. And that's why we find that most of the interventions that you do for climate change turns out to be fairly poor. They're not necessarily bad investments, some of them are. But even, you know, for instance, adaptation or get more energy for poor countries give you sort of, you know, two, five dollars back in the dollar, which is nice. But in the big scheme of things, there are much, much better places you can spend your resources on. Okay, so let's look at this. Well, because I'm really curious about this, because I can't see any a priori problems with your method. It seems to me to make a lot of sense. And if your goal is to do the most amount of good in
Starting point is 00:30:22 the shortest period of time with the least amount of resources, which seems like a pretty damn good goal, and to be realistic about what's attainable, then I can't see that anyone's done a better job from a methodological perspective than you guys have. Okay, but now, but you still face a tremendous amount of opposition. And most of that does come from the climate side of things, as far as I can tell. And so I've been trying to think through why that might be. And so when I reviewed the climate literature, which was a few years ago, I had some real concerns about measurement accuracy and so forth, because it's a very complicated issue. And it's not the constants that should be associated with increase in carbon dioxide aren't obvious, and there's quite wide error bars around them. And then carbon dioxide has all sorts of weirdly complicated effects, like increasing global greening, which is quite an interesting one.
Starting point is 00:31:15 And so anyways, and it also struck me that if you project out the climate change estimates across about a 50 to 100 year period, the error bars grow very large as you move outward, obviously, because the errors multiply. And then it struck me that we're in a situation where the error bars out 50 years are so wide that even if we did what people recommended now, we could never be sure that it actually worked. never be sure that it actually worked. Because you can't, the propagation of error across all those decades makes the picture so blurry two or three, four decades down the road that there's no way of garnering evidence about the effectiveness of your intervention. And if it's a high-cost intervention, that seems to be a really bad idea. So, okay, and I'm going to step one more step backwards, which is,
Starting point is 00:32:03 so, I also found it difficult to trust the climate science. And the reason for that was that it struck me as motivated by issues, at least in some part, that were outside of the science. it seems to me that a tremendous amount of what motivates people's psychological commitment to the idea of climate change is an underlying is something like an underlying anti-western or anti-capitalist ethos and that the idea is that we should restrict growth and we should restructure the economic system and that would address climate change and that would be a positive thing and forestall the apocalypse but the real goal seems to be more to find an ethical justification for the political position that requires the retooling of these economic systems. And so, well, I guess the first thing I'd like to know is, does that strike you as a reasonable argument? Because I can't see otherwise
Starting point is 00:33:03 why people would be objecting to what it is that you're doing. Yeah, so there's a lot of questions in there. Let me just try to unpack some of this. So I think if you look out, yes, there's a lot of uncertainty going forward. Some of that actually cancels out when you're saying, well, we're uncertain about how much the temperature rise will be. But we do know that if the causal mechanism is CO2 leads to higher warming, if you take some of the CO2 out, you will get less of it. Now, we don't exactly know how much, where you get it less, whether it was a lot down here a little bit or whether it was here and down a little bit. But you actually get a little bit the same thing. or whether it was here and down a little bit, but you actually get a little bit the same thing.
Starting point is 00:33:48 So you can take some of the error bars out because you're only looking at the difference, and you're not actually looking at the actual input. The other thing, I'm in no doubt that there's a lot of, you know, other reasons why people latch on to social phenomena. So, you know, when some climate scientists say we should cut carbon emissions because this is leading to a really dangerous issue, there's a lot of other people who will see, oh, that actually fits with my ideological presupposition, so I'll actually join in this conversation. I think that happens in a lot of different areas. And what we're trying to do is to sort of step back and say, look, I'm not going to get into all of that. I'm simply taking as the starting point. We're economists. I'm actually not, I'm a political scientist, but all the people I work with are economists. We just take as given what the climate
Starting point is 00:34:34 scientists are telling us. I think it's an interesting conversation to say, did they actually get it somewhat wrong? And I think certainly, you know, somebody should be looking into it. But, you know, I've met a lot of these climate scientists. My sense is that they're good, hardworking, you know, scientists that are actually trying to find out what's up and down in this area. So we simply take our starting point with the UN Climate Panel.
Starting point is 00:34:58 What we do is simply ask, how much will it cost to cut carbon emissions so much that we will see a significant change in temperature and of course remember we emit co2 not because we want to bother algor or anyone one else it's a byproduct of having a life that is incredibly much nicer than one we would have if we didn't have access to a lot of energy. I mean, we can sit and talk here across the continent, but also, you know, you have heating and you have cooling and you have fertilizer that subsidizes, you know, artificial fertilizer that basically feeds half the world's population
Starting point is 00:35:35 and a lot of other benefits that come from mostly using fossil fuels. So if you want to get rid of some of those fossil fuels, and possibly all of them, you will have to replace it with more expensive energy. And that's why it costs to cut carbon emissions. Now, that may be worth the cost, but that's exactly the question that we try to ask. And that's what William Nordhaus, the Nobel laureate in climate economics, and many others have asked. So it's really important to note that you're not questioning the science
Starting point is 00:36:06 as it stands now, the consensus, so that this is purely a consequence of economic calculation. This is only about saying, good, CO2 impacts warming, and it does so in the way that the UN Climate Panel tells us. Now, that's not entirely true because there's a lot of things that they tell us, and there's a whole variability, and we try to take that into account into account but honestly it turns out that if you do it on the central estimates you get pretty much what i'm about to tell you okay so what you find is if you cut carbon emissions now you can have a little bit of impact in 100 years but it will have a significant cost
Starting point is 00:36:41 now it's not going to put us to the poorhouse. Nobody's talking about that. Just like we're not talking about the end of the world if we don't do something about climate change, we're not talking about the end of the world if we do something about climate change either. So I want to sort of dial back on the rhetoric, both on the alarmists that say, oh my God, the world is coming to an end, or the people who are saying, oh, we can't afford this and we're all going to the poorhouse if you want to have solar panels and wind turbine. No. These are both manageable costs. These are sort of in the order of 2% to 4%.
Starting point is 00:37:10 But the problem is that if we do sort of things that cost 1% to 2% of GDP right now and for the rest of the century, we basically solve almost no part of the global warming problem. We probably solve about 1 part of the global warming problem. We'd probably solve about 1% of it. So basically by incurring a cost of 1 to 2% of GDP now and every year throughout the rest of the century, you'll have solved almost none of the problem come 2100. So you still have to pay all the same problems that global warming is incurring minus a slight amount and then you paid one to two percent every year that's the basic idea why most cost benefit analyses show that unless you do it
Starting point is 00:37:54 very carefully and only do a little bit of cutting and do it really smartly you're actually incurring higher costs than the problem you're trying to solve. So we can thread the needle and do it really carefully, but that requires a lot of smartness from a lot of politicians. But if we do it really bluntly, we're just going to incur lots of costs and actually not get very many benefits. Okay, so when the people who are not happy with you for not prioritizing climate change to the degree that it should be, hypothetically. How do they criticize your statements? Like, on what basis do they decide that your conclusions are inappropriate? I think, I mean, if you read most of the internet, there's a lot of things that'll just say, oh, you're a denier, you can't say, you know, sort of, we're going to excommunicate
Starting point is 00:38:41 you, we don't want to talk to you, that's not right. I'm not really going to talk about those people because that's just, you know, that's political posturing rather than anything else. I think there's a reasonable argument to be made to say that's not the only way that you can approach this. So there's two ways that you can think about cost-benefit analysis actually showing that climate impacts are worth doing. One is to say, ah, but there might be a tiny risk, even just a tiny risk, that the whole world is going to spin out of control and we're all going to die kind of
Starting point is 00:39:12 thing. And, you know, that's not implausible, especially if you say sort of, I'm not going to put a percentage on it, but it's not, it's greater than zero. So there's a non-zero chance that global warming will spin out of control and will basically be, you know, relegate a few hundred couples of humans living on an ice-free Antarctica. So that's a positive feedback loop argument, right? That we might trigger mechanisms like the melting of the Greenland ice sheet, for example, that would flood the world
Starting point is 00:39:41 or cause some irreparable catastrophe of unparalleled magnitude. Okay, so I have a question about that, because that's a tricky one to address, right? That's kind of an apocalyptic argument. And then the argument would be, well, if there's a 1% chance of an infinite apocalypse, it's worth any donation of resources to stave it off. So one way of thinking about that is actually to multiply the catastrophes. Because my suspicions are that that same argument could be used in relationship to a lot of the other problems that you are trying to address. number of people in abject poverty over the next 20 years, let's say, more than we'd have to, that we would increase the probability of the generation of epidemic and infectious diseases.
Starting point is 00:40:39 Because poverty, poor people are a risk to everyone in this, there's a horrible way of thinking about it, but poverty is a risk to everyone. That's a better way of thinking about it because decreased global human health is also a breeding ground for all sorts of catastrophes that might emerge. And then there's also the possibility of political instability and nuclear war and all of those things that are also equally apocalyptic. So it seems to me to be reasonable to some degree to say, look, there's the possibility across a wide range of potential crises of unforeseen positive feedback loops spiraling out of control, but we can't introduce them into the argument unless we can parameterize them, because it's an unfair game move in some sense, because you can't be not wrong about that. Exactly, and you're basically saying saying if you allow it in this area, just because you like that particular area and say, I want you to focus more money on my thing, which is climate change, you could equally well do it in all kinds of other areas. of risk but it's also that they breed terrorism and willingness to you know uh do a lot of bad
Starting point is 00:41:45 things you know focused so it's not just something that happens but you know uh thrown by terrorists and our ability to keep you know all the plutonium in the world under under lock and and you know you can get catastrophe from anything yeah so abject poverty for example you could imagine that there might be two socioeconomic contributions to that. There would be the absolute number of people in abject poverty who are therefore desperate. And then there would also be maybe another contribution of excess inequality and a sense that the world isn't laying itself out fairly and that that would justify political and revolutionary instability. political and revolutionary instability. And also just state failure and many other things that we know make it a lot easier for everyone to make really bad things like we saw out of Afghanistan with 9-11.
Starting point is 00:42:35 A lot of other things, you know, once you get failed states, you get a lot of bad things happen. Right, okay, so we try to make people better off globally so that we decrease the probability of large-scale political and economic instability. And that's another way of staving off an apocalypse. Yes. Okay, and then on the... Can I just say, so Nordhaus actually looked at this, the Nobel laureate, because some people argued exactly what you said. There's a tiny risk that things go really, really bad, so we should spend all of our money on this issue. But of course, that's a failed argument, because likewise,
Starting point is 00:43:09 there's a lot of small risks everywhere else. We know one risk, which is being hit by an asteroid. That could wipe out the Earth. Yet, and Nordhaus did that, I thought that was very, very elegant. And Nordhaus did that. I thought that was very, very elegant. We know that we can track all of those asteroids out there, 99.99%. But we chose to only track 90% because tracking the rest was too expensive. So you can actually see that we put a price on how much are we willing to do this. And of course, that's just one place where we have a very clear example that we say, do this. And of course, that's just one place where we have a very clear example that we say, we care somewhat for the future, but we don't care about it entirely. We have lots of other issues that we want to focus on right now. So that's just like every other area. You have to argue, what is the risks and what are the opportunities to do this? And absolutely,
Starting point is 00:44:02 given that there are some risks, and there are probably more downside risks and upside risks for global warming, we should probably do a little more than what we would otherwise do. And that's exactly what the models show us. And those are the models that we use in making the estimate of how much should you be paying for global warming. So yes, we should take that into account. But it's not a good argument. That was that was one argument. I'm sorry, I'll try to be a little with the other argument. The other argument is that people will say one of the reasons why it doesn't pay to do global warming is because you have to pay now, but the benefits come far up into the future. So basically you do something now that's fairly costly, and then you get a tiny benefit in 100 years. So you have to really say the future is incredibly important. And economic speak, that is that the discount is really low, that you really care a lot about the future. Now,
Starting point is 00:44:51 a lot of people would argue, we should, you know, we're rich, we should be able to care enormously about the future. And if you change that parameter enough, and you say we care enormously about future generations, it actually turns out that global warming becomes a good deal. Doing something about global warming actually goes from saying you spend a dollar and you do a couple of cents of climate damage, sorry, to avoid climate damage, you actually spend a dollar and you might do two dollars of climate benefit. So it actually turns it into a good idea. But here's the the kicker if you care that much about the future you change every other one of all of these priorities and make them boom
Starting point is 00:45:30 right because obviously happens is you've just said I care so much about the future that the guy that I will save from not having tuberculosis and dying from it tomorrow will now go on to have a successful life his kids will live longer they'll do better he will have a successful life. His kids will live longer. They'll do better. He will have a better, his nation will do better. That means they'll be much, much better off in 2100 and so on. And that means this is no longer a question of saying you spend a dollar and you get $43 worth of good, but you spend a dollar and you get $1,000 worth of good.
Starting point is 00:46:01 So what you've achieved is basically just made everything a great idea. And that's also intellectually making the discount rate very, very small. What it means is you should basically starve. You should just eat porridge every day and spend all of the rest of your money on the future because you care so much about it. Now, if you do that, I applaud your consistency, but most people just don't do this. And we certainly don't do this in the way that you know we don't seem to care all that much about our pension systems which are in many rich countries going to fail in the next 20 to 40 years yeah all these other issues so as long as you're saying no no what you're really saying then is on climate we want to care a lot about the future but we don't want to do it in all other areas okay you're going to be consistent you need to do it across all areas
Starting point is 00:46:48 and then you need to be very hungry and only eat porridge right okay so your claim basically from a methodological perspective is that your rank ordering remains constant across variable discount rates yes right and that's a really that's a really important that's a really fundamentally important it's not entirely i gotta say it does change some of these interventions. Because obviously, you know, education, for instance, is one of those where you pay now and you only get benefits 10, 20, you know, 50 years out when the kids grow up and they actually become much more productive. So there is a change, but mostly the rank ordering remains the same.
Starting point is 00:47:21 And I'm simply just insisting that people need to be consistent. You can't just say the future is important when you talk about climate. If you want to say the future is important, it's important across all areas. And then you really have to do everything and forego having a good life yourself. Right. Okay. Well, so the other thing that's worthwhile pointing out about the discount rate is that, you know, you can make a case that the future is more important than the present, especially because it extends out so far. But the other reason that people discount the future is because you can't make the case that you can predict the outcome of your actions.
Starting point is 00:47:55 And that means that the error in prediction magnifies itself as you move out farther in time frame. And so what happens is you get to a point where there isn't a lot of point in adjusting your behavior in the present if you look like a hundred years out let's say or a thousand years out because you actually can't calculate with any accuracy the consequence of your actions or inactions and so the the cumulative error makes Discounting the future the appropriate thing to do because you can predict what's going to happen if you act now, now, and maybe tomorrow, but you get much less accurate as you move forward. So even in the best case scenario, where we had the best wishes for the future, that doesn't mean we could justify incredibly radical sacrifices now, because we can't calculate their cumulative impact.
Starting point is 00:48:39 No, there's a good way of thinking about this. If you look at what previous generations have done for us, the only thing that they've really managed to do is to give us a lot more knowledge. So investment in knowledge is actually a great way to help future generations because it helped them in all kinds of ways. And we can't really predict how, but it's probably a good idea to leave them with a lot of books. I'm using that as a metaphor. But trying to help them in a specific way, imagine back 100 years ago, what our forefathers back in the 1920s, no, 1910s,
Starting point is 00:49:14 would have done reasonably to help us now. Chances are they would have wasted a lot of money on things that never turned into problems. There's a wonderful book called Today Now. Sorry. Oh, God, I'm forgetting. Tomorrow Now? Oh, God. Anyway, it has a great and clever title, which I've clearly screwed up now.
Starting point is 00:49:38 But it was back in 1893. The World Fair in Chicago, I believe, asked 50 of the world's smartest people to predict what would the world look like in 100 years. And so all of them first said, you know, I love the fact that I'm not going to be around when this prediction comes true or not. But then they made all their predictions, and they were almost entirely off. You know, there were some that were pretty close. predictions and they were almost entirely off. There were some that were pretty close. There's one that predicted sort of email in the sense of those pneumatic tubes, which is sent away and it would sort of suck it out. And so you could send a letter somewhere. They imagined that that would be a worldwide thing. And so you could actually send a letter everywhere. You just sort of put it in the very, very long tube.
Starting point is 00:50:28 Right, right. Which is kind of right. And you can sort of say, yeah, yeah, that's not entirely wrong. You know, got the whole technology wrong, but the right idea. But the fundamental point is we're probably wrong about so many things, as you say, that trying to help the world in the future by, for instance, cutting temperature might be one of the least effective ways of helping. So there's another thing that's interesting about that, I think, that speaks to the fundamental intelligence of your approach. So one of the things that has struck me as highly likely is that given how complex things are and how rapidly they're
Starting point is 00:51:05 changing, that the best thing we could do to prepare ourselves for the future would be to make better people, smarter people, wiser people, more responsible people, all of that. So there's a psychological element to that. And so I would say some of my work is concentrated on that and the public lectures that I've been doing. But what's interesting about your approach, the economic approach, is that you're diverting a lot of resources to the creation of better people for tomorrow by investing especially in childhood nutrition. So if you, and I suppose this is kind of how economists look at the world, but maybe biologists could look at it this way too.
Starting point is 00:51:42 If you think of people as general problem-solving machines, which is not a bad way of thinking about us, then it might be that given that you don't know which problems are going to be paramount, what you want to do is improve the machines that will solve the problems, whatever those problems happen to be. And so that investment in early childhood development
Starting point is 00:52:02 seems particularly apropos in that regard. And so having said that, I want to return to the climate issue one more time, because here's something peculiar. This is something I don't understand. It's a real mystery. So let's say that just for the sake of argument, that most of the people who are concerned about climate change and its relationship to economic development are on the left side of the spectrum. Okay, but let's also say that those who are on the left side of the spectrum are hypothetically also concerned with the economic well-being of the most dispossessed, and that those might be equally important concerns, and they're integrally locked together. Well, the strange thing about so many of your recommendations is that they're
Starting point is 00:52:45 directly aimed at addressing the immediate now concerns of the fundamentally dispossessed. And so you'd think that that's part of the reason that I can't understand why there's so much objection to your methods, because it's not like what you came up with looks like support for something that's like a right-wing agenda by any stretch of the imagination. First of all, it's predicated on the idea that there's a certain amount of development aid, especially directed to children, you said not exclusively, that would be of great use. And it seems to me to be undeniable that the most dispossessed people in the world are impoverished infants of impoverished people so so what if some of the objections to what you're doing are ideologically motivated why doesn't that cancel it out it's a good question I I don't quite understand it my sense is that in some way so so there I was in
Starting point is 00:53:42 New York in September there was a the first ever summit at the UN for tuberculosis. And I was there because one of the things that we've identified is this is a great investment. And of course, all the tuberculosis people love us because we're pointing out we should spend more money on their problem. And unfortunately, almost nobody went. I wrote an obit together with the South African health minister, and it was widely published in the developing world. But almost no one in the developed world picked it up.
Starting point is 00:54:12 It was only when I wrote another obit where I said there were two meetings taking place in New York. One was this TB place, biggest infectious disease killer in the world, where almost nobody turned up. And then there was the other meeting, which Macron and the French president and Bloomberg and others attended to, which was the climate summit, which everybody attended to. Yeah, yeah, you know, I sort of pointed out the disparity. And then it was picked up in all kinds of developed country papers. I think fundamentally, it goes down to saying, while everybody says they care a lot about the world's poor, the reality is that you care somewhat for it, but most rich, well-meaning people probably care a lot more about the fact that they worry
Starting point is 00:54:57 that their kids might be in a position where global warming is really going to undermine. Right, but even that doesn't make sense, because look, we already established the fact that there's equal reason to be apocalyptically concerned about unchecked poverty and inequality. So this is why I suggested to begin with that one of the lovely things about the idea of climate change is that it really justifies the idea of overthrowing the current system or of undermining the current system. And that if you're inclined to do that, rather than inclined to truly help the dispossessed, let's say, then you'd be more inclined to support a theory that justifies that sort of radical, let's say, interventionist policy. And I can't see a way out of that logically,
Starting point is 00:55:41 given that the work that you're doing on tuberculosis is a great example is directly and evident evidentially associated with a marked increase in the well-being of the dispossessed and so you'd think that you think that would attract the proper amount of ideological attention but it doesn't and that's that's a great mystery there's something about that extraordinary and it's a good point and I think you have a consistent argument the the thing that I've decided a long time ago that I don't want to argue and and I think that's probably the difference between being more psychologically focused I don't want to argue I think might be people's sort of inner motivations I want to
Starting point is 00:56:25 actually take them at face value and you know many people I meet they say I worry a lot about climate change, I worry a lot about the world's poor, and then I try to show them well if you actually do that why the hell would you be focusing on spending lots of money that will almost do no good instead of spending possibly less money and doing it about more good and it creates some cognitive dissonance and i think it it switches people a little bit towards spending smarter but yes you're right but telling people it also might just be ignorance you know it's like what you're doing is pretty new and it takes a long time i mean it's not new for you, and it's not new considering the span of a single lifetime.
Starting point is 00:57:07 But, you know, what you're doing is very radical in some sense, and there isn't anybody else doing it. And so it might be that it will take 20 years or 25 years or something like that for the approach that you're publicizing and have developed for people to actually know about it. You know, and so what do they say? You should assume ignorance instead of malevolence when you can. I do think that ignorance is a part of this. It's not obvious to everyone that there is this method of rank ordering,
Starting point is 00:57:38 that people have done it and that there are consequences to that that could be laid out in an intelligent economic plan. You know, and I know that it takes a finding in the scientific literature, if it's going to make its way into the public, something approximating 15 years. And that's only the ones that actually do manage to make it. And so it could be that just way more people need to know what you're doing and why
Starting point is 00:58:02 and how it was done before it gets the steam going. I'm interested in the psychological issues in part to try to help figure out what it would take to motivate people to be more attentive to the sorts of solutions that you and your people have been putting forward and to eliminate those barriers. But it could just be, as I said, it could just be ignorance. And look, one of the problems that we're facing constantly, and I know why there's no one else doing this than we're doing, because when you do prioritization, you inevitably end up antagonizing a lot of people. I mean, climate change is the most obvious one. But for instance, sanitation, water and sanitation, huge problem.
Starting point is 00:58:44 There's about two and a half billion people affected by this. One of the points that we emphasize is that doing sanitation while a good thing to do, it probably only pays you about three dollars back on the dollar. Why? Because it's actually fairly costly to do sanitation and also because the benefits not nearly as great as what many have assumed, and this is the new global burden of disease estimates, that the real problem is that what you're doing with sanitation is that you're not removing fecal matter from the environment.
Starting point is 00:59:13 You're simply reducing the amount. So you're not actually having all that much of an impact on disease. You're having a little bit, but not nearly as much as what we would like to see. That obviously pisses off all the people who are doing sanitation. And we end up pissing off a lot of people. And the truth is, I think it's necessary if you're going to do this, that when you rank order, of course, the causes that come out on top love it and the causes that don't, don't love it.
Starting point is 00:59:39 But it's also important to make that argument. And so at the end of the day, certainly my sense is it's necessary to do it, but it will always entail a great amount of sort of unease because it doesn't feel like we're saying, you know, kumbaya and we should do everything, but we're actually saying, no, you should do these things, but not all of these things. Although they seem nice, they're just not in the same league. Right, right, right, right.
Starting point is 01:00:08 Well, it would be nice if we could do everything good that we possibly could all at once. But it's not realistic because you can't do everything at once and you don't have infinite resources, as we've already pointed out. So, okay, so what would you say would be, if you're going to play devil's advocate against your own position, which I presume you've done a lot of anyways, are there criticisms against your, let's say, your aims and your methods that you regard as unresolved?
Starting point is 01:00:42 Like, what is it that you're doing that's still weak and wrong in your own estimation? Or where are the limitations in your methods? Well, look, no method does everything. So we have two very obvious problems. One is not all issues is about money. So we're looking at how do you prioritize money, but sometimes money is not the issue. For instance, on free trade, as we talked about before, we estimate the benefit is incredible, but we actually look at the cost as the cost of subsidizing Western farmers because those are the ones that basically make a,
Starting point is 01:01:16 you know, killing from not freeing up global markets. And those are the ones that usually held it back. But what has happened is it has become much more sort of an emotional thing. It's sort of an identity thing, and I'm not sure how you would cost that. So to the extent that things have nothing to do with money, but they're just simply about political willingness or interest or want, then we are not making the argument that is going to convince you. So in some sense, we are telling you where can you spend money, but we're not talking about the things that don't
Starting point is 01:01:51 require money. Right. So people would object that the problem with your method is that you're measuring everything that can be tangibly measured from an economic perspective, but that's actually a small fraction of the universe of properly attended to okay I thought I would tend to say it's probably you know sort of 70 or 80 percent I'm not quite sure how you make that up but you know yeah biggest the biggest policy decisions in most countries is the national budget it's very clear that that is a very substantial part of what we decide how we gonna allocate money well the problem with that's a big issue well the problem with not the only issue right well the problem with the objection is that well the people who are objecting could be right that your methods are narrow i mean
Starting point is 01:02:35 you're making the case they're not as narrow as a yeah as a pessimist might assume but that puts the onus on them to come up with an alternative way of ranking. Right? I mean, I would just say we're not talking about those last 30% that are, you know, purely about, you know, should we have transgender bathrooms or something?
Starting point is 01:02:54 Yeah. Well, that's possibly a bad idea because that actually has cost and, and building a third bathroom or something. But, you know, there are some things that are mostly just about what do you think? What do you believe? What, what are your intuitions, rather than actual costs.
Starting point is 01:03:12 Right, but there's no way of adjudicating between those claims. That's the problem. All that people do is push each other around about them if they can't. And the point is, there's still a substantial amount of issues where you do need to look at resource allocation. And there we have a good argument. The second part, the second sort of criticism, which is a very fair criticism, is we don't look at inequality. So economists are very, very bad at dealing with inequality because fundamentally that's a political issue. So when we look at you spend a dollar and you do $60 worth of good. We don't look at who gets that $60. Now, to be fair, most of the things, as you've also pointed out, most of the things that we actually indicate are really, really low-hanging fruit in the world are things that will help the world's poorest,
Starting point is 01:03:56 mostly because the world's poorest have so many things that they haven't gotten that would be hugely beneficial for them. So it mostly actually helped also inequality, but we don't measure it. And so we don't actually look at, would this be a good expenditure in the sense of helping the world's poorest? Mostly would, but it's not part of our framework. And there's no way of making that.
Starting point is 01:04:22 Well, because cost-benefit analysis is basically assuming that everybody is equally worth. We talked about that earlier. There's no way of sort of, well, you can, but it becomes incredibly unclear and very unintuitive if you start making weightings on who is actually worth more. So we are, again, saying it's a little bit like the menu you get in the restaurant. We're telling you, hey, the spinach is cheap and it has lots of vitamins and the cake is expensive and it's bad for you, but you go ahead and make the choice. And I think that's the fair way to have that conversation that we're telling you some
Starting point is 01:05:02 important facts about your decisions, but these are not the only things that are going to guide your decision. And I'm absolutely happy to say that. So in some sense, you asked me to be devil's advocate. I just think it's important to clarify, we don't look at all issues because we only look at issues that require resources, and we don't deal with inequality, which is also an important issue. But apart from that, deal with inequality, which is also an important issue. But apart from that, we have to make priorities. And we're simply making a little clearer at the end of the day, you can choose to totally disregard it. But I would imagine that you would at least like to know what does the evidence tell you if you spend a dollar here, how many people will you save? How many lives will be improved? How much environment will be improved and so on versus all the other things where you could have spent that dollar and done different
Starting point is 01:05:48 amounts of good in all those different areas and that's what we provide for the menu so do you okay okay well i appreciate that very much um do you have any sense what do you off the top of your head what the total capital expenditure for the minimization or eradication of tuberculosis actually would be? What are you talking about in absolute dollar amounts? So it, and it depends a lot on, because, so we estimate that you need about $2 billion. The global funds that we were also campaigning with are saying it's about $5.8 billion. And to be quite honest, I'm not quite sure which of these two numbers is the right number. I think the, but, you know, compared to, you know, just to give you a sense of proportion, the amount of subsidies
Starting point is 01:06:38 that we give to solar and wind is about $120 billion right now. So, you know, we're talking about a very, very small amount. And certainly it's a very small amount. And, you know, it's about what, three, 4% of global development spending. So the amount of spending that we spend every year to try and help improve the world. And it will probably be one of the very very best things that we could do so again very personal things people need to know these things they and i think that if they did know that they would start to care if they actually knew so okay i got i got two final questions for you i think and then i'll ask you if there's anything else you wanted to that bring to people's attention that that you thought was particularly necessary. Okay, so the first one is, to what degree do you think, I'll ask all three questions, to what degree do you think you've been making headway? Like, obviously, you've been successful in putting together your institutes,
Starting point is 01:07:37 and your work has garnered a substantial amount of attention, published and otherwise, and so it's not like you've been silenced and imprisoned or anything like that. And so are there reasons for optimism as far as you're concerned? And then the next thing that I'd like to ask you about is what's happening in France? Because one of the things that the people who are pushing for radical current interventions with regards to long-term climate change haven't factored in is the reverse apocalyptic issue, which is that there's going to be substantial resistance to the short-term costs that will cause spin-off disasters of their own. And so the French example seems to be a very interesting case in point. So the first question was, how do you feel about the impact that you're
Starting point is 01:08:25 having? And the second is, what do you have to say about what's happening in France? Yeah, I'm going to answer in reverse, because I think the France point is really a good argument. If you ask people around the world, do you care about global warming? Almost everyone will say yes. Do you want to do something for global warming? They'll say yes. Then when you ask them how much are you willing to pay, the typical answer, both in rich and poor countries, is a couple hundred dollars per year. So it goes from 100 to 200 dollars. So fundamentally, what people are saying is, yes, I do worry about this issue. I'm willing to spend a little bit of money, but not very much. And I think this is the fundamental thing that we just have not been able to get to the attention of a lot of people who are pushing for really, really radical solutions. You're never going to
Starting point is 01:09:14 succeed in a democratic situation. If you keep ramping up the taxes on fossil fuels, if you keep making energy more and more expensive, it's going to harm, first of all, the poor the most. It's very, very regressive. And that obviously means a lot of heartache for a lot of poor people. These are typically also the people who are least able to defend themselves because they're just so busy just surviving their day-to-day. So it typically has to hit the middle class before you really get sort of an eruption as what you've seen in France and elsewhere. Let's remember there's also a lot of other issues in France. So it's not just because they put, you know, three cents on a liter of diesel. But it is an issue of saying
Starting point is 01:10:02 if you push people too far, you will actually not be able to do the solution for climate. And so your very, very expensive solutions are never going to be long-term viable. You know, when you predict these ideas of saying, if we had Obama and if he would actually have managed to put a carbon tax on CO2, remember, he actually had a Democratic Congress the first two years of his presidency, and they were still not able to get a carbon tax implemented. Of course, when you have a Republican Congress, it becomes really hard. When you have a Republican president also, it falls apart. You just can't do this for 100 years.
Starting point is 01:10:38 It's just not going to work out. And that's why, and we never got to that, we actually did a climate consensus where we brought together 27 of the world's top climate economists, three Nobel laureates, to look at where can you do good for climate. And what they found was the by far best investment to tackle global warming is to invest in green energy R&D. So fundamentally, if we could invest in making better green energy for the future, hopefully eventually get it to be so cheap that it will outcompete fossil fuels,
Starting point is 01:11:10 we will solve global warming just simply because the green energy became cheaper. If you'll allow me a slight detour. Back in the 1860s, the world was hunting whales to extinction because whales have this wonderful oil. Should I just say that again? Yep. Yeah, all right. Back in the 1860s, we were hunting whales to extinction because whales have this wonderful oil that just burns a lot cleaner and a lot more bright. And so it was wonderful for the houses in North America and in Europe to burn this whale oil, and they were all excited about it. And it had the bad side effect that it was actually pushing whales to extinction.
Starting point is 01:11:54 Now, the sort of global warming approach to that problem would have been to say, could you please turn down the light? Could you please have it a little less light in your room? And of course, you would have entirely failed. What did save the whales was we discovered oil, fossil fuel oil, which were actually burning cleaner. It was much cheaper and you didn't have to go out and kill whales for it. And so what happened about a decade was you stopped killing whales because you got a better technological product. And we've seen this a lot of times, that technology can simply invalidate an old issue, a problem that you thought was almost intractable. If you get cheaper, smarter, new technology,
Starting point is 01:12:33 people will switch. Right, that's imposing limits, expensive limits on people is not an appropriate long-term solution because of implementation resistance and cost. And the best solution is to come up with a, well, let's say to put it in a cliched manner, is to come up with a better solution, which is cheaper energy that has all the advantages and fewer disadvantages. And that's really how you solve the problem. Wind turbines, solar panels, and I'm just taking
Starting point is 01:13:00 the two most popular things, and batteries together, if they were cheaper than fossil fuels, which they aren't right now, but if they were, of course everyone would buy them. We'd stop buying coal-fired power plants. So it's really not rocket science that way. Now, I'm not saying it's going to be easy, and it's certainly not going to happen right now, but it's the only viable long-term solution that's much cheaper
Starting point is 01:13:19 and much more effective. So we estimate that for every dollar spent, you'll actually do about $11 of climate benefit. Okay, so that's on alternative energy? Yes, yes. Okay. So it's not the best thing, but it comes down here. So actually, it's a pretty good investment.
Starting point is 01:13:38 It's not the best in the world, but we should definitely be doing it. The second question that you had was the optimism. So fundamentally, how much of an impact does this have? Well, it's had the impact and very predictable impact that when we come out and say, for instance, more immunization gives you $60 back on the dollar. The people who are doing immunization tells you all the time, you should fund us because we do $60 in good for every dollar you spend. So very clearly, I sat down with a guy from a family foundation, a big family foundation. We were at a malaria event, and we sat and politely conversed. And he would say, so what do you do?
Starting point is 01:14:23 Well, I work with the Copenhagen Consensus Center. Totally blacks there. And then I asked, so what do you do? Well, I work with the Copenhagen Consensus Center, you know, totally black stare. And then I asked him, what do you do? Well, we work with malaria. Did you know that actually, if you spend a dollar in malaria, you'll do $33 worth of good? And I was like, yeah, we did that number. And this is exactly the point. We're not there to get attention. We're there to make sure that we get attention to some of these top ideas and i think we've definitely helped a lot of these top ideas get a little easier ride in the world okay so let me ask you another cost benefit okay so yes so what if i said wouldn't it be interested interesting in doing a meta cost benefit analysis on how much money you would need to raise and spend to effectively market your findings you know and to hire people who are really good at
Starting point is 01:15:13 doing such marketing so that you had the appropriate advertisements and so that you because you're you're this is not a criticism believe me but your approach is very academic and very objective and and that's all well and good and reliable and valid and all of those things but do you do you could your economists compute the utility in dollar value of establishing an extensive and appropriate marketing scheme because you think that there are, because I've been watching what's been happening with the Democrats in the U S and they've a pack that, that I know about has been making new ads for the Democrats, trying to move them towards the center.
Starting point is 01:15:57 And they've had a substantial amount of impact because the advertisements have been very professionally crafted and constructed. And so, well, I don't, I don't know what you think about that, but part of the reason I'm interviewing you today is because I want to put this up on YouTube and I want to get it out there in podcasts so that more people know about this. And so, all right.
Starting point is 01:16:20 Yeah, so the short answer, of course, is we have tried to do that because we're economists and we think that would be a good idea. So let me just tell you about something else that we've done. So we've been working a lot and we were just talking about the globe. So when you do prioritization on the planetary scale, it's academically very interesting. But unfortunately, the impact is mostly that people say, yeah, that's probably true somewhere else. So when we go and tell the Indians this, they'll say, yeah, that's probably true somewhere else. So when we go and tell the Indians this, they'll say, yeah, that's probably true for Mexico. And Mexico will say it's probably true for Argentina.
Starting point is 01:16:51 And so everybody just pushes it off to somebody else. The globe is never anyone's problem. Someone else needs to fix this. And so what we've increasingly done is to do this in nations. So we did this a couple years ago in Bangladesh and in the nation of course there's an overlap between who actually decides where to spend the money and the problems that we're analyzing so we did the exact same thing for just for Bangladesh so we did a prioritization list of all the things so we talked to everyone in Bangladesh we
Starting point is 01:17:22 got them to say what are the best things that you want to focus on what are the smartest new solutions we work with primus think tank the finance minister everybody else and talked about where can you actually spend money right again this is this is a menu that's not entirely politically correct certainly the politicians don't like all of this but what they you know the finance minister would go like no no no oh yes yes I like this yeah I. And so they did some of the things. So that solves the Tower of Babel problem to some degree. In some way, yes.
Starting point is 01:17:51 Yeah, there's too much distance between the local and the global. And so you're using the nation state as a psychological intermediary. Yeah, so there we actually estimate that every dollar spent on what we were doing does at least $10,000 worth of good, simply because we helped shift spending in Bangladesh gave, if you will, headwind to the poor ideas and tailwind to the good ones. And so we've done that in Haiti. We're now doing this in India together with Tata Trust. I just came back. That's why I'm a little jet lagged or a little bleary-eyed. I just came back from Ghana where we're going to do our next project.
Starting point is 01:18:41 So we want to bring this to Africa. Oh, great. Great. So you can do it globally and locally. Yes. And I think we'll have a lot more opportunity to actually get people's attention when you talk specifically to the nation states where you're actually going to be making these decisions. But obviously, if it's true in Ghana, it's probably also true in the neighboring states. You're going to get the overlap.
Starting point is 01:19:04 neighboring states, you're going to get the overlap. Exactly. So I think I would love to, you know, have a lot of extra sort of PR ability. But I think what we really need is just simply to be able to come up with all these great ideas. And I think we are reasonably successful. But the problem in some ways is we're advocates of all the boring stuff. You know, all the stuff that gets the attention are the ones that have the crying babies and cute animals. Yeah, but Todd, the thing is, it's not true. It's not what you're doing isn't boring.
Starting point is 01:19:32 It's absolutely exciting beyond belief. I mean, I don't believe that it is dry and I don't believe that it doesn't have a powerful narrative message. It's just that there are reasons that the narrative message is obscured. And I think putting your finger on the gap between the reasons that the narrative message is obscured. And I think putting your finger on the gap between the local and the global is a good one. That's smart, because
Starting point is 01:19:50 you see the same problem starting to emerge, for example, with the EU, where the overarching bureaucracy is so distant from the people on the ground that there's a disconnect in identification. And so to harness the latent power of the nation state and its patriotism and its economic, its rather local economic structure seems to me to be a really smart solution. But I really, I was thrilled when I came across your work. And I mean, on an emotional level, because I thought, well, wow, if we really wanted to do good, if that was the goal, and we wanted to do it intelligently and carefully and agnostically to some degree, and in a non-ideologically self-serving manner, which would be a lovely thing to manage if it proper publicity, that people could really get behind the idea that we wouldn't have to have tuberculosis in 10 years. You know, and that some of these things could really, you know, I've talked to people on my lecture tour about the things that we could do to make the world a better place. And there's no shortage of enthusiasm for that.
Starting point is 01:21:02 It's just that there's a fair bit of cynicism, but there's a lot more ignorance. It's like, well, we just don't know what to do. But your prescriptions say, well, here's 10 things. You could do one of them and one of them would work. So you've got a bit of a choice there. We wouldn't have to take our number one priority as your own, but you could take number five and you'd still do a lovely job, and it might be in accordance with your own motivations
Starting point is 01:21:25 Okay Can can can you get me? PDFs for example of the relevant whatever you think is relevant that would inform people in short order I will post in the description of the video Yeah, so that I can get access to that so whatever material you'd like to have disseminated as a consequence of this conversation just get that to me and all posted and any blurb you want me to put in the description then I'll also do that it with with whatever when do you need it for what as soon as as soon as you can get it because I'll put this out very soon like in the next day all
Starting point is 01:22:01 right okay is there anything else that you would like to say that we haven't covered? All right. First of all, I think it's wonderful the way that you're talking about this as sort of an outsider that it's actually exciting. And we probably make this mistake that we think of ourselves a little bit sort of technocrats and fiddlers in the margin kind of thing. And actually, you're right, and it is exciting. It is ridiculously exciting. bit sort of technocrats and and you know fiddlers and the margin uh kind of thing and actually you're right and it is exciting because it is ridiculously exciting actually if we could actually
Starting point is 01:22:30 spend our resources four times as well as what we're doing right now so instead of saying all the things that are politically correct making us all feel warm and fussy actually doing the things that perhaps are not top of our, not top of the agenda, but would just do an amazing amount of good. Why the hell are we not doing that? So, yes, thank you very much for getting me back in the groove and actually saying this. Oh, I really believe that.
Starting point is 01:22:54 And incredibly useful. Yeah. I think it's a mistake not to view what you're doing as an exciting adventure. I think it's a form of non-helpful humility. Yeah. In a sense. And I think, I'm Danish as background, and one of the things we're very, very good at
Starting point is 01:23:16 is self-effacement. And so, yes, you're probably right. Well, you're calling people to a great adventure here. You're saying, look, we have enough resources so that we could deflect a small fraction of them and do an unbelievable amount of good, and there would be no downside to that. There would be no downside to anyone.
Starting point is 01:23:37 There would be nothing but upside, even with some error, and there's going to be error. And so I think we'll find that people will respond to this video in a very, very positive way. And because I do believe that as people become more aware that we are becoming richer and that we do have more resources at our disposal, that that's genuinely true. And that with a bit of intelligent consideration, we could make things a lot more less dismal for a lot of people.
Starting point is 01:24:06 I think that they will start to view that as something that's part of a great national and global adventure. And because you're agnostic, and because you've done the legwork, then people can also, I think, get behind that without any real cynicism. They can say, look, our money spent here is not going to be wasted. We can be reasonably assured that if we're charitable in this direction, we're going to do something positive. And so anyways, like I said, I found it incredibly... Wonderful. And let me just say, again, we said a couple of times that something that I've done, I need to say, you know, I'm just the sock puppet that talks about all these things. This is the work of an incredible amount of really, really smart economists.
Starting point is 01:24:48 So one of the three of the world's top economists, you know, seven Nobel laureates. Those are the guys who've actually done the work and who are giving the credibility to all of this research. And that's why we can say with great amount of certainty, this is not just sort of a whim, but something that is probably the best we know now. It's probably, as you point out, not entirely true, but it's certainly better than anything else we have right now. Well, and that's actually the right comparison. It's like, it's not absolutely true. Yeah. But no one's got a better idea. Right. So we go with the best idea that we have. Exactly. Right. Right. All right. Well, look, it was a great pleasure talking to you.
Starting point is 01:25:28 And I'm hoping that, you know, a million people will watch this and that we'll get another million podcasts out of it. And that this will help disseminate what you're doing broadly. I think that would be lovely. You bet. Thank you. And it was great also meeting you. And I hope our paths will cross again soon. And, you know, we should, we should make a habit of this. Yes, we definitely should. Well, when you start to develop some more of the national indices, have you worked on any Western countries like Canada, the United States? So we, I wanted to do that. So we haven't done it in the US just simply because it's too dysfunctional in so many different ways. We've seen a couple of other people trying to do this without our involvement.
Starting point is 01:26:09 And one of the things we're really, really good at is that, you know, you get all these economists to do all this stuff. And the first draft of the paper is, this is really hard. We need 10 years, a lot of research money, and then we'll probably get you something. And, you know, we say, look, that's nowhere. You've got to, you know, give it your best shot, use the information that's out there now and give us a knowledge because politicians are going to make decisions next year. And, and what has happened in those two places. So they did one in Holland. They did, it might actually be Canada, but that was like 10 years ago. It ends up very much like a very interesting anthology of points that have no sort of consistency as what we're trying to achieve.
Starting point is 01:26:52 What would it cost to have something like this done for Canada? Do you have any sense? The short version is it costs about $2.5 million. It doesn't really scale well. So doing it for Ghana is the same thing as doing it for Canada how long would it take 18 months god that's such a good idea so two and a half million dollars 18 months yeah okay well I'm gonna wrap that around it maybe we can figure out how to raise the money we should we should try and do that that would be good I. That would be fantastic. I think there would be a lot of interest in Canada, and Canada would be a great way to also get sort of bridge point
Starting point is 01:27:30 into the U.S. without doing it in the U.S. Yeah, well, that would be good because we're flailing about politically, and it would be nice to. Yes. Okay, so that's fodder for another conversation. I've got a couple of other conversations that I'd like to have with you about policy development and also about marketing, but we'll save those for another time. Thank you.

There aren't comments yet for this episode. Click on any sentence in the transcript to leave a comment.