The Knowledge Project with Shane Parrish - #53 Howard Marks: Luck, Risk and Avoiding Losers
Episode Date: March 5, 2019Billionaire investor, author and co-founder of Oaktree Capital Howard Marks discusses risk assessment, how to think different than the crowd, and the three mighty dares that separate the successful fr...om the also-rans. Go Premium: Members get early access, ad-free episodes, hand-edited transcripts, searchable transcripts, member-only episodes, and more. Sign up at: https://fs.blog/membership/ Every Sunday our newsletter shares timeless insights and ideas that you can use at work and home. Add it to your inbox: https://fs.blog/newsletter/ Follow Shane on Twitter at: https://twitter.com/ShaneAParrish Learn more about your ad choices. Visit megaphone.fm/adchoices
Transcript
Discussion (0)
Hello and welcome.
I'm Shane Parrish, and this is The Knowledge Project,
podcast exploring the ideas, methods, and mental models that help you learn from the best
of what other people have already figured out.
Learn more and stay up to date at fs.blog slash podcast.
On the show today is Howard Marks, the co-chairman and co-founder of Oak Tree Capital Management.
He's authored two books, the most important thing, uncommon sense for the thoughtful investor,
and mastering the market cycle, getting the odds on your side.
The most famous investor ever, Warren Buffett, said of Howard,
when I see memos from Howard Marks in my mail, they're the first thing I open and read.
I always learn something.
And you're going to learn something, too, in this conversation.
While it's wide-ranging, covering how to think better, how to position yourself to get the odds on your side,
a little bit of investing in market cycles, but there's so much more to this.
It's time to listen and learn.
Can you take me back to the financial crisis a little bit and explain or at least illuminate for me how it is that we had this series of events unfold and you were you were able to have this aha moment and take.
advantage of it. What happened?
Crises are complicated and it's hard to give a linear description of their formation.
But in general, as we'll discuss later about the book, cycles are all about excesses in
their correction. And so the financial crisis grew out of excesses, which were then
corrected painfully. And the excesses were basically, you know, a willing suspension of this
belief, an excess of credulousness, and, you know, there was too much faith in mortgages and
mortgage-backed securities, and they were invested too heavily and too riskily by essential
financial institutions, which then became precarious.
And, you know, you had Bear Stearns and Merrill Lynch and Wachovia Bank and Washington Mutual
all disappear or require rescues.
And it culminated in the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers on September 15, 2008.
And now, you know, I said in one of my memos that in the real world, things fluctuate
between pretty good and not so hot.
But in the investment world, investors go from, you know, perfect to no chance of survival
in their psychology.
And so after the Lehman Bankruptcy, you know, people were talking about the end of the world, the end of the financial world, the meltdown of the financial cycle.
And the truth is that it appeared to be, if you ever saw the Jane Fonda movie China Syndrome, it looked like a vicious circle that would absolutely go nonstop and, you know, go through the center of the earth to be.
Beijing. And so the question was, do we invest or not? First, does the financial system meltdown?
Now, this is something that could not be analyzed or proved or disproved or anything. It was
not subject to intellectualization. It wasn't knowable. No, that's right. And so I took the
stands that it's hard to predict the meltdown of the financial system, that if you think
it's going to melt down, it's impossible to know what to do, that anything you might do
to prepare for the meltdown of the financial system would be a disaster under any other
circumstances, and most of the time the financial world doesn't end. That was the extent of my
analysis. And so I said, well, we can't plan on the end of the financial crisis.
two. Do we invest or not? If we invest and the financial world melts down, it doesn't matter
what we did. But if we don't invest and it doesn't melt down, then we abdicated our
responsibility. We were hired by our clients to invest. If there's a crisis that does not
culminate in the meltdown of financialism, then that was the best of all possible environments
to invest. And we didn't invest, as the English say, full stop. In other words, we had
choice. We had to invest. And so we started to invest and sometimes we thought we were going
too fast and sometimes we thought we were going too slow. But for the last 15 weeks of 08,
we invested an average of 650 million a week for a total of 10 billion. And the financial world
did not melt down. Isn't Wall Street full of people with the same sort of logic who identified
an opportunity? But what was the difference? Because one of the things that I'm so impressed
with is not only did you recognize it, but you actually took action on it. So a lot of people
seem to purport to understand what was happening, but they had an inability to act. Where did
that come from? Our emotions conspire at every turn to make us do the wrong thing. Maybe it comes
from the fight or flight mentality, which is so deeply ingrained in us. But as the economy does
well, and companies report good earnings, and the media reports turn positive, and the stock
prices rise, and people become more enthusiastic. It becomes very hard not to buy. In other words,
emotion causes people to buy more the higher prices go. Now, in most walks of life, people
buy more when the prices go down during sales. On Wall Street, they buy more when the prices rise.
and then let's say eventually things reach atop which is not maintained now the economy turns down
and the company's reporting decreasing earnings or maybe losses and the media put out scare stories
and the prices cascade down now people get depressed and when they approach the bottom they say
I just don't want to lose anymore get me out I'm terrified I don't know what to do I feel so terrible
about all the things I've owned and so stupid.
So in other words, emotion tends to get people to sell at the bottom, just as they bought at the top.
And this applies to professional managers as well.
Well, it only applies to people who have feelings.
You know, I quote in the book Richard Feynman, the physicist, who said that physics would be much harder if electrons had feelings.
Markets, by the way, there's no such thing as a market.
There's only a bunch of people who trade.
Talk to me about that. Why do we conceptualize it as a market then?
Because, you know, if you think of a market, most people flashed to a photo of the New York Stock Exchange, a building, just as if most people, well, in my day, if you talked about a stock, people would think about a stock certificate. But the building is not the market, and the stock certificate is not ownership of a company. It's these things are only signifiers.
But a market consists of a group of people who implement their views on value by transacting.
And so it's all there is as people, and people have feelings.
And so the emotions tend to get people to buy, buy, buy at the top until the last potential
buyer has bought and spent all his money, at which point the top is reached and the second derivative
goes negative, and sell, sell, sell at the bottom until the last person.
who's going to panic out, does so. And so, number one, it's very difficult to take these
contrarian actions in the face of sentiment. And I don't know, I'm sure we're not the only
person who did it. I don't know who else did it. Most people don't report their transactions,
and most investors don't write the memos like I do. So I don't know who was thinking what at the
time. I think we were exceptional. Yeah, I mean, there's thousands of people who,
who sort of manage money and very few, I think, have been able to act on that in the moment.
And that's really interesting to me for a couple of reasons, right?
One, you sort of overcame your evolutionary, emotional programming.
But two, I'm curious about how you test for that beforehand.
How do you test how people will respond in a crisis before you actually have a crisis?
We had lived through some lesser crises, you know.
know, my partner Bruce Karsh and I, who Bruce runs our distressed debt funds, which is where most of
this activity is centered. You know, we lived through a severe market downturn in 1991 and another
one in a 102. So we had rehearsed. I, at the time of the financial crisis, I'd been working 40 years
already. I've seen some of these things. And so you, hopefully, we learn from experience, you know.
hopefully at some point, our intellect aided by dispassionate observation of our experience
can overcome our emotion. That's number one. Number two, maybe Bruce and I are more unemotional
than most. Number three, our very activity of investing in distressed debt is inherently
contrarian. You know, people say, well, how can you invest in companies that are bankrupt or
destined to become so? So, you know, and at that point, we've been doing that for 20 years.
if we succumbed to the normal view of distressed companies, we wouldn't be able to conduct that
activity. And finally, I think we are unusually supportive of each other. And, you know,
we've been doing, we've been partners for 31 years. Neither of us has ever said to the other one,
boy, that worked out badly. You did a stupid thing, you know. This is not an activity where you can
bat a thousand. And hopefully it's better than baseball where the greatest bat 30 or 40%. Hopefully we
can do 60 or 70 percent. But we can't bat 100%. And if you have a partner or an organization,
which second guesses your mistakes, then you become mistake averse. And we don't do that.
So, and we, in this case, we work together and supported each other. And we have a lot of
respect for each other. And that permits it. And I think that that sets the tone for the organization
because it is not a blame the finger-pointing organization. I think all these things help.
Can we geek out on this for a second? So like you have this thing where you're necessarily
valuable. You're not going to about a thousand or a hundred percent. And so there's times when
you're going to be wrong. How do you distinguish between being wrong and it just being a
of probabilities or being lucky and right.
And how do you learn from those in a culture that, and I like the fact that you don't sort
of assign blame, but how do you learn from that?
How do you surface that?
I think for many of the things we're discussing today, I can't give you a recipe.
Oh, of course.
You know, I mean, I think that we have an above average ability to detect risk and make
investments that have upside potential, what with the risks under control. I think we have this
ability you described to understand the difference between bad decisions and bad outcomes and
this hesitation to point fingers when we get a bad outcome. And I think that all of these things
start with a mindset. And rather than have a recipe or a roadmap, I think we have a mindset to
do these things. You know, one of the reasons we're so good at controlling risk is that we put
risk control first. We have a motto, if we avoid the losers, the winners take care of themselves.
And that was fine when we invested in high-yield bonds, where a high-yield bond, if you buy it at par,
the best you're going to get is interest plus par back. But there are lots of worse outcomes.
So we've concluded that if we secure against the worse outcomes, we'll get our interest and our
money back. So those securities have no upside aspiration. Then we moved into areas like distressed
debt, real estate infrastructure and power investments and private equity and so forth, where we do
have aspirations, where we're trying to make a lot of money. And we have a record in distress debt
of, I think, 16 or 17% a year for 30 years without using any leverage. Clearly, we have high
aspirations. Securing against losses is not enough. You actually have to find some winners,
but we have retained our motto. Clearly, if we avoid the losers, winners take care of themselves,
is not enough in an aspirational strategy like the stressed debt. We have retained it because it
signifies front of mind consciousness of risk control. Well, look, I started Wharton 55 years ago
last month. And the first thing I remember learning there is that you can't tell the quality of a
decision from the outcome. And that pervades my thinking. And I think it's very important. And then I play
backgammon with my good friend Bruce Newberg out in Los Angeles. And you know, you need some crazy
number to win. And you get it. That doesn't mean you're a good player. It means you were lucky.
And he always says that improbable things happen all the time and probable things fail to happen all
the time because the world is an uncertain place. If the things that were probable happened all
the time, in theory, there would be no risk. So we understand that we're going to make decisions
that aren't going to work and that the people we work with are going to make decisions that
aren't going to work, especially in the short run. They may work in the long run, but in the short
run, a good decision that didn't work can look an awful lot like a bad decision. But we have a
Mentality, which recognizes that, doesn't criticize people every time something goes wrong.
And, you know, we try to hire people who are not terribly emotional, egotistical, don't have a lot of hubris or testosterone.
And I think we try to have a mellow organization, which is, you know, very helpful in all these regards.
How do you test for that when you're hiring?
Just talking.
We don't run psychological tests or anything like.
But, you know, the first step towards solving a personnel or managerial problem is acknowledging
it.
So if you put a high priority on hiring the kind of person I have described, you have a better
chance of doing so, and we do.
I want to talk a little bit about cycles, which is what the book is about.
What are sort of examples of the most important cycles, and maybe we can do a deep dive
on the economic cycle, including the role of governments and central banks?
Well, it's funny you should say that because literally in the car coming here this morning
I was reading an article about timely article about the Fed, the need for Fed independence
and, you know, the Paul Volcker's great example of Fed independence and some examples of
feds that were not independent and failed.
Volker was the 80s.
Was the bulwark.
Just for people listening, can we give context to?
Well, in the 70s, we had runaway inflation in America, not like some African nation that had
a thousand percent a year, but we had 16 percent a year, I think it was, at the peak, and makes
it very hard to live, and securities collapse, and people have trouble keeping up with the cost
of living, and, you know, commodity prices get out of hand and so forth. And, of course, short-term rates
go up, which makes it hard to finance business and so forth. And everybody, you know, so the main
point about inflation is I think it's very mysterious. It's hard to say what starts it. It's hard to
say what stops it. Deflation, they have in some countries like Japan, it's hard to know what
starts or stops that. But obviously has a great impact on the economic cycle. And if you think
about the economy, U.S. economy grows, let's say, for rounding purposes, on average, 2%
a year. Why doesn't it grow 2% every year? Why sometimes 3 and sometimes 1, and sometimes
4 and sometimes negative? And I think that, you know, and unfortunately, the book is already
printed, and as you keep thinking about things and talking about them, your thoughts come into
better focus. So I would summarize it as saying that cycles have.
happen because people, not electrons, but people commit excesses to the upside, usually
out of enthusiasm, which then have to be corrected, and those corrections offer shoot to
the downside.
And that's the investor psychology.
Yes, exactly.
But it's the way the world works.
I mean, you take a company, we're in a recession, we're coming out of the recession,
and the management sits around the table, says we're going to be in a recovery, there's
going to be an increase in demand for our product. We want to get our share of the
demand, of the increase in demand. So we're going to build another factory, hire a thousand
workers, and build inventories. And all the companies in the industry do the same thing at
the same time. They all build factories, workforce, and inventories. That makes that an above
average year in the economy. Yeah. But then it turns out that collectively, they've built
much more factories and workforce and inventories than they need to take advantage of the gain
in demand in the recovery. And so they falter and the next year they don't build those things
and that makes that a below average year. I'm oversimplifying. Success is sowing the seeds of
its own destruction and that's another description of cyclical behavior. You know, it's interesting
to look at the U.S. economy. We're in the 10th year of a recovery. There's never been a recovery
of more than 10 years. So somebody who was an absolutist, you know, would say, well, then that means
that in, let's see, October, in nine months, the economy will stop going up. But of course,
there are no rules. And Twain said history does not repeat. And that's one of the ways in which
it doesn't repeat. These limitations are not hard and fast. This has also been the slowest recovery
since World War II.
And that's a good thing because that slow recovery, you see, one of the things that your
listeners should note is that in the financial or investment world where psychology is so
important and there are no absolute laws of nature at work, everything has two sides,
a good side, every development has a positive side and a negative side.
So the negative side of a slow recovery is that it's been slow.
the positive side is that it hasn't been marked by excesses. And if it has been marked by
excesses, then that means we don't have to have a correction to the downside, which is called
the recession anytime soon. So my guess is that this recovery will set a record for the longest
recovery in history because of the slowness and the absence of excesses. Now, in December,
the government passed a tax bill, which is highly stimulative.
because it cut the rates on corporations, not from 35 to 25, as most people had thought, generous,
but to 21.
And I would say that was overstimulative.
That tax bill will cut government revenues.
And most people think that that will lead to an increase in the deficit and in the national debt.
And it was, I would say it was overstimulative.
And my reaction at the time was, it still is, that doctors do not give adrenaline to healthy
patients. They give it to people who are having heart attacks. And we had a healthy economy.
That tax bill stimulated it. I would say over stimulated it unnecessarily. That will lead to
excesses, which will then have to be corrected. One of the ways we correct excesses in the
in the economy, preferably and hopefully less painfully, is through interest rate increases.
Because interest rate cuts are stimulative, increases are restrictive, and that will tend to
diminish the growth in the economy and hopefully prevent hyperinflation from taking hold.
So it's this kabuki dance to try to get that balance right.
And given that the tax bill was overstimulative, it will probably need higher interest.
rates than we otherwise would have, which will increase the possibility of lapsing into recession.
What's the government's role in the economic cycle?
The most direct is the actions of the Fed, and of course that's, in theory, that is independent
of government. But the Fed's central banks, which is what the Fed is, have for more than
a hundred years, basically been charged with controlling inflation. That is the number one job.
Keep the economy on an even keel so that it grows but not overheats causing inflation that
has to be rained in. In the more recent years, maybe 30, 40 years ago, the Fed was given another
responsibility, which is to support employment. Now, this is problematic because employment growth,
comes from economic growth, that's good. Too much economic growth, you get rising inflation. That's
bad. So they have two goals which are in opposition. And of course, that requires particularly
adroit management, which is by definition not so easy. And so, well, you know, sometimes the Fed is
too positive and you might get inflation or you might get, you know, I think that in some
ways the Fed contributed to the global financial crisis by being too accommodating. And, you know,
I think that Greenspan was so accommodating of the need of the economy to grow that, and kind of a
cheerleader, that he permitted the perception of something called the Greenspan put,
which is, anytime the economy looks like it might have a problem, the Fed will squirt in some
extra liquidity and cut rates, maybe, and that'll prevent the problem. So, i.e., there will never be
a problem. There will never be a slowdown. We don't have to worry about negative scenarios in doing
our planning. It'll always be okay, and that's dangerous, because if you eschew planning for
tough times, then your planning will be overly biased to the upside. And when the tough times come,
you're by definition not ready. Outside of the Fed, does the government play a wealth sort of
redistribution role? And how does that affect the economics? Like, I mean, we talked about the tax
cuts. Yeah. Well, of course, what people have to understand, maybe more than anything else,
is that governments don't make anything. All they do is redistribute.
All they do, you know, we have these millions of people working in Washington and all these senators
income. All they really do is they collect money and they spend it. They don't make it. They
don't have businesses which add value to our society. And so they make spending decisions and
collecting decisions. These are policies. Taxation. How much from the rich, how much from the poor,
how much from interest in dividends and how much from salaries.
And I've seen fluctuations in these things over the years.
But this is policy.
And then, you know, there are people who say that we have too much inequality and it should be fixed.
And there are people who say that the way to fix it is to get the rich to pay their share.
Now, I kind of bridle at that because it seems like a religious or philosophical statement.
It's not an economic statement.
There is no such thing as a fair share, and the only question is, who determines the fair share?
And my feeling is that the fair share is, by definition, when people say we're trying
to get the rich to pay their fair share, what they mean is we're trying to get them to pay more
than they pay now.
But how do you define a fair share?
Right now, people we might call the rich, or certainly the people in the upper part
of the income distribution, pay almost all the taxes.
So, you know, this question of fair share is problematic.
And then how do you distribute it?
You know, do you have welfare?
Do you have guaranteed universal income?
Do you have federally employed, guaranteed jobs, et cetera?
These are all redistribution questions.
And A, no easy answers.
And B, this is the main grist for politics.
are the differences of opinion on this subject, one of the very most important.
I want to come back to get your opinion on universal basic income in a second, but before
we sort of move on out of the economic cycle and the role of the government and the Fed and
investor psychology, when I think about that intuitively, I think about it as a nation, state,
but we also operate in this global economy where tax rates on businesses make it more
competitive for one country over another, where interest rates make investment in one country
and more prone than another. How do you think about that not only from the individual like
United States point of view, but then in the global sort of world that we live in?
First of all, let me say, Oak Tree is not what we call a macro investor. We do not invest
in broad themes of economic growth and movements and currencies and interest rates.
We are a micro-investor.
We invest in individual companies in situations and properties and so forth.
So I don't do this for living.
But I am out in the world and I do tend to have opinions on these things.
Back in May of 2016, I wrote a memo entitled Economic Reality.
And basically what I said, you know, our presidential campaign was going on at the time.
In campaigns, people always say things which do not comport with economic reality, you know.
In real life, if we have $10, we can't have two $10 hamburgers.
In politics, during campaigns, people say, I'll give you two $10 hamburgers, and it won't cost you anything.
And you don't have to choose between having two hamburgers and putting money in the bank or what have you.
And so, yes, economic realities to find the playing field and the rules.
So, for example, a nation cannot or shouldn't set its tax rates without reference to the tax
rates in the rest of the world.
One of the reasons we had to reduce our corporate tax rate is that our corporate tax rate
was high relative to the rest of the world, which gave businesses an incentive to establish
themselves elsewhere or move elsewhere to escape U.S. taxation. And they can do that. And in
economic reality, I talked about the fact that there was an article in the paper that the highest
tax, the biggest taxpayer in New Jersey moved away. I happen to know them. And people can move
if they want to. So, you know, down in Venezuela, they were running out, oh, a toilet paper was
becoming too expensive. So they control the price of toilet paper. And the price of toilet paper
couldn't go up. Guess what? You can't make people produce toilet paper. And they said, if we can't
raise our price to reflect the cost of making toilet paper, we're going to cut production. And now
it's even harder to get toilet paper. So this is economic reality. And if we say, well, we're going
to balance the budget by taxing the rich, raise tax rates on the rich, they move away. We saw this
in France. You know, I think it was Hollande, put a 75% tax rate on the wealthiest Frenchman.
They move away. This is economic reality in action. And presumably the rich are also the,
I mean, the most, it's easy for them to move away too. Exactly. That's right. That's right.
If you, yeah, I mean, look, in the new tax bill, they changed the tax deductibility of state and local
taxes and mortgage interest. And as to the state and local taxes, there are seven states in
America that have no state and local tax or state taxes. So you have a lot of incentive to move
from New York and California and New Jersey and Connecticut and Illinois to Florida, Texas,
and Nevada. And as you say, the working man may not be able to do that, but the person who
lives off his investment portfolio can do that in a heartbeat. And since I moved to California,
to New York five and a half years ago, I run into a lot of people. I say, how do you like living
in New York? Oh, I don't live in New York. I live in Florida. I only come to New York
181 days a year. Because that's the maximum permissible before you. Yeah. Right. And government
can't undo by fiat in the long run the things that economic reality requires. It's very
interesting, I think. But the same thing is playing out with countries, not just people.
And that's impacting where companies locate.
It's impacting where tax dollars go.
How do you think about that?
And even if you come up with a global agreement,
the cost of defection is a huge advantage
and probably very little sort of like disadvantage
if you're caught.
Well, and when you say if you're caught, nations will cheat.
Right.
You know, every time we have commercial treaties,
you get a little cheating around the edges and the cheaters get away with it for a while.
And, you know, this will always be the case.
How would you do things differently if you were sort of in charge of not only the sort of like
U.S. government and the economic cycle, but broadly, like how would you conceptualize,
how the world would best be maximized?
How do we unleash that potential across the globe?
Well, that raises a real interesting question, Shane. And you use the term maximize. And the greatest
contributor to global economic maximization is globalization. You know, I mean, let's say you have two
countries, mine and yours. And we're really good at raising sheep and you're really good at turning
leather into shoes. And so we raise the sheep. And when they're ready,
we send the hides to you, and you make the leather into shoes.
And this system produces 100 pairs of shoes a year.
And then some politician erects a wall.
No more trade in sheep, leather, or shoes.
Now, I'm good at raising sheep, but I have to try to learn how to make shoes.
And you are good at making shoes, but you have to learn how to raise sheep to get the leather.
And so in this new world, I can only produce 40 pairs of shoes, and you can only produce 40 pairs of shoes because we're not doing what we're good at. We have to do what we're bad at also. And in this new system, there's only 80 pairs of shoes in the old system, which was humming. There were 100. And that's called the benefits of specialization. And globalization is in opposition to
negating the benefits of specialization. And so, you know, the administration in this country
says we run a big $800 billion deficit, trade deficit with China, whatever the number is.
And that shows that, A, they're winning and we're losing, and B, they must be cheating. They're
taking advantage of us. And we're going to stop that. And this is a total ignoring
of economic reality. When you go to the barbershop, you get a haircut, you pay the guy 20 bucks. You
run a trade deficit with him. He's taking in 20 bucks from you. You're not taking in anything from
him. So in those terms, he's killing you trade-wise. But you're not unhappy. He gets the money. You
get the haircut. So when we run a trade deficit with China, most people weren't unhappy. Why?
So let's say the number is $800 billion, I don't remember.
If we run an $800 billion trade deficit with China, what does it mean?
It means we bought $800 million more of Chinese goods than they bought of American goods.
That's what a trade deficit is.
Why do we have a trade deficit?
Because we would rather buy their goods, which are some combination of better and cheaper,
and they're not very motivated to buy our goods because, number one, we don't manufacture that much.
And what we manufacture, by their standards, isn't better and cheaper.
So we get cheap goods.
And if we say we're going to stop the trade deficit, what it means is we're not going to have access to cheap goods.
Now, I saw the president on TV the other day, and he said, you just don't understand.
We've taken billions.
We've collected billions from the Chinese in tariffs.
Well, not economic reality.
Chinese don't pay tariffs.
Tariffs are paid by consumers of goods.
We have collected billions in tariffs from U.S. consumers of Chinese goods.
Paying higher prices.
Paying higher prices.
I don't know if they're happy.
You know, everything in Walmart just went up.
Is that good or bad?
Now, presumably, there would be two reasons for the imposition of these tariffs, well, maybe three.
One is, I would say some machismo.
Another is that China's cheating in some ways on trade, and we want to punish them until they stop.
And everybody tells me there's some truth in that.
And then the third thing is that we want to protect U.S. jobs.
And it clearly can be a combination of all three.
And we've lost, I think the estimate is we've lost three million jobs to China over the last
let's say 15 years. So let's say the tariffs reverse that process. We get those three million
jobs back. That's a good thing. And to do so, we impose tariffs, which require 100 million
Americans to pay higher prices for the things they buy every day. That's a bad thing. Is it justified?
Is that good for America or bad? And those are the kind of decisions that Washington makes
in their judgment.
It's really interesting to hear you say that
because that's not the type of conversation
we hear around that.
We hear the sound bites, the bullet points, right?
The jobs are good.
Okay.
So May 2016, economic reality.
August 2016, I wrote a memo called political reality.
I said political reality is totally different
from economic reality.
The politician says, I can get you everything
you want without any sacrifice.
So I'm going to cost you anything.
Vote for me.
And you can have it all.
You don't have to choose.
Economics, if you think about it, is really the science of choices.
And clearly it's not true, but people can say anything on the stump they want.
And you can't sue a politician for making a promise that he didn't come through with.
And they do.
But we have to make choices.
How is the reasonable sort of person to make sure?
choices in a world where they have to elect officials, but the tone and the quality of that
conversation is just, I don't know, to me it seems absurd on a lot of levels.
Well, the tone and quality is ridiculous. I mean, it has lapsed into just vilification
of the other side. Tribalization of opinions. A great article this week by David Brooks in the
New York Times on the differences in thinking between the extreme left and the extreme right,
you know, and the difference, you know, the difference of opinions on things like, you know,
the level of racism in this country and that kind of thing. They just think totally differently.
And as a consequence, they can't communicate at all. And part of the reason is that I have a position
which is different from yours, and I tell you the good things about my position, and you tell me
the good things about your position. I never admit to the bad things about my position or
vice versa, and we don't have a respectful, honest discussion. We just try to fight for our side.
Part of it is, you know, what percent of, let's say, Americans understand economics?
I mean, economics is really convoluted.
And what percentage of people, all right, now we have tariffs.
There have been tariffs in the headlines for the last six, nine months.
How many people understand what a tariff is?
How many people understand that the Chinese don't pay the tariffs, Americans pay the tariffs?
And pretty soon, when the events surrounding my new book died out, I'm going to write my next memo,
and I'm Bobby going to touch on tariffs and all the things that,
Nobody understands about tariffs, and there are so many.
And you put a tariff on imports of steel and aluminum to protect American manufacturers
of steel aluminum.
But that means that American manufacturers of motorcycles who use foreign steel are at a disadvantage
relative to American manufacturers of motorcycles who use domestic steel.
You want to disadvantage some American country companies relative to others, and they're at a
disadvantage relative to foreign motorcycle manufacturers.
Do you want to disadvantage American companies relative to foreign?
It's not easy.
And why?
Because a tariff is an attempt to regulate the economy by rule in contravention of economic
reality.
You have somebody who can produce deal cheaper than you.
You put a tariff on to fix that, but it has all these ramifications, all of which are, shall we say, unnatural.
What would your, what would do you think personally is a better option?
Oh, so let me, there's one thing I have to interject that I left out.
So globalization leads to global maximization.
And the world economic product is maximized by globalization.
It's a winning strategy.
However, at the individual level, there are winners and losers.
Right.
Because, you know, in my example, all the people who used to make shoes in America were forced out of business because they didn't do it well.
And all the people who used to raise sheep in Canada are forced out of business because they didn't do it well.
And, you know, then you get into the question of whether the American advantage in raising sheep,
cheap is the result of government subsidies, et cetera, and then you pass a rule against subsidies,
et cetera. So, you know, I have to confess, Shane. I've never thought I had the answers
on these things. But I think that I could help participate in an honest and open discussion
of the issues. I think that's where it starts, right? Yes. And hopefully,
thoughtful, honest, objective, not highly partisan people, could come to a decision which
maximizes the welfare for the most people, but still, of course, there will be losers.
And then one of the differences between the two political parties in this country is,
is what do you do for the losers, you know?
We don't want anybody to lose, right?
I mean, that's part of the issue.
Well, we don't know.
some don't want anybody to lose you know I had a stepmother who thought everybody should get a vacation
in Las Vegas and a color TV or I would rather say we don't want anybody to any of the losers and
of course it's hard to use that word but losers in this process to suffer right you have to have
winners and losers. And I used to say to my stepmother, well, why don't we pass a law which says that
when people go to the casino in Vegas, they can't lose. There can be people who win and people
who break even, but nobody can lose. Well, I want to go to that casino. Right, me too. But it would
only, it would only be open for an hour. And then they'd figure out that they should close it.
And so you, again, you're trying to contravene. You have to have losers and winners in the free
enterprise system. If you don't want winners and losers, switch to the socialist system or
communist system in which they, in which they were only losers. I think personally, I mean,
for me, I think of it as people should have equal opportunity, but outcomes should not necessarily
be equal. And part of that is work ethic. Part of it is luck. There's a whole bunch of factors
that go into that. But ideally, I mean, I would love to live in a world where everybody had equal
sort of opportunity to flourish. Well, of course, you can't produce that.
because we are born with advantages of birth, of where we're born, of which schools we go to.
And, you know, I wrote a memo in January of 2014, which happens to be the memo that got the most
response, and it was called Getting Lucky.
And it was on the importance of luck, the role of luck.
And, you know, I talked in there about a dozen ways in which I feel I've been lucky.
I think I've been the luckiest person on the planet.
And I think it was to that that people were responding.
But, you know, I get into arguments with people.
And a lot of people say, oh, you know, well, what started the article is, I read a piece, quoted some Silicon Valley guy who says, success is never accidental.
You make your own luck.
And I don't agree.
I think luck is a real thing and it's important and it's inherently unfair, but that's life.
And so I get into these arguments with people and I say to them, okay, how about your IQ?
What did you do to deserve, develop or nurture your IQ?
You were born with a brain that works better than others.
That's luck.
And it's totally, it's not merit.
We convinced ourselves that, you know, we did something to foster that or improve it.
Well, I don't.
I mean, I was just born lucky, you know, and.
Buffett talks about the ovarian lottery.
I think that's a great concept that people really misunderstand.
They really do.
And let's say we get over the hurdle of agreeing that there is such a thing as luck.
And then we say that some people get it and some people don't.
And that's inherently unfair.
I think the next step is some people might say, I mean, it's conceivable to imagine somebody saying,
you know, I'm kind of down because I realized that my success came from luck and that
depresses me. But me, I think my success comes from luck and I'm ecstatic about it.
It's great, yeah. Because I feel I've always been lucky and why shouldn't I keep you being
lucky? Now, it's, and it's great to go through life with a positive attitude. And I think that
my good fortune in the past contributes to my positive attitude with regards to the future.
Now, that's probably illogical because lucky events in theory may be independent, but I think that I
will continue to benefit from my good luck. And, you know, the philosopher Cicero said something
beautiful. He said, the thankful heart is not only the greatest of all the virtues, but it is the
parent of all the other virtues. And I think, but what that means is that people who are lucky
should thank their luck, acknowledge it, and revel in it. I think it will also,
make them want to share the fruits of their luck with others.
That's a great segue into, so we talked about sort of unequal outcomes, but equal opportunity.
And when people don't have equal outcomes, one of the things that's come up is sort of universal basic income.
How do you think about that?
On the one hand, we don't want anybody to starve.
And we feel terrible about children who grow up in the unlucky circumstances and don't have exposure
to a good education and good nutrition and things that help them stay out of trouble
and develop a positive self-image.
And, you know, so that tends to drive on, shall we say, the left,
which is more concerned about the unequal outcomes and wants to fix them.
And I do not want to see the unfortunate among us suffer, live in extreme poverty.
And we've been doing quite well as a world in terms of fighting extreme poverty.
Do you view that nationally or globally when you say that comment?
Yeah.
Well, I think globally, you know, I was reading the book, Factfulness.
And it says that if you ask people what percentage of the world's population lives in extreme poverty,
most people would say a much higher number than is true.
Yeah. And I think that the number has been coming down. And the other thing is that I think that
people who live in what we describe as poverty, poverty today might be even better than most
people lived 200 years ago in terms of quality of life. But the problem is that we get a lot more
from our work than just our income and um because we feel like we're part of something well we feel a part
of something we get self-satisfaction we understand that we are able to do things we understand that we are
producing our own subsistence and we have colleagues you know we have a team effort we work together
with others on things and we accomplish them and you know there's so many benefits uh to work now the
truth is that the work I do and the work that people who do manual labor is not too much the
same, they may not love their work the way I love mine. One of John Kenneth Galbraith's last
books was he had an essay, maybe I would call it a rant, on the subject that, you know,
it's ridiculous that we use the same word to describe what a CEO does and what a road worker does.
You know, we say work, but clearly it's not very much in common.
But the truth is we get great benefits from work.
And universal basic income will not give those benefits.
It'll only feed the physical needs.
And, you know, so number one,
there was a big debate under Clinton about welfare and we reduced welfare because we thought
it gave bad incentives and it got people into bad habits and I think that's probably right
and universal basic income probably would do so.
I think that the universal basic income idea would go some way to keeping people from starving
to death which of course is important and children from being malnourished and malclothed
but it's not going to solve the problems of society.
And I don't know what is because I think that automation and the elimination of jobs
is one of the biggest problems we face in the long run and may exacerbate the need for
universal basic income or some progressive candidates now say guaranteed jobs from the government.
Talk to me about that sort of change with the, we'll call it technology.
and automation and AI and machine learning, how is that similar to other sort of, I want to use
the term like revolutions, but, and how is it dissimilar in your mind?
Yeah, I was, I was invited down to Tulane University.
They had a speakers program, and I think I was the first speaker at the business school
after the school was repaired following the terrible earthquake, hurricane they had down
there. And my hosts took me to dinner in Basin Street. And one of the things they told me
about was that New Orleans and the environs were thriving metropolis, economically thriving
metropolis in the days of agriculture. And of course, millions of people had jobs in agriculture.
And then agriculture became automated.
Those people lost their jobs in agriculture, and they moved to the upper Midwest to make cars and appliances.
And then they thrived, and people who worked in those industries who really maybe only had a strong back as their main asset did very well.
They had unions, they had strong unions.
The unions got great packages for them, and they did very well.
But then, of course, we globalized, and the manufacturing of cars and appliances moved overseas.
And since then, the unions have been in decline on the private sector side.
And now, what do you do if your only asset is a strong back?
I think President Obama on the stump said, well, we'll give them all laptops.
but not everybody can work a laptop enough to make a living.
And number two, in the information age, by definition, we need fewer people to produce GDP
than we did in the days of physical labor.
So it's a big problem.
Now, I was talking about the fact that China law took three million jobs from us.
I believe I'm accurate in saying that from 79 roughly to today, our manufacturing output in this country has doubled.
We don't think ourselves as being great manufacturers, but I think that we sell, measured in dollar terms,
which is, of course, the only way you can measure it, we sell twice as much today as we did 40 years ago.
And 40 years ago, I think we had about 19 million people working in manufacturing today.
12. So we have twice the outcome, output, with a third less workers, which means that the output
per worker has tripled. If the output per worker hadn't tripled, we'd have three times as many
workers. Right. Making the same amount of goods. Rather than 12, we'd have 36 million employed in
manufacturing. And so I wrote in, I think this was in economic reality. I wrote, if you want to
solve the problem, all you had to do is ban gains in productivity. But of course, that would be
silly and that would not be economic reality because somebody else would implement those gains
in productivity and eat our lunch. But the point is that we have probably lost 24 million
jobs to increasing productivity over the last 40 years compared to 3 million that went to China.
And it shows you the scope of the problem and the location of the problem. The problem is not
China. And, you know, knocking on the door is self-driving cars. And I think driving is the single
largest job category in the- I think that's right. And self-driving cars are going to be a big issue.
By the way, not only will they put, I mean, this is a utopian world that may be decades away,
but not only will they put all the taxi drivers, bus drivers, truck drivers, limo drivers out of business,
but think about the body shops because computer self-driven cars won't have any accidents
and the paint shops and the steel because they'll require less sort of right and the insurance
companies because you know you won't need insurance adjusters since there won't be any accidents
to inspect and then take it take it further down you know people won't want cars they'll do
with cars, what they do today with bicycles in New York.
You'll have a supply of cars.
You'll pick one up, drive it for a few hours, and drop it off, and somebody else will pick one.
So, you know, the average car, take a guess.
The average car in America, and I can't even, it's hard to think about all of America,
but how many hours a day is it used?
Yeah.
Two?
Yeah.
Well, that means, that means if we could increase the utilization of cars by having them
drive themselves, you know, you punch into your number where you need a car, it comes
to you, picked you up and takes you where you want to go, that we would only need one-twelfth the
number of cars. So think of all the people who lose their jobs in the auto industry and because
the auto industry contracts the steel industry and so forth. So, you know, where do those people
get jobs? It's hard to imagine. And yet we've faced this before, haven't we?
That's what people say to me. We faced this before, and that's why I went through the recitation
about people moving from agriculture to appliances and cars.
So the optimist says we've faced it before, and jobs don't go away, they just move around.
I don't have a good enough imagination to picture that world.
You're not optimistic on this.
I'm not optimistic.
And I try to be an optimist, but I try not to be a stupid optimist.
And what do they do?
If they don't drive cars, do insurance adjusting, fix cars, build cars, or make steel, what do they do?
So what's different about this one that causes you?
to be less optimistic.
It's the march of technology.
Is it the sheer volume of number of people displaced?
Well, it's the volume of people displaced and the fact that their jobs will not be done
by other people.
They'll be done by machines.
Who are doing them at an equivalent or better level than they were?
And much faster.
Reduce variability.
Yeah, you know, there's a joke, Shane, about the factory of the future.
You know about that one?
it'll have one man and one dog the dog's job will it keep the man from touching the machinery
and the man's job will be to feed the dog it sounds like the amazon go store i was in
in seattle last week where you just literally there's there's one person uh standing at the front
explaining how you download the app and swipe in and then you just go in and grab stuff and walk
out right and so there's one there used to be 10 people working in the bookstore
What are the other nine doing? Are there new jobs to, you see, when the, when people stopped
working in agriculture, there were the new industries of autos and appliances. Will there be
new labor-intensive industries to give jobs to the nine people who lost them in the bookstore?
What do you think that'll do for wages of blue-collar sort of jobs?
Well, you're seeing it already. In this, in this rising,
income inequality, the people who have capital or technical education skills are doing very well,
and the people who don't have those things are doing very badly. Don't you think that'll just
continue? The people who can develop the personalist bookstore or the robot will be in great
demand and the people who can create artificial intelligence will be in great demand and very
valuable and they'll all live in a small community just south of San Francisco. And the people
who can't do any of that stuff and get displaced from their jobs will be, we'll do very poorly.
And this is dystopian. And I hate myself for thinking that way, but I'm not optimistic about a solution.
And by the way, let's be generous and say that there's a possibility that government could solve this or help.
Not this government, this government, by which I mean the current state of affairs in Washington,
I'm not talking about a person or a political party, this government can't solve any problems because they can't agree on anything.
I think if there were a solution to this problem, it would be a big solution.
There would be a national solution and revolutionary and would require bipartisan support for something pretty radical, hard to believe.
And that seems to be getting increasingly difficult, not only here, but around the globe from, I mean, what I'm exposed to you.
Sure.
The tribalization of views exacerbated by the polarization of the media.
But is this part of a natural cycle?
Like, we become more extreme and then we come back together, or am I?
Am I just trying to be optimistic about it?
Oh, I'd like to hope so.
I'd like to hope so.
I'd like to hope that eventually you have experiences which are so bad that you say,
you know, we can't run that way anymore.
But things probably have to get pretty bad for it to happen.
You know, my greatest interest at the present time in the political world is in bipartisanship.
And I'm supporting an organization which exists, no labels, to support.
bipartisanship. Yeah. And we're hopeful, but most people say it's quixotic. I want to go back to the days
where, you know, both sides of the aisle used to go to social engagements with each other and talk and try
to find reasonable solutions instead of avoid each other and polarize everything. I want to come back
a little bit just to investing. One thing we didn't talk about that I really want to get your thoughts on
is what is risk? Like how do you define risk, not only in investing, but risk in general?
Well, risk in general, what is it? It's the probability of bad outcomes. In academic investment
theory, they say it's volatility. The volatility of prices, the volatility of returns. Now,
I believe, and that was a view basically developed in the new theory of investing, and I would
say basically at the University of Chicago in the early 60s. And I was very, I talked before about
my luck. One of the things I was lucky about is I went to Chicago in 67, and I was among the first classes
taught the new theory. And anytime you're at the front of the line, it's an advantage. And that put me
at the front of the line. But in the new theory, there are all these processes in equations which
concern risk and return and how you optimize risk, return relative to risk. And you have a formula,
you need to plug something in for risk. And they plugged in volatility. Now, I don't think
volatility is risk. I think risk is the probability of bad outcomes. But
Why did they use volatility? Because it exists. You can say how volatile was this asset or asset class in the past and we'll extrapolate to the future. And if you don't use volatility, there's no other number available because there is no number that you can observe historically for the probability of bad outcomes at various points in time. But I think that risk is the probability of bad outcomes. Now,
my thinking, fortunately, is always evolving. And I wrote my last memo on risk in 2015. It was called
Risk revisited again. And I talked about risk as being the probability of loss. And for most
investors, loss is the bad outcome they're concerned with. But the truth is we really should talk
if it's the probability of bad outcomes, there are really at least two risks that we should think
about. One is the probability of loss, and the other is the probability of gains that you miss out on.
Now, given the way people are wired, we care more about losses than we do about gains foregone.
And an investor who works for somebody else is more likely to get fired for losing money
than for missing out on opportunities.
Right. But the point is, I go through this.
only to say that they have both bad outcomes, and we should think of risk in terms of both.
Does that imply we know the range of outcomes that are possible?
I mean, what about uncertainty?
So in this memo, which anybody who's interested in risk, I strongly recommend they read it.
By the way, all the memos that I've been talking about, all the memos I've written in the last 29
years are available at www.Oakreecapital.com under the heading of insights.
hopefully there's some insight there. And they're all free and anybody can go on and read them
and download them and sign up for a service that will notify you the next time one comes
out and you can download that. And I hope people will. We'll include a link on the page.
Thank you very much. That's great. But there was a great economic philosopher, investment
philosopher, is how I describe them, named Peter Bernstein. He died about 10 years ago.
And I quote him extensively.
The reason that risk revisited was revisited again, and thus the title, Risk Revisited
again, is because I found a memo from Bernstein from 07 on my desk in 2015.
My desk can be messy.
And I incorporated a lot of what he wrote.
And he said, risk exists because the future is a range of possibilities.
There was a professor at the London Business School, Elroy Dimson, who said,
risk means more things can happen than will happen, which is a brilliant summation.
But risk exists because the future is uncertain.
There's a range of possibilities, Bernstein says.
Sometimes we don't even know what's in the range in answer to your question.
And sometimes we think we do.
Sometimes we're right about that.
Sometimes we're wrong.
but I think clearly the upshyed is that in order to manage risk, you have to have a view
of what the probability distribution of future events looks like, what's most likely,
what's least likely, and what's in between, and you can only make your decisions on the
basis of that probability distribution. Now, the first key is that you have to do it right.
if you start from the wrong probability distribution, you're unlikely to find success.
But number two, it's essential, and this returns to a theme you and I discussed an hour ago,
it's essential to bear in mind that even if you know the probability distribution exactly right,
you still don't know what's going to happen.
Right.
The difference between probability and outcome, as Bruce Newberg says.
It's like a roulette table at a casino.
Well, I use the example of, I use the example of a craps table.
Sure.
And Bruce and I play backgammon all the time.
Backgammon is, is run by dice.
So you throw two dice, and there are 36 possible outcomes.
Each die has six sides, six times six, 36.
And we know a hundred percent certainty what's possible.
You're going to get one of those outcomes.
We're going to get one of those outcomes.
And we know that of the 36 outcomes,
six of them are seven, six one, one, six, five, two, two, five, four, three, three, four.
So there are six combinations that give seven.
It is the most likely outcome.
Right.
There are five combinations that give six and five that give eight, and from thereon, the probabilities
recede.
So we know which numbers are most likely, somewhat likely, unlikely.
We still don't know what's going to happen.
It's only what the tendency would be on a given role, and probably if you do enough
experiments in the long run, that's what you'll get.
If you roll a thousand, dice a thousand times, six-thirty-sixth of the outcomes will be seven.
But in one role, anything can happen.
And that's the difference between probability and outcome.
that's where the uncertainty comes in, the risk. And in economics, we make decisions based on
what's called the expected value, which is you enumerate the possibilities, you assign probabilities,
you figure out which course of action has the highest probability-weighted value. But some,
maybe the action, which has the highest expected value, includes some possible outcomes which are
unsurvivable, you know? Probably the activity which could produce the highest expected level
of elation for me might be cliff diving. I don't like the bad outcomes. So I'm not going to
engage in cliff diving. And similarly, the highest returning investment activity might be
venture capital investing. And somewhere in the probability distribution for any venture
capital fund investment is the possibility that all the investments turn out to be valueless.
So if I'm a conservative investor, I'm not going to do that.
And so we can't just invest on the basis of the probability distribution and the expected value.
We also have to take our own tolerances and predilections into account.
Like expected value as sort of like a model or a lens into making better decisions.
One of the other ones that you've talked about is sort of second order thinking.
Can you explain a little bit about that?
And then what would be really interesting is to go into other sort of mental models you commonly use to conceptualize problems and think about them.
Well, what I call second level thinking says this.
The goal in investing, investing is a funny activity.
It's really incredibly easy to be average.
And average is usually not too bad.
and if you're willing to settle for average, you can do it with very little risk and very
little, excuse me, very little risk of being below average and very little cost.
You buy what's called an index fund.
If you say, I will be, you know, that the S&P 500 stock index represents average stock
market performance, I'll be happy with the return of the S&P 500.
You invest in an index fund, which invests in all the stocks in the S&P 500, in a
certain weighting. The cost is very low because there's nobody making any decisions.
And you're not investing time either, right? No time cost. And you're absolutely guaranteed
against falling short at the expense of not being able to exceed. So it's really easy to be
average. Those of us who work in the investment business, clearly we shouldn't be well paid
for producing average results, and certainly not below average results, but there should be,
there can be generous rewards for being above average. That's our goal. That's my goal,
to be above average. Now, next paragraph. If you think the same as everybody else,
you'll take the same actions as everybody else. If you take the same actions as everybody else,
you'll have the same performance of everybody else. So, and that by definition, cannot
result in above-average results. So you can't think the same as everybody else. You have to
diverge from the thinking of the herd at some point in time. And if you do and you're right,
then you will probably do things which are different from what the herd does, and you'll
be, have above-average performance. There's problems with that, however, which is that
There is a concept developed at the University of Chicago, 1964, called the Efficient Market
Hypothesis, which says that the market does the, as a good job, I'm going to take off
some of the absoluteness of the hypothesis, that the market, that is the consensus of all
investors, does a good job of incorporating the availability, the available information at a point
in time, which is to say that most of the time, the consensus opinion is,
close to the truth and can't be improved upon. Now, that creates a problem vis-a-vis the desire
for second-level thinking, because to be an outperformer, you have to think different from the
crowd. But most of the time, the crowd is about as close to being right as you can get.
Right. Most of the time, shall we say, idiosyncratic thinking is not right.
Right. Ergo the problem. So to be an above average investor, number one, you have to think different
from the crowd, but number two, you have to be right. So second level thinking is thinking which is
different and better. And by definition, if you think about it, very few people can do it.
My mother used to say it's the exception that proves the rule. And exceptional people think different
from the crowd and better than the crowd. But by definition, they're exceptional. You know,
this isn't Lake Wobigon, a fictional Lake Wobigon where all the children are above average.
And, but, you know, I mean, and my last book was called The Most Important Thing. And
it has 21 chapters and each one says the most important thing is and then it's a different
thing. Because in investing, there is no one important thing or one clearly most important
thing. And there are 21 things, all of which are essential. And,
They're like bricks in the wall.
You can't remove one, in my opinion.
And I've devoted the first chapter to this concept of second level thinking.
And the way you make, you know, most people have no idea how to be a successful investor.
I mean, intellectually, they don't understand, they have no conception of the process.
The way you become a superior investor is you look at things, see things other people don't see.
most people make mistakes concerning a given company they get too excited and price too high they get
too depressed and and toss away its stock at a price which is too low you have to see the mistakes
that others are making understand what they're doing understand why it's wrong hold a different point
of view and be turned be proved right that's a difficult recipe but that's what you have to do
to be a second-level thinker.
So in the chapter, I give some examples.
The first level thing, then this is the simplest and the clearest.
The first-level thinker says, this is a great company, we should buy the stock.
The second-level thinker says it's a great company, but it's not as great as everybody thinks.
The opinions which are incorporated in the price are too optimistic.
and when it turns out that they're too optimistic and when the truth comes out,
those hopes are going to be dashed, the price is going to fall, so we should sell the stock.
Now, clearly, the first level thinker is simplistic.
Good company, buy the stock.
The second level thinking requires a more convoluted discussion, many more words, more time.
A lot of the concepts of second level thinking are by definition counterintuitive, which, by
definition elude most people. That's the definition of counterintuitive. So it's not easy,
but it is a necessary condition for being superior. But you can sort of train yourself to think
in that way. Well, can you or can't you? Some people are naturally born contrarian. Some people
don't get contrarian thinking. And one of the things I say, Shane, is that everything that's
important in investing is counterintuitive. Right. And everything that's obvious is wrong. So
you know, you go up to 100 people on the street and you say, here's a company that, a tech
company, and everybody's buying it, and the stock has tripled in the last month, and we should
buy it. Some large percentage of the people will say, yeah, that makes perfect sense.
Some small percentage will say, no, if it's tripled in the last month, it's probably
some kind of a boom, which means that it has been become unjustifiably popular, and if everybody's
buying it, we should sell it.
That's contrarian thinking.
That's second level thinking.
And I think that that a lot of people, look, I've thought about this a long time.
I've made my money in asset classes that when I got there were unpopular, like high-yield bonds
in 1978.
And I thought to myself, if you went up to a bunch of people in the street.
straight world, the straight investing world, and you said, you should buy this because nobody
else is. Most of them will say, what are you crazy? If they're not buying it, by definition,
it has no merit. And we can't do that. And anyway, we don't want to do something which is
different from what everybody else is doing because if it turns out to be a mistake, we'll look
stupid. How important is that ability to look stupid in terms of outperformance? It's essential.
It is one of the most essential ingredients.
And again, I wrote a memo back in, well, in 06, I think it was.
I wrote one called Dare to Be Great.
And I said, in order to be great, you have to dare to be great.
And then in 14, I updated it, There to Be Great 2.
And I said, everybody dares to be great.
The question is not, do you dare to be great?
The question is, do you dare to be different?
because clearly to diverge from the pack is required if you're going to be a superior in anything.
And number two, do you dare to be wrong?
Number three, you dare to be or look wrong.
Do you dare to look wrong?
Because even things which are going to be right in the long run, maybe look wrong in the short run.
So you have to be willing to live with all those three things, different, wrong, and looking wrong,
in order to be able to take the risk required
and engage in the idiosyncratic behavior required for success.
I want to come back to something you said about thinking the same as everybody else.
How does that change the information that you consume?
And how do you go about the opportunity cost?
I mean, you have a lot of things on your desk.
There's a lot of books to read.
How do you think about that?
At some point in the process, and it's probably a different point for everybody, you have to think
about, again, this idea of counterintuitive. I think what most people think who think about
investing is that if good things happen, you'll make money. Not necessarily so. It all depends on
expectations. If the expectations are too high, then you could have a favorable event, and it
could disappoint people, you know. So people think, last year the company made a dollar per share.
Next year they think they're going to make $2 a share. Earnings doubling. That's exciting. They bid the
stock up and the earnings come out at $1.75. Now, earnings going from a dollar to $1.75 is certainly
a good accomplishment, but most people are disappointed and the stock falls. And so I think it's at some
point, look, the people who work here spend all their time trying to figure out what is.
and they try to know what is, that is to say, what is this company about, what will it be worth
down the road, what will it accomplish, and so forth. And they try to know those things better
than others. But I think an important element in the process is you have to stop at some time
and say, what do other people think? Why do they think it? Why do they diverge from me? What makes
me think I'm right and they're wrong? You have to plumb those differences.
you know, the term you might use that I like to use sometimes is variant perception.
If you think about everything the same way everybody else does, you can't have an exceptional
return. If you think differently and it turns out better, you have an exceptional return.
If you think differently and it turns out worse, you have a horrible return. But clearly,
you can't distinguish yourself if you think the same. And so you know my son. And, you know my son.
And when he was training as a young investor, and when he was in university and starting to think
about a career in investing, he would come to me and he would say, well, you know, we should buy
the stock of Ford because they're bringing out this new Mustang.
It's going to be terrific.
And I always, for pedagogical purposes, answered them the same way.
Who doesn't know that?
See, let's say Ford is going to bring out a Mustang and it's going to be fabulous.
But if everybody knows it, then the expectation of the success of that car is already reflected
in the price of that stock, and the event will not be a profitable one. It'll be favorable
for Ford, but it will not be profitable for investors. So it all comes from seeing things
that others don't see. Another way to say that is it comes from taking advantage of the
mistakes that others are making, which results in thinking which is different, which is right.
That's the laundry list. And does that change the information you consume?
I think it just adds a second level to the information because the information is that you
that you want.
Basically is what's going to happen.
Our people sit around and think about what's going to happen.
If they're in the distressed debt area, how is the restructuring going to go?
If it's in a real estate area, how can that building be optimized and so forth?
But I think it's just another layer of information you need and thinking you have to do,
which is what are other people think and how am I different from them and how are they wrong and how am I right?
Is that one of the reasons that you read broadly across subjects?
I do that mainly. I mean, my reading is not so purposeful.
Okay.
You know, I'm not reading at this point to become a better investor.
I'm not making that many investment around decisions around here.
I'm really just trying to lead the organization, the people and the culture and relate to the clients
and write and speak and that kind of thing.
I'm not making investment decisions.
And I'm just trying to get smarter, you know, and no more and always challenge my thinking.
And, you know, as I said about risk.
And I now have a slightly different way of explaining risk than I did three years ago.
We're always refining and reflecting.
Right.
And I hope to be smarter when we meet next week.
Final question, because I know you get a run, what other parenting sort of ways did you teach
your kids about money that other people can use or borrow from?
First of all, we always talked about money. Not in some, not like it's, you know, the altar
of money on which we have to lay ourselves down, but we talked about responsible financial
decision. And, you know, if you have, if my kids had money, do you want to spend it on this or that
or save it. And if I have money and my wife has money, how do we think we should spend it?
And you should not insulate your kids from the discussion of money. Money is a very real thing
that it's essential to develop good attitudes toward it early. Number one. Number two,
of course, I think you have to keep money in its proper place. And it should not be the be all and all.
And if you're at the dinner table, you should try to avoid saying, oh, that guy is a millionaire,
so he must be a good guy or that person is poor, so they must not have any merit.
And, you know, that's really so important.
I think one of the most important things to have kids who function well around money
is for them to have a feeling of finiteness.
And it goes back really to economic reality, the memo.
They should understand that money is finite.
No matter how much money you have, you can get in trouble if you spend too much of it.
And since it's finite, you shouldn't waste it.
You should make good decisions.
You know, when our daughter went off to college, we said, here's your credit card.
We're going to put money in your checking account every month.
And when the bill comes in, you pay the credit card bill.
And she said, well, I want a credit card like my friend has.
I said, what's that?
She says, oh, she doesn't get bills.
You're not helping your kids if they don't get bills.
And by the way, her friend may not have thought of where the money comes from to pay that credit card.
That's a bad habit.
And, you know, we love our children, and we love them so much.
And some of us grew up without.
And we want to give our kids, we want to give them what we didn't have, we want to give them what their friends have, we want them to feel good, you know.
And there's this temptation to feel that if they have what their friends have, they'll feel good.
if they don't have what their friends have, they feel bad. And so we give them everything. We can.
And some people think that a good parent gives all they can. But it's bad to have the, what the,
what the kid who has the most, it's bad to let that kid set the tone for what your kids should have.
And it builds character to have some, to say, no, in our family, we don't do that. Or in our family, we don't spend
our money that way, or our family decided to take a trip to Paris rather than buy one
of those. These are good letting kids make responsible decisions and choices and stuff like that.
And insulating kids from choices is not doing them a favor.
What are the other sort of like moral lessons that you would start with in our family?
We respect others. We care for others. And we want good for others.
In our family, it's not about getting to the front of the line, and it's not about succeeding
at the expense of others.
We want to be part of a team effort, be in the house, in the community, in the country,
in the company, in the school.
We want to be part of a team effort which brings success to everybody.
And it's not about getting ahead of the others.
and you know if you go out and do a great job you'll be successful and kindness and you know the golden rule
do unto others as you would have them do unto you is it's very relevant and you know the importance of
being good people and being liked and for good reasons and respected and you know when you get to
be my age you Eric Erickson the psychologist wrote about the
stages of man, and you think in terms of how are you thought of. It's very important to you,
but when you get to be my age, it's too late to change how you're thought of. And then ultimately,
how do you think of yourself? And, you know, when I think of people who get close to the end
and are unhappy with how they led their lives, I think it's a terrible tragedy. And then the other
The thing is, I would advise young parents if there are, if there's a choice to be made and
the two choices, let's say, are both non-lethal. Let the child make the choice. When our daughter,
our daughter got into two schools for high school, we wanted her to go to one, but we never said
a word. She chose the other one. She went, she did fine. And number one, maybe the child can
make a good decision. And number two, experience in making decisions is important. And number three,
having your parents tell you, we trust you to make that decision is really very positive for a child's
development. And the other thing is, your kids will make mistakes, hopefully not lethal ones.
And insulating them from making mistakes is not doing them a favor. Because if they make their first
mistake at five, and they improve their decision-making process, and they learn that mistakes
don't kill you, that's a good thing. And if they make their first mistake at 35, and it crushes
them because they're not prepared for that, then that's a bad outcome. And to close on this,
I'd like to read you a paragraph from the book. I'm going to go get it. Just become, for now,
my favorite paragraph in the book. It's also the next to last. As Peter Bernstein said,
is not ours to know, but it helps to know that being wrong is inevitable and normal,
not some terrible tragedy, not some awful failing and reasoning, not even bad luck in most
instances. Being wrong comes with the franchise of an activity whose outcome depends on an
unknown future. No baseball player expects to bat a thousand. Investors shouldn't, which means
they shouldn't get down on themselves if they make a mistake as long as they re-examine their
process and it was good. And you shouldn't castigate your staff members for making a mistake
or your children. Thank you, Howard. That's a great place to end this phenomenal conversation.
Great. Thank you, Shane. I'm glad to have been part of it.
Hey, guys. This is Shane again. Just a few more things before we wrap up. You can find show notes
at Farnham Street blog.com slash podcast. That's F-A-R-N-A-N-A-N-A-N-A-N.
S-T-R-E-E-T-B-L-O-G.com slash podcast.
You can also find information there on how to get a transcript.
And if you'd like to receive a weekly email from me filled with all sorts of brain food,
go to Farnham StreetBlog.com slash newsletter.
This is all the good stuff I've found on the web that week that I've read and shared with
close friends, books I'm reading, and so much more.
Thank you for listening.
You're going to be able to be.