Tech Won't Save Us - How Neoliberalism Seized the Internet w/ Dan Greene
Episode Date: August 19, 2021Paris Marx is joined by Dan Greene to discuss how the Clinton administration reframed poverty through the lens of the internet and how that transformed the missions of key institutions like libraries ...and schools.Dan Greene is an assistant professor at University of Maryland’s College of Information Studies. He is the author of “The Promise of Access: Technology, Inequality, and the Political Economy of Hope.” Follow Dan on Twitter at @Green_DM.🚨 T-shirts are now available!Tech Won’t Save Us offers a critical perspective on tech, its worldview, and wider society with the goal of inspiring people to demand better tech and a better world. Follow the podcast (@techwontsaveus) and host Paris Marx (@parismarx) on Twitter, and support the show on Patreon.Find out more about Harbinger Media Network at harbingermedianetwork.com.Also mentioned in this episode:Anna Pacquin starred in a series of commercials for MCI about the internetBen Tarnoff wrote about the privatization of the internetDan wrote an article about the landlords of the internetSupport the show
Transcript
Discussion (0)
If you do not choose to log on and skill up and connect to this unlimited opportunity,
then you are going to be a drag on national economic productivity,
and you need to be contained by the carceral wing of the state.
Hello and welcome to Tech Won't Save Us. I'm your host, Paris Marks, and this week my guest is Dan
Green. Dan is an assistant professor at the University of Maryland's College of Information
Studies and the author of The Promise of Access, Technology, Inequality, and the Political Economy
of Hope. Now, I have to say, I know I speak to a lot of authors on the show,
but I really think that Dan's book is an essential read because it connects changes in the political
economy of the United States, and certainly these changes also happened around the world as well,
to the narratives that we have been sold about technology and how that changes the welfare state and the way that we understand poverty,
inequality, social reproduction, and so many important aspects of society. Dan goes back to
the Clinton administration and how that coincided with the growth of the internet. And Clinton was
not only the democratic president that embraced neoliberal policy by slashing the welfare state
and increasing the carceral state,
but he also oversaw the privatization of the internet. And he used the internet as kind of
the rhetorical tool to justify the changes that he was making to the welfare state and largely to the
orientation of government to say that no longer were these social programs necessary to protect,
you know, the poor, the
unemployed, people like that. But now the opportunity and their redemption would come
through technology. If only they had access to the internet and developed their digital skills,
then they would be able to access a global labor market. And we might say,
pull themselves up by their bootstraps. And what Dan describes is important because he also shows how those changes to the political
economy and to those narratives on the federal level not only were pushed out to other governments
around the world, but also kind of filtered down into city governments and how they changed
their governing practices to reorient around technology and to focus on those industries
and those workers, but also to alter the public institutions that were supposed to serve,
you know, everybody or specifically, you know, the poor and the marginalized in particular,
to change their kind of remit to serve these new technologically oriented ideas about how
you lift people out of poverty and about how you address these social
inequalities that I think we can see, you know, a couple decades on now that they haven't solved
these problems, but they have been very profitable for certain people. And they have really changed
the orientation of the state in a way that I think is very fair to say is not positive and is not
working for the people that it should be working for. So I was really happy to speak with Dan. I think you're really going to like this conversation.
I highly recommend picking up his book. Tech Won't Save Us is part of the Harbinger Media
Network, a group of left-wing podcasts that are made in Canada. And you can find out more about
that at harbingermedianetwork.com. If you liked this episode, make sure to leave a five-star
review on Apple Podcasts and make sure to share it on social media or with any friends or colleagues who you think would
enjoy it.
And if you feel like you learned from these conversations, consider becoming a monthly
supporter to support the work that I put into making each of these shows every single week.
And if you want to do that, you can join supporters like Rich Thomas and Isaac Meckler by going
to patreon.com slash techw't save us and becoming a supporter.
Thanks so much and enjoy this week's conversation. Dan, welcome to Tech Won't Save Us.
Thank you so much, Paris. Really happy to be here.
Yeah, I'm really excited to talk to you. And you know, obviously, I recently read your book,
The Promise of Access, which I think is really fantastic and is a book that people should be
picking up and reading and kind of understanding
the implications of these policy changes that have happened over decades that we're going to
be talking about today. And so the beginning of your book focuses on changes that took place in
the political economy of the United States during the Clinton administration, and I guess a little
bit before that as well. There are several aspects to this, but I wanted to focus on technology and
the internet first. Around that time, there was a narrative of the internet as a means of promoting that as well. There are several aspects to this, but I wanted to focus on technology and the
internet first. Around that time, there was a narrative of the internet as a means of promoting
freedom and democracy and things like this. And I think a lot of people still hold on to those
kind of libertarian-ish ideas when they think about the potential of the internet even today.
But at the same time, administration officials were talking about it through a neoliberal economic lens and through the lens of state power. So can you talk a little bit about that divide and how the Clinton administration saw and positioned the internet? is to make sure that we always understand technology policy as a poverty policy,
to never take considerations about the economy as something that is separate from technological development.
You know, technology is not an exogenous force that emerges from outside economics.
So the Clinton administration, you know, really importantly,
was the first time that the Democrats were back in the
White House since Jimmy Carter. And in the mid 70s, in the US, as with pretty much the rest of
the West, the wheels really fell off the economy. And, you know, there's a couple of events that
kind of signaled this from, you know, from leaving the gold standard to the kind of oil shock of OPEC to, I think for
me, the most important event is Ford and financial elites just refusing to fund New York City and
allowing the city to go bankrupt. But for whatever reason, the kind of economic compromise that was
built post-war that allowed for big firms with a steady growth of employment, a series of
promotions that you would get over time, mostly nationally bounded in this kind of
Keynesian value network where American companies were all feeding each other within the balance
of the country managed by this labor industry compromise. That wasn't working anymore. The
profits that had emerged from that had kind of dried up. Everything was shaken up by these series of crises, as well as a series
of revolts all over the world, not just anti-colonial revolts with folks in Africa and
Latin America reclaiming their land, but wide swaths of urban riots across France, the US, Canada, everywhere. And so a new kind of economic
regime emerged that was built much more around what David Harvey calls flexible accumulation,
where you see especially urban centers no longer kind of collaborating as different parts of the
same value chain in one country, but competing with each other within one country. We see broad assault
on unions, de-industrialization, and the replacement of those well-paying, highly centralized jobs
with service jobs, which are much more dispersed, much less well-paying. At the same time, we also
see, very importantly for economic policy, the boom in the US in particular, but also in the UK and
France and Canada, of the prison industry in a way that just had never been seen in human
civilization. And this is in part a response to political problems about what to do with these
civil rights and black power activists who have been challenging the state for so long, but also frankly about what to do with the surplus populations of folks who simply
do not have room for them in a de-industrialized economy. And for the Reagan Republicans who were
really at the kind of the peak of their power in the post-70s and the 80s, this was not a
particularly difficult question. You crushed
the unions, you destroyed the welfare state, and you said, if anyone is struggling, that's their
fault. We say that these especially racialized folks are surplus to requirements. We don't need
them. We'll lock them up. In order to regain the White House, the Clinton Democrats
needed to tell a different story and importantly, win a different political coalition over to their
side because the post-war coalition with Northern Industrial Unions was largely starting to collapse.
So what they did at the top, at the kind of donor level, was reach out especially to tech. In the 80s, through the Democratic Leadership Council, which Clinton and Gore were a big part of, this included people at MCI, at Apple, at Intel, who all became really important coalitions of this new Democratic Party that was nicknamed in the press the Atari Democrats.
Tech was important to them because it required some research and development, you know, more than what the Republicans were giving out.
It required a more global outlook and required some investment in education and control over intellectual property,
things that distinguish the Democrats
from Republicans. At the same time, they recruited new voters who replaced the multiracial,
especially unionized working class of the Great Society and New Deal eras. These new voters were
people like me. They were white, highly educated professionals, often working in office parks in the suburbs rather
than in cities. So places like Montgomery County, Maryland, Route 128 in Boston or Silicon Valley.
And these folks were all about formal equality and equality of opportunity. So, you know, pushing very hard
for like fair housing legislation, for example. But redistributive measures, especially those
that affected them, they were very harshly against. So two-way busing, for example,
that would integrate their schools with urban schools, really not popular with this crowd of
white professionals. They relied on education heavily and as a way to
kind of move up the chain in their particular professions, in tech especially, but also,
you know, things like accounting, consulting services. And so we're not unionized by and large.
And the Clinton Coalition brought these two sides together, these new voters and the new industrial base, by telling a different story about the economy than what the Republicans were telling.
And this focused on the Internet, because instead of looking at this problem of persistent poverty in a deindustrialized information economy and saying, well, you know, those people are surplus requirements. Clinton administration said, when we build out the internet and we ensure through market means,
but nonetheless ensure that everybody has access to the internet, that ensures that everyone has
access to the global labor market. And no one will ever be outside of the economy because we
are building this thing and commercializing this
thing, what had previously been a relatively limited research network that will connect
everyone to jobs that could be anywhere. And so you see commercials in the 90s from some of these
main members of the coalition, especially MCI, where it's this famous commercial of a young
Anna Paquin going to play Jean Grey. And she's standing in the middle of
the desert and she's saying, you know, distance doesn't matter anymore. There's no such thing
as time, race doesn't matter, gender doesn't matter, disability doesn't matter. We're all
online. We're all on the internet. This is a much more hopeful story about the economy than the kind
of like vengeful story that Republicans were telling. And it worked.
You know, Clinton really sold himself in 92 as a whole new kind of politician representing a whole
new generation of voters who were coming into their own and really kind of gave us the whole
vibe of the 90s, which was, you know, we can do anything. The old rules of the economy are gone
and we're connecting everything
together. So the internet for them, and Gore had been telling this story for more than a decade at
this point, was not just some kind of curiosity about R&D that they were bringing to market.
It was really integral to their entire message about what they were doing as economic managers
and why they were
superior to the Republicans. And it's what brought them back into power after many decades. It was
really central to their mission. Yeah, I think that's such a good description of what is going
on in the Clinton administration and, you know, before it, for these shifts to happen that result
in, you know, what you are describing in your book and what we're obviously going to dig into
a little bit further. Before we discuss the implications of that, I just want to stick on this
point just a little bit longer because, you know, obviously the policies of the Clinton administration
with regard to the internet are around the privatization of the internet and in particular,
the deregulation of telecommunications. And I feel like when we
discuss that today, it feels like there's kind of an inevitability around that, like naturally,
the internet had to be privatized, because this just had to happen. But in the book, you describe
how this was kind of a break from some previous ways of regulating telecommunications in the
United States, and you reference AT&T in particular. So can you talk a
little bit about that change in the government's orientation to telecommunications policy from
one that saw it kind of as a public service, I guess, to something that needed to be
distributed or provided through competitive markets?
The shift can seem quite subtle, in part because the administration, especially in
92, 93, it goes back and forth in the language.
But what you see over time is that the executive branch in particular and then Congress, the 1996 Telecommunications Act, moves telecommunications away from a goal of universal service.
You know, everyone gets what should be a relatively public good, to something like universal access.
We've seen this a lot with health care debates recently.
Access then becomes the key word for this coalition.
But it's really in the Internet that we start to see it first.
And access really just means an opportunity for competition, a place where you can, if
you fight hard enough, get the goods. So in the 20s and 30s, when it became clear that telephone companies were not connecting to each other because they were competing,
there was a lot of negotiations with the then emergent FTC and FCC to make sure that folks, especially in rural areas, were able to connect to this network. And the compromise that was eventually reached was that AT&T, Ma Bell, would basically receive a government-approved
monopoly. This is distinct from what happened in, say, Britain, where there was outright state
ownership of British Telephone. But nonetheless, there was no no trust busting until the 70s, really the 80s of AT&T, because they exchanged that privilege for universal service.
Getting everyone onto the telephone line in the name of being able to access important information, you know, call for emergency assistance, that sort of thing.
The Internet could have been that. I don't go into this in
the book as much, but I have a forthcoming article about how most internet infrastructure is operated
by commercial landlords about this transition. It's not beyond the realm of possibility that IBM,
who was really the biggest tech company of the 70s and 80s, could have been handed the whole
of what was then the NFSnet, a research
network that had taken over the civilian functions of ARPANET. But they made some kind of crucial
business errors in that stage of the early 90s when the internet was going to be deregulated.
And so it was really thrown open to be a free-for-all. The idea was that the maximum amount of opportunity for competition would serve
the maximum amount of people. This was then written into law, most notably in 1996 with the
reform of the 1934 Telecommunications Act. And you see, especially in Al Gore's speeches and
his correspondence, he's really leading this within the initiative, that this goal of getting everything to everyone is slowly, slowly chipped away.
And by 96, 97 is replaced with a goal of opening maximum competition, not just in the U.S., but globally.
So in the WTO, there are negotiations about extending internet access and funding internet build-out in
post-Soviet states, but it's contingent on privatizing their state-run telecommunications
infrastructure. The way this happens in the U.S. is that all kind of frictions that are introduced
into telecommunications ownership in the previous regulatory regime are killed off. So now you can
have cross- cross sector ownership,
like a cable company can own a satellite company who can own a phone company and that kind of
thing. And we kind of remove any kind of universal service requirements on the basis that the maximum
amount of competition will deliver people the maximum amount of internet and that the people
in kind of choosing the best options for how to
get online will then be able to find the best way to compete themselves in the global marketplace.
This is important to note, fails miserably. And it is this kind of regulatory regime that gives the
U.S. not only some of the slowest, but really the most expensive internet in the OECD. We saw this in a really bad way during the pandemic. So in my county, for example,
which is a relatively wealthy county outside of DC, we had one choice of vendor to provide
hotspots to the thousands and thousands of kids that did not have consumer internet at home,
because it's incredibly
expensive. Most Americans have one or maybe two choices for broadband. And in that kind of monopoly
position, you can raise the cost as much as you want. So a bunch of people were already without
internet. The pandemic hits, you have to do virtual learning. We have one vendor to choose
from to provide people hotspots. And then it turns out half of those hotspots don't work, and they have to be returned en masse. And this is directly a result of the kind of free market
ideology that the Clinton and Gore administration brought into internet regulation. And it was
really important throughout that that was a state project. This was not just kind of backing away,
but actively selling off government assets to Sprint, MCI, AT&T, and so forth,
and actively forcing other countries to follow the same so that American investors and American
kind of soft power political missions could succeed elsewhere. It was really an important
part of their national and global outlook. I want to get to the broader things that you discuss in the book, but I have one final
question and maybe you can give a quick answer and then we'll move on to the other points.
But, you know, obviously what you're describing there is how the government goes from this
position of wanting this universal service requirement to a policy that's focused on
prioritizing competition.
And I think in this moment, we're having this discussion about antitrust and the best way forward. And it seems like
the arguments are that part of the reason that people are not having sufficient access to the
internet and whatnot is because there's not enough competition and because AT&T, Verizon,
Comcast, these large telecommunications companies are controlling the market and have
consolidated too much in our monopolies.
And so I feel like what you're describing there gives us potentially a different way
to look at the problem.
So could you discuss that a little bit?
Yeah, I hear what you're saying.
And the antitrust issue is extremely complicated.
I won't pretend to be an expert, but I will say that we get to this realm of monopoly power through wide open competition.
And this is fairly easy to expect.
It's what you've seen in industry throughout the centuries.
This is a classic kind of Marxian conclusion that capital tends to concentrate. When you throw open the floodgates and allow everyone to compete for everything for a major resource that tends towards natural monopolies because it's a fiber in the ground, what's going to happen over time is the people with the greater amount of capital and the interest in specific regions are going to corner the market.
It's very hard to do a startup broadband supplier when someone like Comcast is already in the game.
So we get to the state of zero competition today and the disservice that does to consumers
by yesterday throwing open the doors to competition and allowing everyone to compete for everything,
specifically because we did not want to think about the internet as a public good.
As you were describing earlier, you said that the approach to technology policy
also really becomes poverty policy, right?
The way that the administration wants to address poverty is not through a welfare state and
social support programs and things like that, but through providing access to opportunities,
to skills, to things like that through its telecommunications policy.
And as a result of
that, you talk about an access doctrine that is kind of adopted by the Clinton administration and
by the US federal government, and I'm sure other governments as well, and how that results in a
digital divide, where technological tools and digital skills are supposed to allow people to
bridge this divide. So can you talk a bit about the
access doctrine and the implications of it? And then who falls on which side of this digital
divide and how they're supposed to cross it? Yeah, you know, it's always going to be really
important for me to say that even as I'm critiquing the way technology poverty policy
has been handled in the past, it's always important to say that these are very real
inequalities. There are absolutely have always been people who have not been able to get internet
access. And so to say that something like the digital divide was a constructed policy problem
built on specific terms and framed in specific ways does not mean that the problem itself
is false. We've just been talking about it the wrong way.
So I'm part of the problem here, as are many other researchers in my field. We have,
since the Clinton administration coined that term digital divide, probably through an administration employee named Lloyd Morissette, although there's some debate. In 95, 96,
there have been people like me since then trying to measure who has what internet where, what they're making do with it, all for the reason of, you know, first establishing these binaries between who's online and who's not.
And then, you know, somewhat complicating that with saying like, oh, OK, so who has what quality of connection, what kind of device, what they're succeeding from, and we keep doing this. But at the core has always remained this framing of the problem that the Clinton administration gave us, which is,
are you online or are you not? That's the thing that's going to determine your life chances in
the information economy, because that's what determines your access to the global labor market.
And that's based in this idea that I call the access doctrine, which decrees that the problem
of poverty can be solved through the provision of new technologies and new technical skills. You make sure that those people who are left out of
the information economy are able to catch up and compete. And that, as I was talking about,
is kind of there initially in 92, 93, when Clinton and Gore come into power, but it really comes into
the fore when they start talking
about this problem of the digital divide through these famous falling through the net reports
that begin in, I think, 1994. And, you know, they find that there, you know, and these are facts,
that Black folks in central cities and especially Native folks in rural areas are, unsurprisingly, much less likely to
have internet access than white folks in the suburbs. You know, it's very gated by class,
race, and geography. These reports grow in length over the next couple of years.
By the time the Bush administration comes around 2001, the word digital divide is gone,
but that same kind of hopeful framing remains.
And these, you know, reports assert over and over that a modem connection is the thing that is going to get you a good job and economic opportunity in the 21st century. There's this, you know,
always looking towards the 21st century in the 90s. And that's very real. But what a lot of
technology scholarship fails to do is kind of ask, what else is going on
at that moment?
And so it's really important to track that at the exact same time that the Clinton administration
is saying, hey, this is the solution to persistent poverty in the information economy.
You may be stuck in a dead-end job.
The plant may have left your town.
You may be struggling to get along on what meager welfare
still exists. But as long as you can get online, it'll be fine. And at the same time, the Democrats
are doing this. They are filling our prisons in an unprecedented way. That is always a poverty
policy. And they are, as Clinton said, destroying welfare or ending welfare as we know it. They're making it much more difficult to find respite from the labor market for parents,
for disabled people, for people who have just lost their jobs through no fault of their own.
Instead of having institutions that kind of protect you from the labor market in a moment
of weakness, provide some funds so you can get back on your feet.
The new poverty policies that started to roll out in the 70s, what we call workfare, says that everybody has to be in the labor market at all times.
You have to be constantly looking for a job, scaling up and training.
There is no outside.
There's no break.
This even filters down into education, where education starts increasingly to be more and more about workforce readiness. So the technology policy is not separate from this.
It is an integral part to this. And it is through that opportunity presented by the internet that
the Clinton administration is able to say, everyone has access to global labor markets.
If you do not choose to log on and skill up and connect to this unlimited opportunity, then you are going to be a drag on national economic productivity, and you need to be contained by the carceral wing of the state. hopeful story about anyone being able to do anything. And that is distinct from,
but always in collaboration with the right hand, the punitive message that if you step out of line,
you will find yourself in a cage. And both of those stories happen at the same time. And they're
very much present in everyone's life as they struggle with poverty, even if they seem to
sometimes be coming out of different politicians or different institutions.
Absolutely. You know, I think that's such an important framing of it, and especially that
divide, like the two different sides of the neoliberal policy and what is going on there
and what they expect of people, and also how that transforms, you know, the services and
the institutions that are available to people. And so in the book, you describe how this changes
things on multiple levels. And so I wanted to start with, you know, on the higher scale of the city itself, because you talk about how there's a real transformation in urban policy and on the focus of the government of Washington, in many other countries as well. So can you talk about that change to urban policy that comes as a result of this larger kind of neoliberal shift that you're describing?
Sure. So one of the kind of core operating principles of the book was that, you know,
people are smart, or at least they're not stupid. So if you're getting a message from the top down, from the federal government about the kind of new economic rules of the game, and if that message is not particularly borne out empirically, you know, it's often we see that, you know, at the minimum, the story about STEM gaps and skills gap is more complicated than first presented. You know, most STEM majors are not working in STEM post-degree. When we look at labor market returns
over the life course, it's often critical thinking skills that receive the most wage
payoffs compared to something like technical skills. We have seen really terrible failures in big
training programs, particularly in the Reagan administration that tried to take workers from
deindustrialized towns and push them into more clerical jobs. We've seen a lot of failures like
that. And we've also seen, frankly, stagnant wages over the last couple of years, even as
educational attainment has risen
across the population. So at minimum, the story that, you know, log on, skill up, you'll be fine
is more complicated than we've led to believe. Nonetheless, it remains the story that everyone
has repeated all the time. And I don't think it's just sheer repetition that gets into people's
heads. You have to be taught this lesson and you have to live this lesson. So what I do in the book is after moving from this kind of large-scale political economy
of the late 20th century, I then move into the city of Washington, D.C. to show how this message
gets built into our institutions that prepare people for the labor market or protect them from it. Places like libraries and schools.
I also spend time with startups who have become the kind of ideal organizational model that
everyone else tries to be.
The schools and libraries are trying to be like startups.
Why is that?
Why does that message of social mobility carry over from one domain to one very different
one?
In part, this is because because cities themselves are quite desperate.
After being cut out of the National Keynesian Value Network in the 70s, most famously symbolized by New York City going bankrupt, the center of Western capitalism, cities realized that they were in competition against each other.
And this in itself is not
terribly novel on my part there have been a lot of good especially geographers who have shown that
cities are often competing to bring in kind of limited industrial resources downtown and to
make their places make their cities sites of consumption and to encourage real estate
development above all costs since that's the kind of most consistent, sticky investment that they can get,
which then winds up driving out a lot of people who have lived there for years.
And we have seen over and over again that especially when we're hinging our future on tech,
on luring in these new, what someone like Richard Florida would call creative workers,
that often leads to a lot of changes in the city
that don't necessarily bear a lot of returns for everyone else's chances in the job market.
What I wanted to do in the book was show how that hinging your hopes on recruiting these talented,
largely white outsiders to save your city plays out for everybody else on the ground.
You know, what does it do to our schools? What does it do to our libraries and places like that? So cities have, uh, done things like offered
these like Mac, massive economic incentive packages, you know, we'll, we'll pay for your,
you know, first couple of years of rent or even like employee salaries or whatever,
um, will lower your taxes if you move into specific areas, areas, all that sort of stuff. And in part, because tech is
relatively not, or at least small startups are relatively not capital intensive, they don't need
a lot of heavy machinery or anything like that. The way the city actually changes to recruit these
people is largely through what we would call gentrification. You know, you replace existing
housing stock with luxury condominiums. You replace older businesses serving working class
black and brown folks with newer, higher priced, especially national chains that people can
recognize as they move from city to city. And there's a way that, you know, especially people
like Richard Florida, but really cities in general can kind of trick themselves into believing that
this is an investment in productive capacity. You know, why by encouraging this kind of exclusive
real estate development, we are building up our city as a site for industry because, you know,
all these techies just work in their laptop at home or in the coffee shop anyway.
When, in fact, this is just the same regular degular kind of gentrification that we've seen for decades.
The other thing that cities will do is then try to reform the rest of the what we call a kind of social reproduction, the places outside the labor market that prepare people for it, they reform those parts of the city to kind of transform existing members of the city to look more like these new
white outsiders and to make the city itself look more welcoming. In part, this also happens because
those new white outsiders are now important members of the city who start to serve on school
boards or make grants or even run for office or
at least donate to people's political campaigns. So places like schools begin to compete on startup
models. That's really what charter schools are, is to fund a bunch of different experiments,
much in the same way that venture capital works, on the hopes that one or two of them will bear returns measured in test scores. And we often
find that business language is incredibly important into the way these places are managed,
funded, and taught, that technical skills are the focus of the most popular and far-reaching charter chains. We see in libraries that are desperate for funding and legitimacy
start to reach out for tech sector models for how they do business
and start focusing more on digital skills training and technology provision
over and above the services that people are actually trying to receive when they go there. Things like I need healthcare signups or even just I need a place to rest because there's
no other public space in the city. So the city starts to make lots of offers to outside businesses
because the city is desperate and competing with other places for industrial capital. But the city
also starts to remake itself,
especially those institutions that prepare people for the job market in the image of the tech sector.
Yeah. And I think everything you talked about there is important, but the transformation of
the institutions is also incredibly important. Like the institutions of what you call social
reproduction, right? Which is a term that I think many people, you know, who are familiar with left wing scholarship will be familiar with.
But you talk about how these institutions have to bootstrap to remain relevant, right, and to try to emulate these kind of startup models for, you know, I guess a public institution,
but that they struggle to do that because their kind of goal or what they're trying to do is very
different from a startup or some sort of private business. And I think one of the pieces that stood
out to me was how naturally these institutions have been starved of funding to a certain degree
because of the cuts that have come with the neoliberal period and have thus had to seek out
funding from other areas or to show that they are
embracing this kind of model so that they can get funding. And, you know, naturally one of the
institutions or one of the places that these groups can get funding is from places like the
Gates Foundation, which have a particular idea of what these institutions should be doing.
So can you talk about how these kind of funding gaps and how this need to kind of bootstrap and show a different way of doing things that aligns with the tech model affects how these institutions work? we keep pursuing this particular strategy of economic development if the results aren't there?
And, you know, why do we keep teaching people to log on and skill up, learn to code or else?
And I locate the answer in these sites of social reproduction, the places that, you know, don't make products, but make people. Some of them are public owned by the state. Some of them
are private. Some of them are in the home, the unwaged work of mostly mothers, but parents generally.
And it is in those spaces, these institutions of social reproduction that I found the answer.
Because it's not that, you know, when I spent, you know, three years hanging out in D.C.
public libraries that I would talk to librarians there and they'd say, oh, yeah, we're effectively
the largest homeless shelter in the city.
We're going to solve that if we teach everyone C++. No one actually believed that. What they did believe was that the library itself,
and this was very true in DC in the early 2000s, was at risk of total collapse or privatization.
School system in a similar state. And they knew that they were short on legitimacy. Politicians
didn't believe in them. They were short on funding because of relentless budget cuts, especially during recessions, you know, clinics, community centers, stuff like that.
All those other social problems end up coming on to schools and libraries and places like them.
You know, it's very common to hear teachers talking about like, you know, I'm a teacher, but I'm also a nurse, social worker, peer mediator, counselor, you know, all these other things, because there's no other place to receive those services. So these institutions that face poverty head on then find that they have to tell
a particular story about poverty. They have to engage in this kind of myth-making in order to
keep themselves alive. So when they start saying, yes, we are going to teach people to code,
that is the thing that wins them legitimacy.
Politicians start saying like, hey, you know, you got something here. This sounds interesting and new. They win funding, like you say, from often from private foundations that are filling the
gap left by tax cuts. These foundations more than ever have a lot of tech sector influence,
especially the Gates Foundation, you know, effectively runs education policy in the US
just as much as the Department of Education does. And they clarify their mission. So the example I
often give is the library who, frankly, doesn't know what to do with folks who are sleeping there.
It's a really difficult question because there's nowhere else to rest during the day in our
swampy 100-degree summer. There is no right to shelter
for the homeless in that period. Most homeless shelters close during the day. There is really
no real public space to speak of. You know, you got to pay to hang out at Starbucks or something.
So a lot of people feel that, yeah, you know, let someone sleep. It's fine.
But they're not using the resources. They might be blocking access to a computer. Maybe the donors or at least the people who show up at those community meetings don't like it because they're, you know, kind of busy bodies that show up to meetings.
But it's a confusing thing.
And the Access Doctrine provides clarity to that.
It says, no, people are here to log on and skill up.
So if you're not making use of these resources, you've got to go.
And while that might tug at the heartstrings for, you know, individual service providers, that clarity is
really, really helpful. So those are the kind of things that convince people to retell the story.
And that's ultimately how the story continues to be reproduced. But like you said, ultimately,
schools, libraries can't be startups, because they have, you know, obviously a different level
of funding, but also a fundamentally different mission, have, you know, obviously a different level of funding,
but also a fundamentally different mission. They, you know, ultimately must accept,
usually, I mean, it's different with charter schools, whoever walks in the door,
they can't pivot in the middle of a year and suddenly become a, you know, a business-to-business operation instead of a business-to-consumer operation in the way that startups do. They
don't have that level of flexibility. And they're constrained by other stakeholders in a very
different way. You know, they have to answer to politicians, to school boards, to funders,
to students and teachers, to unions in a way that startups simply don't. So they often find
themselves running up against, you know, problems that they're unable to solve with these solutions that they've kind of bought off the shelf.
You know, it's in schools, for example, like we've known for years that like the majority of something like test scores is accounted for by non-school factors.
You know, you give us like a kid's zip code and the neighborhood that they live in, the school that they attend.
We can do a pretty good job of estimating their SAT
scores because they're very much a function of household income. And there's just not much that
a school can do about that. You know, a school can provide a safe space for a kid. It can do
wonderful things. I'm a teacher because I believe in schools. But at the end of the day, there's
also really important things about like, you know, how much food is in a kid's belly, whether they
have internet at home, whether their parents are able to kid's belly, whether they have internet at home, whether their
parents are able to read at them, whether they have to work after school or not, whether they
have activities in their neighborhood that the school can't control. So the school ends up
putting all of its pressure on itself to kind of save these kids. The library puts all its pressure
on itself in order to end homelessness in the book, you know, in part because the library that I'm
talking about was desperately overdue for a major renovation and had to save itself. But they keep
failing. You know, they can't live up to this mission that they've set before them, to this
model of startup to success. And so they just start again. You know, bootstrapping is a never
ending cycle because when you fail, there's always another skills gap to worry about after
that. There's always another programming language, another job challenge, something that you did
wrong last time you could improve on next time. Ultimately, because the thing that you're
responding to isn't that skills gap, it's the fact that your institution might die and you need to do
something to save it. Yeah, I think that's such an important point to make,
right, about how these institutions change and how it's difficult for them to provide the services
to achieve the mission that they're supposed to be carrying out when there are these other
expectations that come from something like the access doctrine and this idea that technology
is what is going to solve these issues when it's these other, you know, aspects of the social
safety net or whatnot that are necessary, but that are not being provided by these larger kind of government structures.
And I think what you're discussing there also shows how we think about people differently,
right? And how we are supposed to act as individuals, how we're supposed to learn,
how we're supposed to operate in society, in the labor market, et cetera, et cetera.
And as I was reading your book, I was thinking about something I read in Fred Turner's
from counterculture to cyberculture, where he describes how the global business network,
this consulting agency that was started by Stuart Brand, who, you know, also started the whole earth
catalog, you know, tried to promote the idea that the way of working that was established in the
consulting firm was something that should be rolled out to the rest of the economy and other workers, you know, something that is natural when you think
about kind of the post-industrial society, but naturally doesn't work for everybody, right? It
might work for these really high paid consultants, but you can't have everybody like living in this
insecure, precarious way. So can you talk about how this kind of shift in the access doctrine
then changes the idea of how we are all supposed to live and work?
Yeah, that's a really powerful point, Paris.
And ultimately, the way I approach that question is through hegemony.
You know, there's this Marxist scholar, Antonio Gramsci, an activist who's important in the Italian Communist Party and famously imprisoned by Mussolini, who is really important to my thinking in this book.
And, you know, he's most famous really as a political theorist for explaining how
coalitions come together to run a given society on a certain set of rules,
making sure that everyone in a given society is pointed towards the same social ends,
even when that path ultimately doesn't benefit them.
Because what has happened is that a certain dominant class has universalized their interests
such that everyone else is persuaded by hook or by crook to follow that model.
And when, you know, when Stuart Brand or whoever is saying that this is the way that we need
to do things, that's a fine invitation. But what we see
in the Clinton administration or in municipal policy later in the ethnographic portions of the
book, when I'm interviewing people like that, is that that is not entirely a process that people
go along with willingly. You have to change how our schools are funded, how kids are tested, how labor market is presented to them,
what they read, what they work on, where they're allowed to be, how they sit.
All of these things have to change in order for people to realize that there's one way to be
successful in this economy. And that is through this kind of nonstop training, this embrace of economic uncertainty that can work for certain people in certain places and startups, but simply does not apply to other kinds of work or other kinds of institutions just because they're different. Exactly what I was describing when we were talking about the Clintons putting together a new coalition to kind of ensure that there had continued success in the information economy.
It's taking these tech sector donors and financial sector donors, kind of international minded people at the very top, the kind of people giving money, even becoming politicians themselves, if we look at our governor of Colorado, or at the bottom,
you know, new voters and activists in the party, who are these kind of tech sector or office park
people. And their way of working, or the way they think the world should work, then becomes
everybody else's way of doing it, by remaking these institutions that prepare us for the labor
market or help us when we're out of it. Schools,
libraries, that sort of thing. And at no point are people being tricked or fooled by some kind
of propaganda. But if you're, you know, say some of the homeless folks they hung out with for a
while in DC public libraries, they know that to receive help and to be recognized as worthy of
service, you have to present yourself as in search of a new skill,
constantly looking for a job. You can't just be expressing an interest in some kind of literature
or a need of a space for rest. You need to present yourself as someone who wants to work and needs to
work constantly, adding new skills. They have to mimic the kind of 18-hour workday of the startup that was down the street.
It's so sad and frustrating to hear. But obviously, what you're describing there and what you have described in these other ways that these policies and this kind of economic
orientation, the shift in the political economy has altered institutions and ways of governance
on other levels, really suggests, what you're describing here with
these changes through the Clinton period, through the access doctrine, the bootstrapping in these
institutions is how capital reshapes society and the people within it to serve its goals,
and in particular, its modes of accumulation, right? And that's something that, you know,
I've been recognizing recently, as I've been reading more and more about these histories
and these shifts in political economy over time.
And I think for me, it also shows the difficulty of materially changing things for the better
when the overarching structure is sending things in a particular direction and in a
direction that I think we would consider is negative and not having the kind of social
benefit that we would want to see.
And so what are the implications of that when we think about how to challenge it?
So I think the basic core insight of really any kind of work of Marxist political economy is that,
you know, it didn't have been thus, if the world was built to be a specific way,
with a specific series of steps, I mean, this doesn't even have to be Marxism, it's just history, really, then it can be rebuilt or deconstructed to be something different. You
know, it wasn't inevitable. If we can show that specific people made specific decisions along the
way, we can suggest that other decisions could be made. Even if everyone is, you know, ultimately
responding to this like massive structural global condition of depressed profits in the 1970s.
There were other steps that we could have made. In the book specifically, I close on an optimistic
note, and I am hopeful. I'm more hopeful now than I was 10 years ago. I'm frankly more hopeful now,
especially after seeing arguably the largest uprising in American history last year than I was when I finished the book.
And that's because the core action of the book focuses on this universalization of class interest,
that these particular class of professionals, largely but not entirely white, became the center of liberal politics in the 1990s.
And in the book, we see that happening both in the hyper-profitable sectors that are,
you know, the center of so much media attention and startups, but also in those places that
are helping people try to catch up to that success with schools and libraries.
So we have, you know, software developers on the one hand, but then teachers and librarians on the other. And often these people come from the same class,
you know, good middle-class families in the suburbs who, you know, went to decent schools.
They all, you know, room together in college. They might, you know, live in the same apartment
building in DC. They might brunch at the same place or whatever. And, you know, even as one
side is paid much less than the other, they're similar people
with similar ideas about how the world works.
I consider myself part of that class.
You know, that's part of my job in education, right?
Is I'm supposed to help people do what I did.
You know, even as I know there's a ton of exogenous factors to my success that are about,
you know, just sheer luck or birth or race or geography or whatever.
You know, I went to school,
I learned some skills, I got a good job. Now I'm supposed to teach my students to do the same thing.
But importantly, in institutions of social reproduction, those professionals are confronted
with the people that they're managing. You know, there isn't a lot of contact at Uber, for example,
between developers and drivers. You know, that's changing with some political action. But for the most part, the professionals in tech who are designing systems that reproduce
capital relations in the workplace, tools of management, are not interacting with the people
that ultimately they're displacing or automating or controlling or whatever. It's not their job.
But teachers see their students every day. Librarians see their patrons every day. They know that when they're trying to reproduce a certain mindset,
that they're going to be confronted with those consequences immediately. And what that means is
that there is a potential to see the kind of immediate stakes of the game and a solidarity,
because ultimately they're partners in these crumbling institutions. The teachers realize
that their students are suffering just as much as them, and they need help to get through this. they're partners in these crumbling institutions. You know, the teachers realize that like their
students are suffering just as much as them and they need help to get through this. So since 2012,
at least, we've seen in the U.S. a real turn in what is often called social justice unionism or
community unionism, where professionals in these spaces, especially schools, but historically
libraries here have had a serious political history in the U.S. and contemporarily, there's a lot of great
political action in libraries and Canada specifically. We've seen this turn where
workers in these spaces try to unite with the people they serve. This is in part a defensive
maneuver because the first thing that happens when teachers go on strike is that politicians say,
oh, you're hurting the kids. So you need to build alliances with kids and their parents
in order to prevent that from happening. It's also in part to fight for common goals.
Everyone wants a better workplace with air conditioning that actually works.
And it's in part to build power that is persistent for a longer amount of time than just
whatever contract fight you need to fight for a raise. If you have roots not just in your workplace,
but in your neighborhood with the parents who are sending kids to your school and who
seek so many other services from the school for food, translation, especially this past year for all sorts of other resources you might need at
home, then you're going to have a pretty big bond with that school. So in Chicago, in the teachers
union there, we saw the kind of radicals that took over CTU and the core caucus start to organize
not just their members, but students and their families. They started to work with bus drivers security guards and other
kinds of public employees so that when when they went on strike the entire city was behind them
and they won and they kept winning that model worked they beat Rahm Emanuel repeatedly
and it's that kind of action that I think offers hope you know and I tell a couple stories in the
book about kind of early roots of that action failing in DC because that solidarity hadn't been built
because the antagonism in the central library branch that I look at between patrons and
librarians was pretty intense over the years. So that when librarians tried to provide services
as the library closed and prevent patrons from being pushed out to the edge of the city,
there just wasn't a lot of trust there. But the terrain is there, the opportunities are there, and we see them going
off all over the country. These professionals start to organize with the people that they serve
in a kind of a common vision for an institution that acts as a public good, rather than an engine
of competition that separates everyone from each other and acts in a vertical fashion.
So instead of this kind of paternal relationship where a librarian or a teacher tells this working class kid how to be in order to survive,
they start looking at them as partners in the present, as people that are allied in the search for a just, equitable institution that treats them all like human beings.
And they start to organize together.
In teacher organizing, we often say that, like, my working conditions, my students'
learning conditions.
In Los Angeles, teachers there have been heavily involved in the Black Lives Matter movement.
And so when they were fighting for their recent contract, they also fought for an end to random
searches of kids at their schools and discriminatory disciplinary policies.
And this wasn't just in like liberal strongholds like L.A. or Chicago.
In 2018, these teacher strikes were in West Virginia and Arizona and Oklahoma.
They were all over the place.
So the ground is there change the whole economy.
Schools and libraries aren't going to be outsourced.
That stuff needs to stick around forever.
And those are real community bastions that people love and care about. And it's a real space of strength that can offer a real substantial kind of hope for
the future, rather than this false hope that if we simply skill up, we'll be able to out-compete
everyone else who is doing the exact same thing at the exact same time. I love that. And I think
that's an essential point, right? Those key public institutions are important places that people can
organize around and find solidarity. Dan, I have really
appreciated this conversation. And I think your book makes such an important contribution
to illustrating how these changes to political economy, to policies affect so much more in
society and shape things to serve capital in these ways. So I really appreciate you taking
the time to talk to me today. Thank you so much, Paris. It was a pleasure. Dan Green is an assistant professor at the
University of Maryland and the author of The Promise of Access, Technology, Inequality,
and the Political Economy of Hope. You can follow Dan on Twitter at at green underscore DM. You can
follow me at at Paris Marks, and you can follow the show at at Tech Won't Save Us. Tech Won't
Save Us is part of the Harbinger Media Network, and you can find out more about that at harbingermedianetwork.com.
If you want to support the work that I put into making the show every week,
you can go to patreon.com slash tech won't save us and become a supporter. Thanks for listening. Thank you.